Future of Work Paper Series
Future of Work Paper Series
Table of Contents
Domestic Outsourcing in the U.S.: A Research Agenda to Assess Trends and Effects on Job Quality—
Annette Bernhardt et al. ...................................................................................................................... 1
Sector-Based Training Strategies: The Challenges of Matching Workers and Their Skills to Well-paying
Jobs—Harry J. Holzer .......................................................................................................................... 48
Some Implications of the Changing Structure of Work for Worker Retirement Security, Pensions and
Healthcare—David A. Pratt ................................................................................................................. 73
The Changing Structure of Work: Implications for Workplace Health and Safety in the US—Leslie I.
Boden et al.. ......................................................................................................................................... 99
Domestic Outsourcing in the U.S.:
A Research Agenda to Assess Trends and Effects
on Job Quality
by
Prepared for the Future of Work Symposium, U.S. Department of Labor, Washington DC,
December 2015
DISCLAIMER: This report was prepared for the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL), Chief Evaluation Office. The
views expressed are those of the authors and should not be attributed to DOL, nor does mention of trade names,
commercial products, or organizations imply endorsement of same by the U.S. Government.
1
Abstract:
The goal of this paper is to develop a comprehensive research agenda to analyze trends in
domestic outsourcing in the U.S. – firms’ use of contractors and independent contractors – and
its effects on job quality and inequality. In the process, we review definitions of outsourcing,
the available scant empirical research, and limitations of existing data sources. We also
summarize theories that attempt to explain why firms contract out for certain functions and
assess their predictions about likely impacts on job quality. We then lay out in detail a major
research initiative on domestic outsourcing, discussing the questions it should answer and
providing a menu of research methodologies and potential data sources. Such a research
investment will be a critical resource for policymakers and other stakeholders as they seek
solutions to problems arising from the changing nature of work.
2
Table of Contents
1. Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 4
The Problem ........................................................................................................................................4
2. Defining Domestic Outsourcing ........................................................................................ 7
Relationship between Domestic Outsourcing and Nonstandard Work.............................................. 8
Examples of Domestic Outsourcing ..................................................................................................10
3. Why Do Firms Contract Out, and What Explains Variation in Their Strategies? ................ 13
Economic and Management Perspectives ........................................................................................13
Institutional and Political Explanations.............................................................................................17
What Explains Variation in Outsourcing?..........................................................................................19
4. The Impact of Domestic Outsourcing on the Quality of Jobs ............................................ 22
Variation in Outsourcing and the Quality of Jobs .............................................................................25
5. The State of Data on the Prevalence of and Growth in Domestic Outsourcing ................. 27
Evidence on Prevalence and Growth ................................................................................................27
Data Limitations ................................................................................................................................31
6. A Proposed Research Agenda and Research Network on Domestic Outsourcing .............. 33
Research Questions...........................................................................................................................33
Industry Studies................................................................................................................................. 34
Economy-Wide Research and Data Development ............................................................................38
References .......................................................................................................................... 40
3
1. Introduction
Stagnant wages, growing inequality, and the deterioration of job quality are among the most
important challenges facing the U.S. economy today. Although domestic outsourcing – firms’
use of contractors, franchises, and independent contractors – is a potentially important
mechanism through which companies reduce compensation and shift economic risk to workers,
surprisingly little is known about the extent of this practice and its implications for wages and
working conditions. Our review of the available research suggests that domestic outsourcing
takes place on a much larger scale and affects many more workers than has been recognized –
ranging from low-wage service workers such as janitors, security guards, warehouse workers,
and hotel housekeepers to professional and technical workers such as programmers, health
care technicians, and accountants. These trends are part of a structural change in the
organization of production and work across firms that we suspect is profoundly affecting the
quality of jobs and the nature of the employment contract for a significant portion of the
American workforce (Weil 2014).
The goal of this paper is to develop a comprehensive research agenda to analyze trends in
domestic outsourcing in the U.S. and its effects on the quality of jobs – including wages,
benefits, employee skills and discretion at work, training and mobility opportunities, and job
security – as well as inequality across jobs. In the process, we review definitions of outsourcing,
the available scant empirical research, and limitations of existing data sources. We also
summarize theories that attempt to explain why firms contract out for certain functions and
assess their predictions about likely impacts on job quality. We then lay out in detail a major
research initiative on domestic outsourcing, discussing the questions it should answer and
providing a menu of research methodologies and potential data sources.
In our view, such a research investment will be a critical resource for policymakers and other
stakeholders as they seek solutions to problems arising from the changing nature of work.
Domestic outsourcing has potentially important implications for the adequacy of existing
employment and labor laws; the provision of health, pension, and other workplace benefits;
and workplace enforcement strategies – all topics of current debates that could be informed by
better data and research.
The Problem
Firms’ choices regarding the organization of work and production play a critical role in shaping
the skill requirements of jobs, the level and distribution of wages, and working conditions. This
is well-documented in the sociological research on job quality (Kalleberg 2013), the industrial
relations literature (Kochan, Katz, and McKersie 1986), and the management literature (Cappelli
1999). In particular, industry-based empirical research has documented how variation in
4
employer strategies between firms in the same industry has led to variation in the quality of
jobs (Appelbaum, Bernhardt, and Murnane 2003; Gautie and Schmitt 2010). That research
typically focused on comparing work restructuring within the establishments of primary firms
and showed how managerial choices to pursue value-added or cost-focused strategies often
lead to differences in the quality of jobs for workers in the same occupation or with the same
skill level.
We believe that the next step for understanding how firm strategies affect the quality of jobs
and inequality is to study more systematically the reallocation of labor across organizations, as
a result of firms contracting with other firms (or independent contractors) for goods and
services. We refer to this process as domestic outsourcing or contracting out. Based on
existing research and imperfect datasets, we suspect that firms have increased their use of
outsourcing and that the effects of the reallocation of jobs across firms are at least as salient as
the reorganization of work within firms that has been more typically studied (Weil 2014). If we
are correct, then this raises the possibility that the rise of domestic outsourcing may have
contributed to growing wage inequality, which would help to explain recent research findings
that the majority of the increase in inequality has occurred between firms (Barth et al. 2014;
Handwerker and Spletzer 2015). 1 We also suspect that variation in firms’ contracting decisions
leads to quite different labor market outcomes, depending on such factors as ownership
structures and market pressures, industry and occupation, motivation for contracting, and
power relations between the primary firm and different tiers of contractors. For example,
outsourcing overflow work in high or uncertain demand conditions or to take advantage of
specialized expertise or technology may have different implications for worker outcomes than
outsourcing of functions previously performed in-house in order to reduce labor costs.
Contracting out is difficult to define because, in the broadest sense, a large part of economic
activity has always occurred through business-to-business transactions, as captured in macro-
economic input-output models. Our observation, however, is that the scale and scope of
contracting for goods and services production has changed in fundamental ways in recent
decades, and that this change – and its implications for the quality of jobs – needs to be
conceptualized more clearly and examined empirically. In the past, much of value creation
occurred within large enterprises; in recent decades, however, the vertical disintegration of
large corporations has led to more value creation through decentralized production networks,
resulting in a larger proportion of productive activity occurring through business-to-business
contracting.
1
Indeed, Goldschmidt and Schmieder (2015) show that the outsourcing of cleaning, food, security, and logistics
services accounts for a sizable share of the growth in wage inequality in Germany since the 1980s.
