Market Structures
Market Structures
STRUCTURE
By : Divya Mathur
The Four Types of Market Structure
Number of Firms?
Many
firms
Type of Products?
Monopolistic Perfect
Monopoly Oligopoly Competition Competition
◦ If the firm tried to charge a higher price, it would lose all its business. Customers
could go elsewhere to buy the same product for less.
◦ Since the firm is very small, it can sell as much as it wants at the market price. So
there’s no reason to charge a lower price.
◦ The demand curve for the product of the perfectly competitive firm shows
how much can be sold at specific prices. Let’s see what it would look like...
◦ The firm can sell as little or as much as it wants at the market price.
Suppose, for example, the market price is $5.
The firm can sell 10 units for $5.
price
$5
10 quantity
The firm can sell 20 units for $5.
price
$5
20 quantity
The firm can sell 30 units for $5.
price
$5
30 quantity
The firm can sell 40 units for $5.
price
$5
40 quantity
The firm can sell 50 units for $5.
price
$5
50 quantity
So all these points are on the demand
curve for the firm’s product.
price
$5
quantity
Connecting these points, we have the
demand curve for the firm’s product.
price
$5 demand
quantity
The demand curve for the perfectly
competitive firm’s product is a
horizontal line at the market price.
price
quantity
Recall: Total Revenue
price
market price D = MR
quantity
Optimal Output Level
Recall:
To maximize profit, the firm will produce at the output level
where MR = MC.
So the firm will produce where the MR and MC curves
intersect.
Total Marginal
Total Cost Marginal Profit (TR -
Quantity (Q) Price (P) Revenue Revenue
(TC) Cost (MC) TC)
(TR) (MR)
1 50 50 50 30 30 20
2 45 90 40 55 25 35
3 40 120 30 75 20 45
4 35 140 20 95 20 45
5 30 150 10 115 20 35
Draw your axes; label them quantity and $.
Quantity
Draw your ATC, AVC, and MC curves. (Make sure
MC intersects ATC and AVC at the minimum.)
$
ATC AVC
MC
Quantity
Draw the D = MR curve horizontal
at the market price.
$ D = MR
ATC AVC
MC
Quantity
If the market price is P1 ,
the quantity produced will be Q1.
$ D = MR
P1
ATC AVC
MC
Q1 Quantity
If the market price is P2 ,
the quantity produced will be Q2.
$
ATC D = MR
P2
AVC
MC
Q2 Quantity
If the market price is P3 ,
the quantity produced will be Q3.
$
ATC AVC
P3
D = MR
MC
Q3 Quantity
If the market price is P4 ,
the quantity produced will be Q4.
$
ATC AVC
P4
D = MR
MC
Q4 Quantity
If the market price is P5 ,
the quantity produced will be Q5.
$
ATC AVC
D = MR
P5
MC
Q5 Quantity
Price P5 was the minimum of the AVC curve (the shutdown
point). If the price fell any lower than P5 the firm would
produce no output.
The p.c. firm’s short run supply curve
The firm’s supply curve shows the quantity the firm
will produce at each price.
The P, Q values we have shown, therefore, are
points on the firm’s supply curve.
But those points are all on the firm’s MC curve.
So, the firm’s supply curve is the part of the MC
curve that is above the minimum of the AVC curve.
The p.c. firm’s short run supply curve
$ Supply
ATC
AVC
MC
Quantity
The market short run supply curve
length Area
width
We also know TR = P . Q.
So, if we can find a rectangle
P TR
whose length is P and whose
width is Q, then its area must Q
be total revenue.
To determine Total Cost, first remember
ATC = TC / Q
So, ATC . Q = TC
To determine Total Cost, first remember
ATC = TC / Q
So, ATC . Q = TC
ATC TC
Now, if we can find a rectangle
Q
whose length is ATC and whose
width is Q, then its area is TC.
Then to determine profit,
we just subtract the TC area from the TR area.
Graphing Profit:
The six steps
Step 1 a. Draw your axes and label them Q and $.
