5638035
5638035
Introduction
* Professor of Economics and Professor and Chairperson, Economics Department, Saint Mary’s
University, Halifax, NS, Canada, respectively.
productivity depends, in turn, upon the rate of export expansion. Rapid export
growth implies a dynamic export sector, most likely characterised by high rates
of absorption of new technologies from abroad as well as more rapid
technological progress at home. To assess how the impact of these factors on
growth is influenced by the size of government, we classify countries according
to the aggregate size of government in the economy, and study the relationship
specified above for each category of government size using the Swamy-Mehta
random coefficients approach. In other words, our interest is in determining
whether, and to what extent, the impacts on economic growth of traditional
factors such as capital accumulation, growth of the labour force, and export
expansion are affected by the overall size of government in the economy. The
random coefficients approach is designed to accommodate inter-country
differences in the nature and structure of institutions and other forms of
heterogeneity, all of which are central to the political economy literature, but
which are very difficult to quantify in unique and reliable fashion. Our approach
would, therefore, probably be superior to those that attempt to quantify these
factors directly.
In this article, we use time series data for the following 17 Western hemisphere
countries: Argentina (1964–95), Bolivia (1967–96), Brazil (1965–95), Canada
(1962–96), Chile (1963–96), Colombia (1970–96), Costa Rica (1962–96), El
Salvador (1962–96), Guatemala (1962–96), Honduras (1962–96), Mexico
(1962–96), Nicaragua (1962–96), Panama (1961–95), Peru (1963–95), the
United States (1961–96), Uruguay (1962–96), and Venezuela (1961–96). The
data were obtained from various issues of Government Finance Statistics and
International Financial Statistics Yearbooks published by the International
Monetary Fund.
Table 1 presents sample period averages for rates of growth of output (G Y),
labour (GL), and exports (GX), as well as the investment to GDP (denoted by
I/Y) and total exports (X) plus imports (M) to GDP ratios, and population
(1995–6) for the countries in the sample. The countries have been classified into
four groups in terms of the size of government measured as the ratio of
government expenditure (G) plus revenue (R) to GDP. It can be seen that the
size of government varies from a relatively low 21-26% for Guatemala, Bolivia,
Colombia and El Salvador, to a high in the 49–58% range for Brazil, Uruguay,
Venezuela, Nicaragua, Chile and Panama. Argentina, Peru and Honduras are
in the intermediate group of 30–31% range, while Mexico, Canada, the US and
Costa Rica belong to the intermediate-to-high group III, with the size of
government ranging from about 36% to 44%. The countries with the lowest
(Nicaragua) and highest (Panama) rates of economic growth both belong to
68 Development Policy Review
Table 1
Average annual growth of output (GY) and exports (GX), investment-
output ratios (I/Y), openness ((X+M)/Y), government finance ((G+R)/Y)
and population
Y = Y(K, L, X) (1)
where Y is aggregate real output, K is the capital input, L is the labour input and
X represents exports. Assuming that the aggregate production function is linear
in natural logarithms, the usual model employed for empirical purposes (after
taking total derivatives and manipulating) can be shown to be:
where GY is the rate of growth of Y, I/Y the investment-output ratio, GX the rate
of growth of X, and GL the rate of growth of L, approximated, here, by the rate
of population growth. Note that 2 is the marginal physical product of capital,
70 Development Policy Review
where W is the set of excluded variables that, along with those that are included,
is sufficient to determine GY. However, in the linear deterministic law stated
by equation (3), neither the slope coefficients nor W are unique in that they are
sensitive to the parameterisation chosen. To ensure uniqueness, we postulate:
(GY)it = 1i + 2i (I/Y)it + 3i (GX)it + 4i (GL)it + uit (5)
where 1i = 1 + 1iU , 2i = 2 + 2iU , 3i = 3 + 3iU , 4i = 4 + 4iU and uit =
vitU .
Note that equation (5) is a random coefficients model, and that the
disturbance is not the joint effect of the excluded variables; instead, it is the
joint effect of the remainder of the excluded variables after the effect of the
included variables has been factored out. Note also that, whereas the included
variables cannot be uncorrelated with every variable that affects GY, they can
be uncorrelated with the remainder of every such variable (see Pratt and
Schlaifer, 1988). Thus, each of our explanatory variables can be uncorrelated
with u, and equation (5) can be taken to represent the law relating GY to its
determinants.
Dar and Amirkhalkhali, Impact of Government Size on Economic Growth 71
Table 2 reports the OLS results for each group as well as the entire sample, and
Table 3 gives the corresponding GLS results. Looking at the OLS results, we
note that, with the exception of group II, each group regression as well as the
regression using the entire sample is highly significant as a whole. Most
coefficients are also significant at the 5% level. The OLS results, however, are
not reliable if the impacts on growth are country-specific. Furthermore, the
Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics and the Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey (BPG) tests
reported in Table 2 point to the existence of autocorrelation in all of them and
heteroscedasticity for groups I and IV. We turn therefore to our random
coefficients GLS results.