5
While this transformation has been the focus of considerable research in its international form
(the offshoring of work in global supply chains), until recently the domestic counterpart has
received relatively little scholarly attention. This, despite some evidence suggesting that the
growth in offshore outsourcing has been accompanied by growth in domestic outsourcing
(Yuskavage, Strassner, and Medeiros 2008) and the fact that the majority of production in
supply chains is still domestic or regional (Rugman, Li, and Oh 2009).
Specifically, we lack research on three fronts: the prevalence and different patterns of firm-
level contracting within and across industries; the factors driving contracting out; and the
relationship between these patterns and the quality of jobs at the workplace. First, inadequate
and incomplete data mean that it is difficult to estimate the prevalence of domestic
outsourcing of various business functions across sectors of the economy or the number of
workers affected by it, though estimates are feasible for several specific industries and
occupations (Dey, Houseman, and Polivka 2010). Similarly, our understanding of variation in
contracting strategies within and across industries is thin, but initial research suggests that the
stylized view of domestic outsourcing as a linear supply chain or a unidirectional process of
economic fragmentation is inadequate (Gospel and Sako 2010).
Second, we lack a clear understanding of the factors that are driving domestic outsourcing –
and by extension, whether firm decisions about what to retain in-house and what to outsource
have changed over time. At a general level, market deregulation, heightened competition,
technological change, and the rising influence of institutional investors and shareholders have
put severe pressure on U.S. firms to reduce costs and headcount and increase quality and
responsiveness to consumer demand. Some evidence suggests that firms have responded by
focusing on their “core competencies” and outsourcing peripheral or low value-added tasks as
well as higher value-added specialized functions. Advanced technologies have facilitated this
process by allowing firms to outsource entire functions and more easily monitor contractors as
well as employees who work virtually, leading to new forms of networked production and the
rise of specialized firms. But few studies provide a more fine-grained empirical analysis of
which factors are more salient for different industries or how these differences lead to distinct
forms of outsourcing and contracting relationships – and in turn, differential outcomes for
workers.
Third and most important, we lack robust research on how domestic outsourcing and the
nature of the relationship between contracting firms affects wages and other dimensions of job
quality, such as benefits, hours, workload, job stability, schedule stability, occupational safety
and health, incidence of wage theft, and access to training and promotions. As we will see,
some of the theoretical frameworks in this area predict that job quality and mobility
6
opportunities will suffer when jobs that do not require a college degree are contracted out.
Predictions are less clear for other cases – for example, jobs requiring professional, technical, or
specialized skills, or those that are outsourced to large and diversified contractors. The impacts
of the rise of on-demand platforms – such as Uber, TaskRabbit, and Upwork – are especially
difficult to study because the work constitutes a collection of micro jobs (“gigs”) that often
supplement individuals’ income from a main job; as a result, government surveys of workers
are likely to miss some portion of this work activity.
In sum, our review of existing research suggests a substantial lack of knowledge about domestic
outsourcing in the U.S. – its prevalence and the various forms it takes, its causes, and its effects
on job quality and inequality.
In producing goods and services for final demand, firms may choose to perform certain
functions in-house or they may contract with other firms for those inputs. For example,
companies may perform manufacturing, transportation, research and development, IT services,
accounting, or cleaning functions in-house, or they may outsource those functions by
contracting with another firm. Changes in the mix of this “make or buy” decision over time
have been variously labeled the vertical disintegration of the firm, the changing boundary of
the firm, the growth of networked production, and so forth. We review different academic
approaches to this question in the next section.
Specifically, we define domestic outsourcing as firms or governmental entities located in the U.S.
contracting with other firms or individuals located in the U.S. for the provision of goods and
services. In this definition, we include the outsourcing of functions that used to be performed
in-house, new activities that have emerged as contract services from the start, and activities
that have always been outsourced but where the scale or nature of the outsourcing has
changed. Types of contractors include suppliers or vendors of goods (such as manufacturing
inputs) or services (such as business services or staffing firms), franchisees, and independent
contractors (such as freelancers, independent consultants, or on-demand platform workers). 2
In order to capture important changes in the organization of work across firms and its
implications for workers, our definition of domestic outsourcing is broad in scope. Given that
research on this topic is at an early stage, we think it is prudent to take an empirical approach
to identifying the range of forms that outsourcing may take, rather than eliminating certain
2
We only include true independent contractors in this definition, though in practice, misclassification may be one
of the strategies that accompany contracting out.
7
categories from the start. This will help ensure that we capture the full extent of change in the
organization of production and its impact on workers. We do not, for example, limit the
definition of domestic outsourcing to purchased services, as in Yuskavage, Strassner, and
Medeiros (2008). 3 Note that while we include purchases of both goods and services in our
definition, not all contracting for materials and services inputs are of interest. For example,
firms have always purchased office supplies, and absent any indication that the scope or nature
of contracting for these products has significantly changed, the contracting for office supplies
would not be a good candidate for study. In contrast, there has been significant restructuring
of domestic manufacturing supply chains with greater reliance on suppliers and subcontractors,
and the changing relations of power between primary and contractor firms have important
implications for the quality of jobs and inequality. In practice, researchers may choose to focus
their analysis on a particular industry; certain types of outsourced functions, such as business
support services; or one form of contracting, such as franchising.
Figure 1 distinguishes between several levels of analysis that research on domestic outsourcing
should examine. A first distinction is between changes at the firm level, in the organization of
production, and changes at the job or workplace level, in the organization of work (Grimshaw,
Willmott, and Rubery 2005). Ultimately, we are interested in the effects of domestic
outsourcing on job quality and workers, but this first distinction requires understanding
changes in the organization of production at the firm level. Outsourcing is an action by a firm
and should be defined and measured at that level; this is the first level of analysis. The
empirical question then becomes, what is the impact of firm-level outsourcing decisions on the
organization of work at the establishment level and, by extension, the quality of jobs. This is
the second level of analysis. In addition, the potential growth of on-demand gig work as well as
other forms of job fragmentation suggest a third level of analysis: worker outcomes across jobs.
Here, the question is how workers are bundling multiple forms of income-generating work to
achieve economic security, and how they are building careers across jobs and over time.
An important feature of our framework is that it clarifies the relationship between domestic
outsourcing and contingent or nonstandard work. Although there is no consensus on what
constitutes “nonstandard” employment, to illustrate how it differs from work that has been
outsourced, we use the categories identified in the BLS CPS Supplement on Contingent and
Alternative Work Arrangements: direct-hire temporaries, agency temporaries, on-call workers,
day laborers, contract workers performing work at the client’s worksite, and independent
3
For other examples of related definitions, see Berlingieri (2014); Brown, Sturgeon, and Lane (2014); and Weil
(2014).
8
contractors. By contrast, standard jobs follow the structure of the traditional employment
relationship in the U.S.: workers are employees of the firm, and while employment in the U.S. is
“at-will,” there is an implicit contract of permanent employment.
As shown in Figure 2, jobs at contractor firms may be standard or nonstandard; the same is true
for in-house jobs. This point is critical: Contractor firms may be small fly-by-night shops offering
spot employment or large multinational corporations – such as Aramark or Securitas – offering
standard employment contracts. As a result, there is nothing inherently contingent or
nonstandard about jobs at contractor firms, and outsourcing’s impact on the organization of
work and job quality is not predetermined. We suspect that in some industries, nonstandard
jobs may be more prevalent at contractor firms, as is the case in call centers (Batt, Holman, and
Holtgrewe 2009), but establishing this relationship (and understanding its determinants) is an
empirical question. Similarly, how other job quality outcomes (such as wages, benefits, hours,
schedules, and workplace safety) map onto each of the employment relationships in the table is
an empirical question.