( Label the origin 0.)
$
0 Quantity
Step 1b. Draw the firm’s ATC curve. (If the price is below the
minimum of ATC, you will also need to draw the AVC curve.)
$ MC
ATC
P
0 Quantity
Step 1 c. Draw the MC curve and D=MR curve. (For a
positive profit, D must be at least partly above ATC.)
$ MC
ATC
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Step 2: Determine the profit-maximizing output (Q*) by
finding where MR = MC.
$ MC ATC
P
D = MR
0
Q* Quantity
Step 3: Find your TR = PQ rectangle.
$ MC ATC
P
D = MR
0
Q* Quantity
Step 4: Determine ATC at the profit-maximizing
output level.
$ MC ATC
P
D = MR
ATC
0
Q* Quantity
Step 5: Find your TC = ATC . Q rectangle.
$ MC ATC
P
D = MR
Q* Quantity
SHORT RUN EQUILIBRIUM
Step 6: Find profit = TR - TC.
$ MC ATC
P
profit D = MR
Q* Quantity
You follow the same steps to
draw a firm that is making a loss
or breaking even (zero profits).
$ MC
ATC
AVC
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Step 2: Determine the profit-maximizing output (Q*) by
finding where MR = MC.
$ MC
ATC
AVC
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Q*
Step 3: Find your TR = PQ rectangle.
$ MC
ATC
AVC
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Q*
Step 4: Determine ATC at the profit-maximizing
(or loss-minimizing) output level.
$ MC
ATC
ATC
AVC
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Q*
Step 5: Find your TC = ATC . Q rectangle.
$ MC
ATC
ATC
AVC
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Q*
Case of Loss (or Subnormal Profit)
Step 6: Find profit (or loss) = TR - TC.
$ MC
ATC
AVC
loss
P
D = MR
0 Quantity
Q*
A firm that is breaking even
(zero profits)
Step 1: Draw & label the curves & axes. To break even, make D tangent to
the minimum of ATC.
$ MC
ATC
D = MR
P
0 Quantity
Step 2: Determine the profit-maximizing output (Q*) by
finding where MR = MC.
$ MC
ATC
D = MR
P
0 Q* Quantity
Step 3: Find your TR = PQ rectangle.
$ MC
ATC
D = MR
P
0 Q* Quantity
Step 4: Determine ATC at the profit-maximizing
output level.
$ MC
ATC
D = MR
ATC = P
0 Q* Quantity
Step 5: Find your TC = ATC . Q rectangle.
$ MC
ATC
D = MR
ATC = P
0 Q* Quantity
Case of Normal Profit
Step 6: Find profit = TR - TC.
$ MC
ATC
D = MR
ATC = P
0 Q* Quantity
Special Case: Exit or Shut Down Point
If the prevailing price in the market is more than the
average variable cost (AVC) of production, the firm would
continue production. But if AVC exceeds AR the firm
would shutdown.
Perfectly Competitive market in long run
Over the long-run, if firms in a perfectly competitive market
are earning positive economic profits, more firms will enter
the market, which will shift the supply curve to the right. As
the supply curve shifts to the right, the equilibrium price will
go down. As the price goes down, economic profits will
decrease until they become zero.
When price is less than average total cost, firms are making a loss.
Over the long-run, if firms in a perfectly competitive market are
earning negative economic profits, more firms will leave the market,
which will shift the supply curve left. As the supply curve shifts left,
the price will go up. As the price goes up, economic profits will
increase until they become zero.
In sum, in the long-run, companies that are engaged in a
perfectly competitive market earn zero economic profits.
The long-run equilibrium point for a perfectly competitive
market occurs where the demand curve (price) intersects the
marginal cost (MC) curve and the minimum point of the
average cost (AC) curve.
LONG RUN EQUILIBRIUM
Perfect Competition in the Long Run: In the long-run, economic
profit cannot be sustained. The arrival of new firms in the market
causes the demand curve of each individual firm to shift downward,
bringing down the price, the average revenue and marginal revenue
curve. In the long-run, the firm will make zero economic profit. Its
horizontal demand curve will touch its average total cost curve at its
lowest point.