Table 2
Regression results: OLS
Model: (GY)it = 1 + 2(I/Y)it + 3(GX)it + 4(GL)it + uit
2 3 4 1 F R2 DW BPG No Nc
GROUP I 0.252* 0.066* 0.844* -3.109* 15.9* 0.28 0.92 9.28* 125 4
(0.071) (0.014) (0.343) (1.565)
GROUP II 0.009 0.046** 0.965** 0.140 1.8 0.05 1.53 3.23 101 3
(0.092) (0.024) (0.504) (2.303)
GROUP III 0.097** 0.055* 1.172* 0.973 13.0* 0.22 1.25 1.11 141 4
(0.066) (0.014) (0.282) (1.583)
GROUP IV 0.308* 0.046* -0.403 2.122** 14.6* 0.18 1.32 19.6* 205 6
(0.059) (0.014) (0.393) (1.151)
ALL 0.173* 0.053* 0.511* -1.439* 29.8* 0.14 1.27 10.4* 572 17
(0.032) (0.009) (0.190) (0.714)
Note: Figures in parentheses are the estimated standard errors. No and Nc denote the number of
observations and number of countries respectively. F gives the F-ratio for testing the overall
significance of the model. DW and BPG are the Durbin-Watson and Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey
statistics respectively. * indicates statistical significance at the 5% level.
72 Development Policy Review
Table 3 contains the aggregate group results based on GLS estimation. Note
first that the G-statistic is statistically significant at the 5% level in all cases,
thereby vindicating the random coefficients model. What do the results suggest
about the size of government ? First, it is evident that investment rates have, on
average, the largest statistically significant impact on economic growth for
group IV, the group of countries which are characterised by the largest size of
government. The corresponding impact for group I is somewhat smaller but also
significant. Interestingly, this impact for the intermediate groups is not
significant. Since the investment rate, on average, is roughly similar across
groups, these absolute impacts are also suggestive of their relative impacts. It
seems, therefore, that the role of capital formation in fostering economic growth
is not adversely affected for countries with big government sectors. This may
well reflect the beneficial externality that government activity generates in the
economy. The results for the impact of export growth are also more clear-cut
here. The coefficients are significant at the 5% level for all groups taken
together, and although there does not appear to be much difference in the
absolute growth impacts for the four groups there is a positive (at least non-
decreasing) relationship between the size of the impact and the size of the
government sector. However, the impact is statistically significant only for the
countries where government size is largest (group IV) and smallest (group I).
Table 3
Regression results: random coefficients GLS
Model:(G<)it = 1i + 2i (I/Y)it + 3i (G;)it + 4i (G/)it + uit
2 3 4 1 G-statistic No Nc
Table 4
Regression results: random coefficients GLS
Model: (GY)it = 1i + 2i (I/Y)it + 3i (GX)it + 4i (GL)it + uit
Group/Country 2 3 4 1
I. Guatemala 0.1368 0.1065 0.3515 -0.0443
0.0941 0.0213 0.7870 2.6668
Bolivia 0.3679 0.0396 -1.3960 -0.1774
0.0954 0.0160 0.4771 1.9601
Colombia 0.1531 0.0568 1.3487 -2.2096
0.0980 0.0190 0.6435 2.4780
El Salvador 0.2365 0.0359 2.4887 -6.9467
0.1144 0.0281 0.6071 2.4089
II. Honduras -0.0308 0.1568 -0.1054 3.6239
0.662 0.0266 0.6588 2.1093
Argentina 0.1573 0.0325 1.2520 -3.0433
0.1174 0.0277 0.7990 2.6716
Peru 0.0469 0.0906 1.3062 -1.5539
0.0576 0.0199 0.4805 1.6588
III. Mexico 0.2628 0.0240 3.1346 -9.6990
0.1063 0.0197 0.6194 2.3973
Canada 0.3238 0.0822 0.3078 -4.6112
0.0970 0.0276 0.5673 2.3029
USA 0.5131 0.0024 0.9889 -7.6597
0.1216 0.0239 0.5022 2.2759
Costa Rica -0.0721 0.1450 0.8346 2.5632
0.0842 0.0284 0.7714 2.5919
IV. Brazil 0.2478 0.0877 1.6704 -5.4992
0.1021 0.0297 0.8662 2.7071
Uruguay 0.1297 0.1027 0.4062 -0.7531
0.1160 0.0253 0.5241 1.5659
Venezuela 0.1463 0.0045 1.3012 -3.5799
0.0809 0.0151 0.8685 2.0732
Nicaragua 0.3396 0.1300 -2.4915 2.2504
0.1189 0.0302 0.8250 2.6379
Chile 0.4156 0.0365 1.4407 -6.9905
0.1023 0.0243 0.8092 2.5334
Panama 0.1272 0.0750 1.4831 -2.4265
0.0898 0.0299 0.8605 2.5001
variations that are obscured in the aggregate results. These results are presented
in Table 4 . It can be seen that the investment impact is the largest for the US.
Other countries with large impacts are Chile, Bolivia, Nicaragua, Canada and
Mexico. Interestingly, these countries straddle all four groups, with three of
them belonging to the intermediate group. It is evident that the aggregate group
74 Development Policy Review
In this article, we have attempted to investigate the role played by the size of
government in determining the impact of major determinants of economic
growth for a group of 17 Western hemisphere countries within a production
function framework, but in a much more general manner than previous studies.
To this end, we classified the countries into four groups of low, intermediate,
intermediate-to-high, and high ranges in terms of the overall size of the
government sector. We also developed the estimating model so that it more
accurately represented the law relating the rate of economic growth to the rate
of investment and the rates of export and labour force growth. Indeed, in light
of the great diversity among countries, we used a random coefficients model,
which can be viewed as a generalisation of the laws stated by Pratt and
Schlaifer. Our results supported the random coefficients approach for the entire
sample. The results generally indicate that the role of capital formation and
export expansion in fostering economic growth is not adversely affected for
countries with large government sectors. Our estimates of the country-specific
Dar and Amirkhalkhali, Impact of Government Size on Economic Growth 75
B = (U0-1)-1U0-1Y
0ii = i iU+)ii
Note that Zi contains observations on K explanatory variables over T periods of
time for the ith country,
References