9
Figure 2. Relationship between Contracting Out and Employment Status
Firms in every sector of the economy contract with other firms as part of their production
process, as do governmental entities. The functions that are outsourced vary widely, and even
a cursory sampling shows considerable diversity: human resources and R&D functions, building
services, recycling, regulation and compliance, accounting, credit card collections, call centers,
mortgage and check processing, information technology and data processing, logistics and
transportation, machine maintenance, cable installation, food services and food processing,
parts manufacturing and assembly, laundry, housekeeping, diagnostic labs and MRI scans, and
clinical research trials.
The structure of firm-level contracting relationships is similarly varied. Based on the existing
research literature, we have identified several different examples, depicted in the figures
below. The figures illustrate the variety and complexity of contracting structures and are meant
to be suggestive, not exhaustive. Moreover, existing research does not document the
prevalence of any of these forms; that is an empirical question for future research.
The archetypal image of firm-to-firm contracting is the linear supply chain. For example, in
Figure 3a, we illustrate the food supply chain in the U.S., showing the classic line of contracting
from agriculture all the way through to firms that sell food to consumers (which may be
contractors themselves, as in the case of food services companies). But domestic contracting
also includes a wide array of business-to-business transactions that are not well captured by the
supply chain paradigm. In Figure 3b, we illustrate what Barenberg (2015) calls the “hub and
spoke” model of contracting, where the lead firm (in this case a building owner) contracts with
a number of other firms for on-site services such as cleaning and security and off-site services
such as insurance. Note that one could flip this diagram and place a major business services
10
contract firm (such as Compass) at the hub and identify its contracts with a wide range of
clients via the spokes. Figure 3c illustrates a non-hierarchical production network, featuring
continuous collaboration between video game publishers, console manufacturers, and software
developers and designers (Balland, De Vaan, and Boschma 2013). Figure 3d shows the classic
pyramidal franchising structure that is prevalent in fast food and other industries (Weil 2014).
Finally, in Figure 4 we use the hotel industry to illustrate how several different contracting
structures operate together to deliver a set of final services to the consumer (adapted from
Barenberg [2015, Figure 7]; see also Weil [2014]). The figure shows the franchising structure of
a hotel brand, the services contracting of a particular hotel, the logistics contracting chain for
delivering furniture and linens, and the use of independent contractors in the case of trucking
and temp staffing firms in the case of warehouses. Note that this diagram could be expanded
to include many more nodes of contracting, such as the use of staffing firms by the
manufacturers or the contracting by the security services company with other clients besides
the hotel franchise.
11
These descriptive diagrams raise a host of important questions, both about the contracting
relationships themselves and about their impact on workers. How prevalent is domestic
contracting and how has it changed over time? What factors are driving it and how does it vary
by industry, occupation, firm-level strategies, and other organizational characteristics? And
how do these different models of contracting out affect the organization of work within and
across firm boundaries and, by extension, the quality of jobs, inequality, and other labor market
outcomes?
In the next three sections, we review existing theories and empirical research to identify what is
known about the causes and consequences of outsourcing on labor market outcomes. In the
final section, we propose a major research initiative designed to significantly strengthen the
body of knowledge about this important but understudied economic trend.
12
3. Why Do Firms Contract Out, and What Explains Variation in Their Strategies?
Central to theories of the firm is why, or under what conditions, they choose to make versus
buy goods and services. Social science research explained the vertical integration of firms over
most of the 20th century by arguing that internal production was more efficient than
contracting out. Today the challenge is to explain an observed shift towards outsourcing.
In this section, we review the recent literature on outsourcing from economics, management
sciences, industrial relations, and sociology. Overall, we find that most scholars agree that
domestic outsourcing has increased, albeit for different reasons. While some privilege the role
of new technologies that facilitate outsourcing, others emphasize the role of heightened global
competition or the role of deregulation of capital and labor markets that shift the balance of
power from labor to capital. These changes have affected firms’ make-or-buy calculations. This
literature, however, does not provide sufficient fine-grained analyses about the factors driving
change or why the use of outsourcing varies across specific industries, occupations, or business
functions, and it largely fails to address the implications for workers.
To explain the make or buy decision, economic and management theories have focused
primarily on the relative costs of internal versus external production. They explain recent
changes in terms of technological advances that have reduced the relative costs of outsourcing.
Chandler, for example, focuses on relative production costs (Chandler 1977, 1990). He argues
that advances in transportation and communications technologies at the end of the 19th
century led to the rise of a mass market and to mass production. Firms achieved higher
productivity via “economies of throughput” – by processing a large volume of inputs through
dedicated, high fixed-cost machinery. From this perspective, vertical integration of the supply
chain followed because firms needed a steady supply of inputs and stable consumer demand.
In addition, managerial expertise was critical for internal coordination of processes and ongoing
improvements in productivity, growth, and market share (Helper and Sako 2010, 403ff).
Mass production manufacturing was undermined in the 1980s, according to Chandler and
others, by the rise of international competition and the availability of new production and
management technologies. Flexible manufacturing technologies allowed factories to produce a
greater variety of goods in small batches, enabling decentralized production in flexibly
specialized firms (Piore and Sabel 1984). Japanese lean production, characterized by lead firms
controlling manufacturing processes in a complex web of supplier firms (Dore 1986), achieved
higher levels of innovation, lower time-to-market for new products, and higher quality and
13
productivity than mass production models (Jaikumar 1986, MacDuffie 1995). U.S. firms tried to
emulate lean production by increasing their use of contracting out and reconfiguring their
supply chains.
More broadly applicable across service as well as manufacturing industries is the transactions
cost framework (Coase 1937), which explains the make or buy decision on the basis of relative
transaction costs. Williamson (1975, 1985) argues that the vertically integrated firm emerged
in the 20th century because hierarchies are more efficient than markets. Hierarchies minimize
the costs of transactions between buyers and sellers because we live in a world of bounded
rationality (limited ability to process information), asset specificity (nonstandard, idiosyncratic
capital goods or skills that are especially valuable in the relationship), and individual
opportunism (self-interested behavior with guile). Consequently, by retaining production in-
house, firms minimize transaction costs and have more mechanisms to control or limit
opportunism.
In this framework, supply-side changes that reduce the cost of market transactions relative to
internal hierarchies explain the recent vertical disintegration of firms. New information and
communications technologies (ICT) have facilitated outsourcing and the decentralization of
producing goods and services because ICT lowers the costs of information processing and
coordination of work across organizational boundaries, thereby reducing the cost advantages of
internal production. ICT also enhances firms’ capabilities to monitor and enforce contracts with
external suppliers, thereby reducing the relative advantages of hierarchy. ICT allows firms to
achieve control over productive activities – the advantages of vertical integration – without
assuming the risks of actual ownership or the inflexibility of bureaucracy. Blois (1972) refers to
this as “vertical quasi-integration,” and others as “virtual integration.”
These supply-side arguments are typically combined with demand-side arguments – that
reductions in product market regulation have heightened cost competition and increased
incentives to outsource based on cost. These changes include not only trade liberalization in
global markets but also deregulation since the 1970s in service industries such as airlines,
telecommunications, transportation, banking, and health care.