CASE
MONOPOLY
◦ A monopoly is the sole supplier of a product with no close
substitutes.
◦ Monopoly definition by Prof. A.J. Braff – ‘Under pure monopoly,
there is a single seller in the market. The monopolist’s demand is
the market demand. The monopolist is a price maker. Pure
monopoly suggests a no substitute situation.‘
Features of Monopoly
◦ No close substitute
◦ Legal restrictions
◦ Economies of scale
◦ One way to prevent new firms from entering a market is to make entry illegal.
◦ Patents, licenses, and other legal restrictions imposed by the government
provide some producers with legal protection against competition.
◦ A patent awards an inventor the exclusive right to produce a good or service for
20 years
◦ Patent laws encourage inventors to invest the time and money required to discover and
develop new products and processes.
◦ Also provide the stimulus to turn an invention into a marketable product, a process
called innovation
Licenses and other Entry Restrictions
◦ Because such a monopoly emerges from the nature of costs, it is called a natural monopoly.
◦ A new entrant cannot sell enough output to experience the economies of scale enjoyed by
an established natural monopolist -entry into the market is naturally blocked.
Control of Essential Resources
◦ Alcoa was the sole U.S. maker of aluminum for a long period of time because it controlled the
supply of bauxite
◦ China is the monopoly supplier of pandas
◦ DeBeers controls the world’s diamond trade
Revenue for the Monopolist
◦ Suppose De Beers controls the entire diamond market and suppose they can sell
three diamonds a day at $7,000 each -total revenue of $21,000
◦ Total revenue divided by quantity is the average revenue per diamond which is also
$7,000
◦ Thus, the monopolist’s price equals the average revenue per diamond.
◦ To sell a fourth diamond, De Beers must lower the price to $6,750- total revenue for 4
diamonds is $27,000 and average revenue is again $6,750
◦ The marginal revenue from selling the fourth diamond is $6,000-marginal revenue is
less than the price or average revenue
◦ Recall that these were equal for the perfectly competitive firm
Loss or Gain from Selling
By selling another diamond, De Beers gains the revenue from that
$7,000
LOSS sale, $6,750 from the 4th diamond as shown by the blue-shaded
6,750 vertical rectangle marked gain.
Price per However, to sell that 4th unit, De Beers must sell all four diamonds
Diamond
for $6,750 each ➔ it must sacrifice $250 on each of the first three
diamonds which could have sold for $7,000 each.
D = Average
G
revenue
A
I The loss in revenue from the first three units, $750, is shown by the
N red shaded horizontal rectangle marked Loss.
The net change in total revenue from selling the 4th diamond equals
the gain minus the loss ➔ $6,750 - $750 = $6,000.
0 3 4
Revenue Schedule
The first two columns contain the pertinent price and quantity
information.
◦ The firm earns normal profits – If the average cost = the average
revenue
◦ It earns super-normal profits – If the average cost < the average
revenue
◦ It incurs losses – If the average cost > the average revenue
Normal Profits
◦ A firm earns normal profits when the average cost of production is equal to the
average revenue for the corresponding output.
◦ In the figure above, you can see that the MC curve cuts the MR curve at the
equilibrium point E. Also, the AC curve touches the AR curve at a point
corresponding to the same point. Therefore, the firm earns normal profits.
Super-normal Profits
◦ A firm earns super-normal profits when the average cost of production is less than the average revenue for the
corresponding output.
◦ In the figure above, you can see that the price per unit = OP = QA. Also, the cost per unit = OP’. Therefore, the firm is earning
more and incurring a lesser cost. In this case, the per unit profit is
◦ OP – OP’ = PP’
◦ Also, the total profit earned by the monopolist is PP’BA.
Losses
◦ A firm earns losses when the average cost
of production is higher than the average
revenue for the corresponding output.