Academic scholars, however, have not only tried to explain changes in firm behavior, many
have actively promoted new decentralized organizational models, especially advocates of
agency theory and core competency theory. Inspired by Milton Friedman’s (1970) argument
that profit maximization is the sole purpose of the corporation – and reacting to the poor
profitability of large conglomerates in the 1970s – a generation of agency theorists provided
14
the rationale for breaking up large corporations and selling off or outsourcing less-profitable
operations.
Large publicly-traded firms, they reasoned, suffer from principal-agent problems because
dispersed shareholders (the principals) are not able to hold opportunistic managers (the
agents) sufficiently accountable -- allowing them to make decisions that favor their own
interests at the expense of shareholders (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Jensen 1986). As a result,
managers could engage in a variety of behaviors that are assumed to interfere with maximizing
profits and shareholder value, such as building large conglomerates or negotiating better wages
and working conditions.
As Weil (2014) and Goldschmidt and Schmieder (2015) have pointed out, these large companies
tended to offer jobs with higher wages and employment security due to union contracts (Card,
Lemieux, and Riddell 2004), internal equity concerns (Weil 2014), or efficiency wage
considerations that higher wages and better treatment of workers would elicit greater labor
productivity (Akerlof and Yellen 1990; Rees 1993). In the U.S., where the union-non-union
wage gap is large, firms faced with increased competition or shareholder pressures have
incentives to reduce costs by outsourcing work to lower-cost or non-union providers.
Agency theory provides the rationale for eliminating these uses of corporate earnings, including
the rent sharing of firm profits with workers. In this view, retained earnings should be returned
to shareholders rather than spent on business expansion or above-market wages. Less-
profitable operations should be sold off, with returns going to shareholders. Thus, agency
theory provided the rationale for breaking up corporations – as exemplified by corporate
raiders in the 1980s – who bought up undervalued companies with poor stock market
performance and sold off or closed divisions to increase shareholder value. These strategies
soon became widespread.
While agency theory provided the overarching argument for maximizing shareholder value, it
did not translate this theory into specific business strategies. That was taken up by
management strategists who argued that firms could achieve “competitive advantage,” and
hence higher profitability for shareholders, by focusing on their “core competency” – that is,
what they do best. In this view, the diversified conglomerate of the 1960s and 1970s unraveled
because it lacked sufficient focus and the competence to effectively manage diverse productive
activities. Firms, it is argued, should compete by pursuing a single-minded business strategy –
for example, as a low-cost producer or by providing differentiated products (Porter 1985).
Firms become “best in class” by focusing resources and talent on their core competencies and
eliminating other lines of business (Prahalad and Hamel 1990). Firms achieve competitive
15
advantage by capitalizing on their unique resources (Penrose 1959) and investing in difficult to
imitate human resource (HR) systems that enhance human and social capital (Barney 1991).
The core competency argument justifies organizational restructuring at two levels: the business
unit level and the operational or task level. At the business unit level, firms are admonished to
sell off those businesses that are not best in class – hence, for example, hiving off entire
product divisions or business functions. At the operational level, management scientists argue
that firms should assess the “strategic value-added” of each task in their core business units
and outsource lower valued-added activities as well as ancillary services, such as routine HR
administration or customer service operations (Lepak and Snell 1999). This line of reasoning
justifies a specialized division of labor, with more value-added or knowledge-producing
activities retained in-house and less-value-added activities outsourced.
The knowledge-based view of the firm reaches similar conclusions (Kogut and Zander 1992).
Firms should keep in-house those tasks or capabilities that are complex and difficult to codify or
that the firm already has and believes will contribute to innovation or higher economic value. It
will outsource tasks that are easily codifiable or tasks in which other firms have already
developed expertise.
Again engineering and management scholars cited advances in technology and the digital
revolution to explain why the ability to codify and standardize knowledge – and hence
outsource it – has increased. They have elaborated the design principle of “modularity” – that
is, the decomposition of complex systems into separable design elements. This enables firms to
codify knowledge of a production process, identify separable parts, and standardize the
interfaces. When done effectively, modularity reduces costs, increases the speed of innovation,
and increases returns to specialization (Ulrich and Eppinger 1995; Fixson 2005). It also reduces
the probability of contractor opportunism given the ability to standardize and specify product
design features (Helper, MacDuffie, and Sabel 2000). While modularity has focused on goods
production, codification of information and knowledge applies equally to business functions
and service activities such as business process outsourcing, law, accounting, banking, and other
customer-facing operations. Deblaere and Osborne (2010) argue that services have been
broken into their components and optimized through automation and standardization. This,
they contend, has created economies of scale that make external provision of inputs more
efficient than internal production.
The rise of the computer industry and the digital revolution also help explain the rise of a new
model of business organization – a horizontally specialized structure as opposed to a vertically
integrated one. Saxenian’s (1996) research demonstrating the superior performance of
16
networked firms in Silicon Valley compared to hierarchical firms in the MIT corridor is
illustrative, as are Powell and colleagues’ (1996) study of the U.S. biotech industry and a
number of studies of the ICT industry (Fine 1998; Kraemer and Dedrick 2002; Fields 2004). Firms
in other industries have tried to apply this networked form to their own organizations.
In contrast to the economics and management literatures, other scholars have advanced
institutional and political explanations for the demise of the vertically integrated firm. From
these perspectives, U.S. corporations grew and prospered during most of the 20th century
based on a managerial business model in which experienced managers with industry-specific
expertise were the source of on-going improvements in firm performance (Chandler 1977).
Separation of ownership from organizational control ensured that managers could focus on
long-term productivity growth rather than short-term shareholder profits, and long
organizational careers reduced opportunism by tying managers’ individual fortunes to firm
outcomes (Lazonick 1992).
That model depended on banking and securities laws put in place in the New Deal, as well as on
labor market regulation and union cooperation. Internal labor market theory argues that large
employers established internal administrative rules and provided benefits and promotion
opportunities to secure a loyal workforce and to ensure labor peace; unions negotiated
seniority clauses and internal job ladders to enhance job and income security (Doeringer and
Piore 1971; Jacoby 1985). Non-union firms mimicked union rules (Foulkes 1980).
That model began to unravel in the 1960s and 1970s due to a series of institutional changes
both inside and outside of the firm (Davis 2009). Internally, U.S. corporations increasingly
focused on growth through mergers and acquisitions, giving rise to diversified conglomerates.
Under this “portfolio model of the corporation,” the frequent buying and selling of businesses
created a new norm of viewing companies as bundles of assets to be bought and sold (Hayes
and Abernathy 1980). Decision-making power shifted from line managers with production
expertise to chief financial officers, who bought and sold units based on their profitability
(Fligstein 1990; Lazonick 1992; Zorn 2004).
This concept of the firm as akin to Lego pieces that can be assembled and reassembled based
on short-term profit goals has received growing attention. Some scholars particularly
emphasize the deregulation of capital markets and labor markets from the 1970s on to explain
the vertical disintegration of the firm and the growth of outsourcing (Appelbaum and Batt
2014). In this line of reasoning, financial market deregulation gave investors and stockholders
17
more power to pressure firms to maximize shareholder value, and the lax enforcement of labor
laws and the decline of union power freed them from prior constraints to do so.