◦ In the figure, the average cost curve lies
above the average revenue curve for the
same quantity. The average revenue = OP
and the average cost = OP’. Therefore, the
firm is incurring an average loss of PP’
and the total loss is PP’BA. In the short-
run, a monopolist sometimes sets a lower
price and incurs losses to keep new firms
away.
A Firm’s Long-run Equilibrium in Monopoly
◦ In the long-run, a monopolist can vary all the inputs. Therefore, to determine the
equilibrium of the firm, we need only two cost curves – the AC and the MC.
◦ Further, since the monopolist exits the market if he is operating at a loss, the
demand curve must be tangent to the AC curve or lie to the right and intersect it
twice.
◦ There are two alternative cases for the
determination of Equilibrium in
Monopoly:
◦ The marginal revenue curve MR2 cuts the MC curve from below at point B. The
corresponding height of the AR2 curve is E’M1.
◦ Hence, the monopolist produces OM1 quantity and sells it at E’M1 per unit to
earn an extra profit of E’B per unit.
◦ Being a monopoly, this extra profit is not lost to competition or newer firms
entering the industry.
Long-Run Profit Maximization
◦ A monopolist that earns economic profit in the short-run may find that profit
can be increased in the long run by adjusting the scale of the firm
◦ Conversely, a monopoly that suffers a loss in the short run may be able to
eliminate that loss in the long run by adjusting to a more efficient size
Monopolistic Competition
• Monopolistic Competition is a market
structure in which many firms sell products
that are similar but not identical.
• Examples of monopolistic competition:
Books, toothpaste, computer software,
restaurants, furniture, and so on.
Advertising Image
Firms also use advertising to create apparent differences between
their own offerings and other products in the marketplace.
Price
MC
ATC
Price
Average
total cost
Profit Demand
MR
0 Profit- Quantity
maximizing
quantity © 2007 Thomson South-Western
The Monopolistically Competitive Firm in the Short Run
Price
MC
ATC
Losses
Average
total cost
Price
MR Demand
0 Loss- Quantity
minimizing
quantity © 2007 Thomson South-Western
The Long-Run Equilibrium
• Firms will enter and exit until the firms are making exactly zero
economic profits.
MC
ATC
• Two Characteristics
• As in a monopoly, price exceeds marginal cost.
• Profit maximization requires marginal revenue to equal marginal cost.
• The downward-sloping demand curve makes marginal revenue less than price.
• As in a competitive market, price equals average total cost.
• Free entry and exit drive economic profit to zero.
P*
D
Q* quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
MR Curve
for the top part of the Demand Curve
$
D
P*
MR
Q* quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Drawing MR Curve
for the bottom part of the Demand
Curve
$
P*
MR
D
Q* quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
MR Curve
for the bottom part of the Demand
Curve
$
P*
MR
D
Q* quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
The Kinked Demand Curve
and the MR Curve
$
P*
MR
D
Q* quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
The MC curve intersects the MR curve
in the vertical segment.
$
MC
P*
MR
D
Q* quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
If costs shift up slightly, but MC still
intersects MR in the vertical segment, there
will be no
change in price.
$ MC’ This price
MC rigidity is seen in
real world
P*
oligopoly
markets.
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
The ATC curve can be added to the graph. To
show positive profits, part of ATC curve must
lie under part of the demand curve.
$
MC ATC
P*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
The ATC* value can be found on the ATC
curve above Q*.
$
MC ATC
P*
ATC*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
TC = ATC . Q
$
MC ATC
P*
ATC*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
TR = P . Q
$
MC ATC
P*
ATC*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Profit = TR - TC
$
MC ATC
P* profit
ATC*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
To show a firm with a loss, the ATC curve
must be entirely above the demand curve.
ATC
$
ATC* loss MC AVC
P*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
To show a firm breaking even, the ATC curve
must be tangent to the demand curve at the
kink.