The shift in the relative power of capital and labor encouraged firms to maximize profits in part
by selling off business units or outsourcing less-profitable parts of the value chain. Firms exited
low-margin activities and retained those with high margins to increase earnings that could be
returned to shareholders via higher dividends or stock buybacks, which increased share price
(Lazonick 2014). CEOs would implement these strategies because their own pay was
increasingly tied to stock market performance (Jensen and Murphy 1990). Stock option pay
represented 20 percent of CEO compensation in 1980 but 50 percent in 1994 (Hall and Liebman
1998).
Capital market deregulation occurred through a series of legislative changes. The power of
institutional investors to influence corporate behavior increased with passage of the
Employment Retirement Income Security Acts (ERISA) of 1974 and 1978, which allowed pension
funds and insurance companies to invest in stock and high risk bonds for the first time (Useem
1996; Gompers and Metrick 2001; Zorn et al. 2005: 274). Some argue that the rise of
institutional shareholders in the 1980s was critical in shifting the balance of power from
corporate stakeholders (managers and workers) to shareholders (Donaldson 1994).
Similarly, in the 1980s, relaxed enforcement of antitrust and securities laws and the elimination
of state antitakeover laws (Jarrell 1983) gave corporate raiders greater leeway to engage in
hostile takeovers and sell unprofitable businesses or increase outsourcing to improve profit
margins. To hedge against hostile takeovers, corporations themselves started engaging in these
strategies (Holmstrom and Kaplan 2001: 132-4).
Further deregulation of banking since the 1990s facilitated the growth of financial
intermediaries such as private equity firms that engage in leveraged buyouts and activist hedge
funds that are able to overthrow CEOs or force changes in business strategies based on
ownership of a relatively small percent of a company’s stock. These actors often insist on the
sell-off of assets, divestment of less-profitable establishments, and greater use of outsourcing
(Appelbaum and Batt 2014; Brav, Jiang, and Kim 2015).
Labor market deregulation occurred as global labor markets expanded (Freeman 2005) and as
U.S. labor laws went unenforced. The decline in union density and power allowed firms to
outsource work either to rid themselves of expensive and time-consuming union contracts or to
prevent unions from organizing new units. De-unionization in manufacturing also diminished
those unions’ resources for organizing new unions in emerging sectors within the U.S.
18
Similarly, deregulation of service industries with traditionally high union density also
contributed to de-unionization, the intensification of competition from non-union competitors,
and the ability of firms to shift work to contractors. Examples of this pattern have been
documented in trucking (Belzer 1994; Milkman 2008), construction and building services
(Milkman 2006), and call centers (Batt, Holman, and Holtgrewe 2009: 458ff). Organizing
campaigns in service industries have yielded single-digit union density in almost all cases.
Union administrative failure (Piore 1989) and inter-union conflicts have also led to the decline
in union power. Beyond voiding or minimizing the power of unions, companies may use
outsourcing to avoid accountability for other U.S. labor and employment laws, including wage
and hour, prevailing wage, workers’ compensation, health and safety, pension, and anti-
discrimination statutes (Weil 2014).
In sum, academic theory and research points to an array of explanations for the vertical
disintegration of firms across a wide range of industries, as well as why new forms of business
organization based on interfirm networks are emerging and becoming institutionalized. While
much of the research and theorizing has focused on globalization and the rise of global supply
chains, none of the theories identified here are specific to that international process. Rather,
they attribute outsourcing to heightened competitive pressures – whether in traded or
nontraded goods – and to technological, organizational, regulatory, and political changes that
affect how firms decide where to produce goods and services.
While there is a growing consensus that more networked forms of business organization have
emerged, academic research offers few insights into why the prevalence and forms of
outsourcing vary across different industries, firms, or productive activities. Below we identify a
few approaches that provide a starting point for thinking about how and why firms vary in their
approaches to outsourcing.
Two frameworks take an economic or functionalist approach, arguing that variation in how
firms use outsourcing depends on the product market in which they compete and their
organizational capabilities. One framework identifies three functions of outsourcing (Holmes
1986). First, if firms operate in markets with high or uncertain demand fluctuation, they may
outsource overflow work (capacity contracting) to meet increases in demand without investing
in expensive equipment that may lie idle during economic downturns. Second, if the
production of particular products requires specialized inputs, they may take advantage of
contractors who have particular expertise or sophisticated technology (specialization
subcontracting). Third, firms may choose, for a variety of reasons that are not clearly
19
understood, to turn over large parts of the production process to an independent supplier
(supplier subcontracting). Each of these strategies shifts risks to contractors and has the
potential to both improve revenues for the firm (via higher quantity or quality of production)
and reduce costs (due to contractor efficiency, absorption of risk, investments in technology, or
payment of lower wages in non-union settings). In this framework, variation in outsourcing
depends on the particular characteristics of goods or services produced and differences in the
competitive conditions of markets. Hypercompetitive and volatile markets or industries
characterized by rapid innovation are more likely to use all three types of contracting.
A second framework for why firms vary in their use of outsourcing is based on specific product
characteristics (Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon 2005). This framework integrates insights
from transaction costs economics, production networks, and dynamic capabilities
(organizational learning) to create a typology of five different types of networks – market,
modular (turnkey), relational, captive, and integrated. Gereffi and colleagues argue that
variation depends on three factors: the complexity of information and knowledge to be
transferred across firm boundaries, the extent to which this information and knowledge can be
codified and transferred, and the capabilities of contracting firms and individuals.
Variation also arises because industries and firms differ in the point at which they begin to
outsource parts of production and how much they learn over time. Research on organizational
learning and dynamic capabilities shows that firms may produce the same good with different
production costs (Teece 1988; Teece, Pisano, and Shuen 1997; Kogut and Zander 1992), and as
new technologies or capabilities change, firms’ make or buy decisions can change as well
(Langlois 1992). As suppliers learn over time, they can increase the scale and scope of what
they do, develop greater sophistication, and take on increasingly complex processes or bundled
services. As primary firms become more confident of the quality and reliability of their services,
the use of suppliers is likely to become permanent or institutionalized (Sturgeon 2002; Saxenian
2005). Gereffi and colleagues argue more generally that this learning process is likely to lead to
a permanent shift away from hierarchical and captive forms towards relational, modular, and
market forms.
Other management scholars and sociologists argue that variation in supplier networks is shaped
by the level of trust between partners. The repeated interactions of people in interfirm
networks over time should create norms of trust that reduce the likelihood of individual
opportunism (Powell 1990; Uzzi 1996). Higher trust leads to better performance outcomes
(MacDuffie and Helper 2006), suggesting also that networked firms should become stable or
institutionalized over time. The argument that trust matters in relational contracting contrasts
20
sharply with modularity arguments, in which trust is not essential (Helper, MacDuffie, and Sabel
2000; Sturgeon 2002).
The structure of governance may also help explain variation in interfirm networks and
outcomes among contracting parties (Bair 2009). By governance we mean the set of rules and
practices that establish the balance of power and control among the lead and contractor firms.
This includes not only contractual obligations between the parties as set forth in legal
agreements, but also the ways in which the various actors in the contracting network exert
control over other participants. An analysis of who holds the power of decision-making and
monitoring and enforcement of rules should help explain how value is created, appropriated,
and distributed among actors in the production network. Variation in the governance
structure, then, should also have important implications for the quality of jobs for workers,
depending on where in the production network they are employed.