$
MC ATC
ATC*= P*
D
Q* MR quantity
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
GAME THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF COOPERATION
Bonnie’ s Decision
Confess
Remain
Silent
Jack’s Decision
High
Production
40
Jill gets $1,600 profit Jill gets $2,000 profit
Jill’s gal.
Decision Jack gets $2,000 profit Jack gets $1,800 profit
Low
Production
30
Jill gets $1,500 profit Jill gets $1,800 profit
gal.
Arm Disarm
Arm
Decision
USSR at risk USSR safe and powerful
of the
Soviet Union U.S. safe and powerful U.S. safe
(USSR)
Disarm
USSR at risk and weak USSR safe
These are:
1. Difference in Elasticity of Demand:
Price discrimination is possible only when elasticity of demand will be different in different
markets. The monopolist will fix higher price where demand is inelastic and low price where
the demand will be elastic. In this way, he will be able to increase his total revenue.
2. Market Imperfections:
Generally, price discrimination is possible only when there is some degree of market
imperfections. The individual seller is able to divide his market into separate parts only if it is
imperfect.
3. Differentiated Product:
Price discrimination is possible when buyers need the same service in connection with
differentiated products. For example, railways charges different rates for the transport of
coal and copper.
First-degree price discrimination doesn’t exist as it is just too expensive and difficult to specifically obtain
each consumer’s maximum willingness to pay. Not only is it difficult to find out, but it is practically
impossible to do. There is also the element of each individual’s cognitive ability. The maximum price they
are willing to pay can fluctuate rapidly. For instance, when a consumer is looking through the store, they
may find something they like, but when they see something they prefer, they put the first good back as
this has changed their valuation.
• Most airlines operate a form of price discrimination by using dynamic pricing. This is
simply where prices fluctuate depending on current demand. For instance, if tickets are
selling quickly, then prices will start to rise. If tickets are hardly selling, then the prices
may fall to attract more customers.
• Whilst this form of price discrimination doesn’t necessarily maximize revenue from the
consumer, it does increase the firm’s profits by taking advantage of some consumer’s
higher willingness to pay. For example, those consumers who are price-sensitive are
more likely to book when the tickets come out and are at their cheapest. By contrast,
those who are not so sensitive to prices may book last minute when prices may be
significantly higher.
• Therefore, airlines are able to segment between more price-sensitive consumers and
those who are not. For instance, those who need to travel for last-minute business will
have a higher willingness to pay than a family of four looking for a holiday.
Coupons
Many customers get coupons in the post or at the store as a way to encourage existing customers to
come back and buy more. By offering a discount to those customers, the firm is able to attract repeat
custom and increase sales. These are commonly adopted by retailers – usually in conjunction with a
loyalty card. By offering coupons, customers are encouraged to come back and buy more goods from
the store – albeit at a lower price.
Cinemas
Cinemas are another example of third-degree price discrimination. They do so by segmenting the
market between children, adults, and seniors. Usually, children and seniors receive a discounted rate,
which adults pay the highest price. The reason being is that children will most often come with an
adult.
It is cheaper than child care and makes it cheaper overall for the adult to go to the cinema. Adults
benefit from having to pay lower prices to bring their children, but the cinema also benefits from higher
expenditures on related items such as popcorn. Quite simply, by offering children lower rates, it not
only brings in more children but also more adults.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
• Restaurants
• Some restaurants offer discounts for customers that come at a specific time. This might
include a cheaper ‘lunch-time’ menu or some kind of ‘early-bird’ menu for customers
who come during non-peak hours. This attracts customers who are more price-
sensitive, whilst also benefiting the firm by utilizing its capacity during less busy hours.
Some restaurants also offer discounts for veterans and healthcare workers.
• Student Discounts
• Most firms recognize that students demand is very elastic – meaning they are more
sensitive to changes in price. As a result, many firms offer substantial discounts for
students in order to win their business. Not only does this win their custom in the short-
term, but it could also win their custom for their adult life too. After all, students are
likely to be curious and try new brands and experiment. If one firm does well with their
offering, they may in fact win a customer for life.