Industrial relations scholars also emphasize the importance of relationships of power to explain
variation in contracting – whether, for example, regulations or unions constrain managerial
choice of business strategy. Variation in labor institutions, regulations, and union power shape
firm strategies for achieving labor flexibility, the extent of use of contingent or temporary
workers, and the use of outsourcing (Houseman and Osawa 2003; Doellgast, Sarmiento-
Mirwaldt, and Benassi 2016). Where unions have sufficient bargaining power, they are able to
limit outsourcing and negotiate the terms and conditions of its use (Doellgast, Sarmiento-
Mirwaldt, and Benassi 2016). Where unions have weak bargaining power, by contrast, firms
may actually outsource more in order to rid themselves of union contractual requirements and
costs, as in the case of Delphi Automotive Corporation, where 30,000 union jobs were
offshored when private equity owners took control (Appelbaum and Batt 2014). Thus, union
presence and power provide one explanation for why firms that compete in the same markets
may nonetheless have different approaches to the use of outsourcing.
In sum, existing research points to several factors that have driven the overall growth in
outsourcing, the break-up of vertically integrated firms, and the rise of new networked forms of
production. Technological advances and management innovations have reduced the
monitoring and coordination costs of arms-length transactions. New economic and
management theories have promoted the alignment of managerial and shareholder interests to
focus on profit maximization, leading firms to focus on high-value-added core activities and to
sell off or outsource lower-value-added processes. And the growth of competitive pressures on
firms has threatened margins and provided greater incentives to cut costs, in part via
outsourcing. At the same time, specific research is thin regarding variation in the extent of
outsourcing and the form it takes across industries, firms, and different productive activities.
21
These questions are at the cutting edge of new research on outsourcing and will require
consideration of a variety of economic, political, and legal factors.
Empirical research on the effect of outsourcing on the quality of jobs is limited. In the literature
reviewed in Section 3, the outcomes of interest are organizational performance,
competitiveness, or firm survival. Clearly, however, changes in the organization of production
at the firm level will spill over into changes in the organization of work, with implications for HR
management and job quality (Rubery, Earnshaw, and Marchington 2005).
Theories about why firms choose to outsource do, however, offer implicit predictions for what
is likely to happen to the quality of jobs, including pay, benefits, and working conditions such as
health and safety. Most suggest that job quality will be lower in outsourced operations,
although there is reason to expect variation as well. This section presents some working
hypotheses about how outsourcing affects the quality of jobs and inequality, the causal
mechanisms at work, and the scant empirical evidence on these questions.
The economic and management literatures – including transactions costs, core competency,
resource-based theories, and global value chain literatures – suggest that firms will retain in-
house more complex jobs and outsource those involving lower-value-added tasks with routine
to mid-range skill requirements. Tasks that are complex and require firm-specific skills will be
retained in-house, in this view, because of the challenge of monitoring and enforcing contracts.
The more granular arguments in the modularity literature clarify that these tasks are not
amenable to codification and standardization, and hence not easily outsourced without
sacrificing cost and quality. The resource-based view argues that higher-value-added tasks
associated with core competencies must be retained in-house to preserve the firm’s source of
competitive advantage, and the knowledge-based view argues that these unique resources are
the firm’s lifeline to innovation and sustainability.
In these scenarios, outsourcing changes the rules for determining wages for low-skilled
workers, from internal administrative rules in large firms to market-based pricing across firms.
Internal equity norms or efficiency wage considerations lead large primary firms to compress
the wage structure. When low-skilled tasks are outsourced, internal equity norms are broken
and workers in those jobs receive pay that more closely reflects the market wage for the
specific tasks they do. Workers are sorted into higher-paying jobs in primary firms and lower-
paying jobs in contractor firms according to differences in skill levels. Contractors supplying
22
low-valued-added or routine services also face tougher competitive conditions as barriers to
entry are low and price-based competitive bidding is common.
Recent empirical studies provide some evidence that this process of outsourcing lower-skilled
jobs results in substantial pay and benefit penalties in janitorial and guard services (Dube and
Kaplan 2010). Similarly, in their study of logistics, cleaning, security, and food services functions
using German administrative data, Goldschmidt and Schmieder (2015) document the dramatic
rise in outsourcing of these functions and the substantial decline in wages relative to similar
jobs that were not outsourced, contributing to the rise in German wage inequality since the
1980s. These studies attribute the lower wages for contractors to the loss of firm-specific rents
and to primary firm strategies to lower labor costs.
Batt and colleagues examine the impact of outsourcing on call center jobs based on
establishment-level survey research (Batt, Holman, and Holtgrewe 2009). Regression analyses
show systematic differences between union, non-union in-house, and outsourced operations,
with the latter scoring the lowest on virtually all dimensions of job quality, including
substantially lower pay, benefits, and discretion at work; they also show greater use of
electronic monitoring and part-time and contingent work (Batt, Doellgast, and Kwon 2006; Batt
and Nohara 2009). Doellgast and colleagues (2016) find similar wage penalties in studies of call
center outsourcing in Europe.
Weil (2014) argues that the quality of jobs and wages are likely to be worse in outsourced
operations because small contractors are more likely to violate labor and employment laws.
Typically they are less knowledgeable about what the law requires, have unsophisticated (or
no) human resources function, and have greater incentives to violate the law because their
profit margins are thinner. Small firms may also bargain contracts with lead firms that set
unrealistic performance requirements. Ji and Weil (2015), for example, find that non-
compliance with minimum wage and overtime regulations are much higher in franchisee than
in company-operated outlets and attribute this to differences in the profit models of the two
entities. Whereas franchisors earn their money through a royalty fee based on revenue
volume, franchisees depend on profit margins and have greater incentives to squeeze labor
costs.
Available evidence indicates that contracting out also is associated with a higher incidence of
workplace injuries. For example, U.S. research has found much higher injury rates among
contract workers in petroleum (Rebitzer 1995), mining (Muzaffar et al. 2013), and among
staffing agency workers in a variety of occupations (Morris 1999; Foley et al. 2014; Smith et al.
2010). Particularly in triangulated employment relationships, responsibility for safety training
23
may be unclear and fall through the cracks. In addition, employers with unsafe workplaces may
turn to independent contractors or contract companies for staffing in order to shed legal
liabilities and high workers’ compensation insurance costs, which are experience rated. 4
Finally, reputational effects, even for large contractors, may be less important for franchisees or
subcontractors than for primary firms that compete on their brand. And the lax enforcement of
labor and employment laws in the 2000s created a permissive context for contractors to evade
or violate labor regulation (Bernhardt, McGrath, and DeFilippis 2007; Bernhardt et al. 2008).
The question of whether these arguments also apply to outsourcing of higher skilled or “core”
workers has not been tested. Weil argues that the downward pressures on wages and working
conditions in outsourced operations should apply more generally, based on the assumption
that the lead firm has asymmetric power relative to suppliers or contractors. This allows the
lead firm to set the terms and conditions in contractual agreements and create a highly
competitive bidding process that puts downward pressure on profit margins and, in turn, wages
(Weil 2014: 15, 100). Compared to primary firms, small contractor firms also face higher costs
of capital and have less control over contract duration or renewal; this contractual uncertainty
may translate into greater job insecurity for workers and greater use of contingent labor by
contractor firms. These arguments, it should be noted, do not take into account cases where
contractor firms may be in a strong bargaining position due to their large size and the range of
services they provide or because they supply specialized expertise or technology.
Where large lead firms dictate terms and conditions to smaller contractor firms, domestic
outsourcing can lead to greater inequality in two ways. First, if it sorts higher-skilled and lower-
skilled workers into (large) primary and (small) contractor firms, then inequality between
different skill or occupational groups is accentuated because lower-skilled workers are removed
from the internal wage structures of large firms. The resource-based view of the firm hints that
inequality between in-house and outsourced jobs may be even greater than one would expect
based on core competency and human capital arguments alone. In effect, the “human
resources” retained in-house are quasi-fixed or valuable assets that require on-going
investment. Core workers in primary firms benefit not only from higher pay but also training
and participation in “high involvement work systems” that offer more opportunity (Appelbaum
et al. 2000). By contrast, routine labor in outsourced firms will be viewed as a variable cost to
be minimized and is unlikely to receive training investments. If outsourcing distributes workers
with the same skills and abilities into primary (large) and contractor (small) firms, then it is also
4
See Boden, Spieler, and Wagner (2016) for an expanded discussion of the issues and empirical evidence on
contracting out and workplace health and safety.
24
likely to increase within-group inequality by removing workers from internal labor markets in
large firms (Cappelli 1999; Bernhardt, Dresser, and Hatton 2003).
Findings from several recent studies suggest a general relationship between increased domestic
outsourcing and rising inequality, but do not provide enough detail to sort out the causal
mechanisms. Davis and Cobb (2010) find that inequality is inversely related to the proportion of
workers in the largest firms. A recent study using the Longitudinal Business Dynamics data base
and the Longitudinal Employer-Household Data (LEHD) finds that much of the growth in
earnings inequality in the United States since the 1970s is accounted for by increased
dispersion in earnings across establishments (Barth et al. 2014). Similarly, Handwerker and
Spletzer (2015) and Handwerker (2015) use data from the Occupational Employment Statistics
program to show that growth in the occupational concentration of workers in establishments
accounts for a large share of the growth in wage inequality.
In sum, these literatures provide economic, strategic, and political explanations for the
existence of lower-quality jobs in outsourced operations as well as for increased inequality.
Existing empirical findings are consistent with this argument for low-wage workers, but only a
small number of empirical studies have been carried out, and much more research is needed.
Other lines of research question the association between outsourcing and low job quality. The
literature on “strategic” or managerial choice has demonstrated that firms may compete
successfully in the same market on the basis of radically different business and production
strategies (Cappelli 1999; Berger 2005). Typologies of different types of contracting relations
(Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon 2005) suggest that the labor conditions that result from each
approach may be different. And a recent paper (Lakhani, Kuruvilla, and Avgar 2013) presents a
straightforward linear mapping between contractor types and employment systems, with a
market-based model (relying largely on contracting out) offering the lowest levels of skills and
job stability and the hierarchical model (with internal labor markets) offering the highest. No
empirical tests of this framework exist, although case studies of U.S. multinational firms show
that closer and longer-term relations with offshore suppliers tend to produce fewer labor
violations (Locke, Qin, and Brause 2007; Locke 2013). These types of studies are suggestive, but
they provide little guidance regarding the impact of outsourcing in the United States on the
quality of jobs and inequality.
The literature on trust and collaboration in supply chains similarly carries an implicit prediction
that variation in contracting relations along these dimensions should lead to variation in
25
employment systems. Some research has shown that trust and collaboration are key to
sustainability and high performance in supply chains (Dyer and Chu 2000; MacDuffie 2011); and
arguably, greater stability among contractors may well benefit workers via enhanced employee
training, autonomy, and employment stability. But no empirical research has tackled this
question.
The specific terms of contractual agreements also matter. Lead firms set forth explicit and
detailed specifications in legal agreements with their contractors, and these requirements and
the incentive structures they create vary substantially across different types of contract or
franchising agreements (Weil 2014: 63-79). Any theory of the impact of domestic contracting
on the quality of jobs should examine the terms and conditions of vendor contracts; the relative
asymmetry between the primary and contractor firms; the mechanisms for monitoring,
enforcement, renewal, or termination of contracts; the duration and certainty of contract
renewal; and the business model of contractors.
Finally, some studies show that the jobs and conditions for managerial and professional
employees may improve when they move to specialized contractors. Dieticians and food
service managers, for example, generally have better job promotion opportunities if they work
for a contract food service company than if they are the direct-hire employee of an individual
hospital, school, or other establishment with a cafeteria (Erickcek, Houseman, and Kalleberg
2003). By contrast, research on the unbundling of corporate functions (law, accounting, HR
functions, shared services) provides no clear evidence regarding the quality of jobs in
outsourced high-skilled occupations (Sako, Chondrakis, and Vaaler 2013). Where access to
specialized services is the driving force in interfirm contracting, human capital theory suggests
that pay and working conditions should depend on the degree of specialization in each node of
the network.
In sum, the preponderance of theory predicts that workers in outsourced operations will
experience lower wages and job quality, and a handful of empirical studies support this claim,
but only for low-wage workers. But the causal mechanisms remain unclear or unspecified.
26
More broadly, there is a clear need for systematic empirical research that identifies a wider
range of outsourcing models and documents the relationship between the type of outsourcing
and the quality of jobs and inequality, specifies the causal mechanisms in this relationship, and
identifies the institutional conditions under which these relationships hold.
Most available data point to significant growth in domestic outsourcing in recent years.
Nevertheless, there are substantial gaps and, likely, biases in these data. In this section, we
review available evidence of the prevalence of and growth in domestic outsourcing, discuss the
limitations of existing data, and argue for the urgent need for better information.
One way to get a sense of the scope of the growth in domestic contracting out is to examine
employment growth in industries that primarily contract services to businesses. The relative
employment growth of professional and business services is especially notable because other
businesses are the principal consumers of these services, and consequently employment trends
in this sector are often used as a key indicator of outsourcing growth.5 The share of payroll
employment in professional and business services has nearly doubled from 7.3 to 13.9 percent
since 1970. Within professional and business services, about half of the growth was accounted
for by industries primarily employing workers in professional occupations (e.g., computer
systems and management and technical consulting) and about half in industries primarily
employing workers in nonprofessional occupations (e.g., security services, services to buildings
and dwellings, and temporary help and other staffing services).
While employment growth in professional and business services provides a useful indicator of
the growth of domestic outsourcing in the U.S., it is crude. Consumers account for some of the
higher demand for professional and business services, such as legal services. Moreover,
contract workers are employed in all sectors, and consequently a focus only on the professional
and business services sector will miss important developments occurring in other segments of
the economy. 6
5
Data on payroll employment come from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) program, a monthly
establishment survey conducted by the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
6
For example, food services contractors and airport and airline contractors are not classified in the professional
and business services sector, but instead are identified with their own codes under food services and support
activities for transportation, respectively. In other cases, contractors are not identified by distinct codes and are
27
Input-output data developed by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), in contrast,
provide a natural tool to comprehensively examine growth in domestic outsourcing. Input-
output (I-O) tables show the dollar value of the intermediate inputs one industry uses from
itself and from others, and any increase in outsourcing should appear as an increase in the use
of intermediate inputs by the outsourcing industry. 7 By linking the industry providing the
contract services with the user industry, input-output data show not only trends in outsourcing
but also variations across industries in outsourcing patterns. 8 In addition, I-O data, in
combination with employment data in the contract industry, permit estimation of the number
of workers affected by outsourcing.
Several studies have relied on I-O data to document the growth of domestic outsourcing in the
U.S. Using data on the input-output structure of the economy, Yuskavage, Strassner, and
Medeiros (2008) report that the share of GDP accounted for by domestic providers of
outsourcing services—which they defined as purchased services excluding telecommunications
and financial services—rose from 7 percent to 12 percent between 1982 and 2006. Similarly,
Berlingieri (2014) uses input-output data for the U.S. economy to examine the extent to which
the shift in U.S. employment from manufacturing to services is the result of outsourcing.
Controlling for changes over time in demand for manufactured products and services, he
concludes that a substantial share of the increase in services employment and the decline in
manufacturing employment is the consequence of outsourcing. Services previously housed in
manufacturing firms have been outsourced to service firms, highlighting the importance of
outsourcing to professional and business services as noted above. Other evidence supports this
conclusion. Dey, Houseman, and Polivka (2012) estimate that by 2006, staffing services
(primarily temporary agencies) added close to 10 percent to employment in manufacturing
establishments, compared to just 2 percent in 1989. Currently about half of the workers
needed for the production of manufactured goods are employed outside the manufacturing
sector (Timmer, Los, and de Vries 2015; Houseman 2014).
grouped with other establishments in a given industry (e.g., in mining and telecommunications, see Weil [2014]).
In these cases, subcontracting will show up as own-industry inputs in the I-O data – i.e., inputs purchased by firms
classified in the same industry. The increased share of employment in professional and business services also could
reflect other compositional changes, such as an increase in the relative size of industries that outsource, and do
not solely reflect changing staffing practices within industries.
7
Dollar values in the annual I-O tables may be deflated by the appropriate price indexes to yield real growth in
outsourcing.
8
I-O data can show differences in outsourcing across industries but not across firms within industries. In Section 6
we propose industry studies that, among other things, will help us understand variation in outsourcing practices
among firms.
28
Evidence from government household surveys
While statistics on industry employment and input-output tables are derived from business
surveys, government household surveys provide some additional evidence of the magnitude of
the contract workforce. Most notably, the Supplement on Contingent and Alternative Work
Arrangements (CWS) to the Current Population Survey (CPS), which was conducted five times
between 1995 and 2005, asks individuals about their status as temporary help workers,
independent contractors (including independent contractors and freelance workers), or
contract company workers. With respect to the last category, the survey focuses only on
individuals who work for a company that primarily contracts their services to one organization
and who work at that client’s worksite. This is a subset of contract company workers, many of
whom work off-site or at multiple client sites. One valuable feature of the CWS is that it
surveyed contract and temporary agency workers on the industry of the client firm, and so
constitutes the only source in federal statistics on where these types of workers perform
services.
In the 2005 survey, 7.4 percent of workers identified themselves as independent contractors,
independent consultants, or freelance workers. Another 0.9 percent and 0.6 percent indicated
that they worked, respectively, for temporary help agencies and other companies that
contracted out their services to one client (BLS 2005). The estimated share of the workforce in
temporary help agencies from the CWS, however, is roughly half the estimated share as
measured from the BLS establishment, which, as we discuss below, raises questions about the
accuracy of estimates from the CWS.
In 2015, the Rand American Life Panel Survey included many of the same questions asked on
the CWS (last conducted in 2005), along with questions on workers’ use of online platforms
(Krueger 2016). This new survey evidence suggests significant growth over the last decade in
various types of nonstandard employment arrangements, particularly in on-site contract
workers. The share of respondents identifying themselves as contract workers who work at the
client’s worksite jumped by more than fivefold from 0.6 percent in the 2005 CWS to 3.1 percent
in the 2015 American Life Panel Survey. 9 The share participating in on-line “gig” work is small,
accounting for only 0.5 percent of employment, according to the survey estimates.
9
Although the survey results are intended to be comparable to those from the CWS, the American Life Panel’s use
of an on-line survey format and possibly other methodological differences could account for some of the apparent
growth in contract and other nonstandard employment arrangements.
29
Evidence from employer surveys, industry research, and case studies
Drawing on a combination of government data, private surveys, and other proprietary sources
of information, researchers and analysts have been able to generate industry- or function-
specific estimates of the prevalence of (and sometimes trends in) domestic outsourcing. In
addition, case studies have provided detailed descriptions of the evolution of supply chains.
Academic researchers have conducted a number of employer surveys that, dating back to the
late 1980s, have pointed to the high incidence of and growth in domestic outsourcing (e.g.,
Abraham 1990; Houseman 2001; Kalleberg, Reynolds, and Marsden 2003; Nielson and Sturgeon
2014). For example, using information from the 2010 National Organizations Survey, which
included questions on private sector business use of contractors for various functions, Nielsen
and Sturgeon (2014) summarize the percent of businesses using domestic contractors for
facilities management (34 percent), IT systems (34 percent), transportation services (30
percent), sales and marketing (22 percent), R&D (20 percent), management, administration and
back-office functions (14 percent), and customer service (12 percent). A 2003 establishment-
level survey of U.S. call centers estimated that almost 15 percent of centers at the time were
outsourced operations, but because they were larger in size they employed almost 50 percent
of call center workers (Batt, Doellgast, and Kwon 2006: 336; additional Batt calculations of
original data).
Information routinely collected by consulting firms and industry trade groups on outsourcing
offers provides another source of nongovernmental data. Multiple surveys conducted by
national consulting firms have found that a majority of firms contract out at least some of their
HR functions, including payroll and benefits administration, background checks, training, and
recruitment (Greer, Youngblood, and Gray 1999). IT services constitute an important share of
services outsourcing, including data centers, help desk services, and training (Sharpe 2001).
Industry-specific surveys show substantial rates of contracting out for a wide range of functions
across many industries. One summary of proprietary data on insurance companies found high
rates of contracting out for a diverse set of services (Greenwald 1999). Almost 90 percent of
survey respondents reported that at least some use contractors for employee benefits
administration. For other services, the comparable figures were 85 percent for legal services,
81 percent for cafeteria services, 77 percent for janitorial and housekeeping, 61 percent for
security, 58 percent for payroll processing, and 47 percent for loss control. Similar surveys exist
for air transportation, banking, communications, construction, health care, hospitality,
manufacturing, mining, pharmaceuticals, and retail, among others (Bernhardt and Garrick
2013). Although the quality and representativeness of specific data from consulting firms and
industry trade groups are often hard to assess, the evidence from these sources consistently
points to a high incidence of contracting out of many business functions.
30
Researchers have also conducted industry case studies that yield detailed descriptions of the
evolution of supply chains. The critically important logistics sector is a case in point.
Deregulation of freight transportation in the 1980s, developments in information technology in
the 1990s, and growth of complex global supply chains have resulted in significant growth of
outsourcing in logistics (Bonacich and Wilson 2008). Examples include the shift to independent
contractor drivers in trucking and the growth of delivery services such as FedEx based on that
model; the contracting out of warehouses; and the rise of third-party logistics (3PL) companies
to which businesses outsource the management, transportation, and storage of goods and
information in their supply chains. Studies have described the dramatic rise during the 1990s
and 2000s in U.S. manufacturers’ outsourcing of transportation and warehousing, once core
functions of manufacturing firms (Baker and Hubbard 2003; Lieb and Bentz 2005; Belzer 2002;
Armbruster 2003). Use of 3PLs is common in all sectors, however, including retail, hospitality,
food and beverage, construction, and energy (Langley and Capgemini Consulting 2015). Large
companies commonly use multiple 3PLs and hire a firm to manage its outsourced logistics
functions (so-called fourth-party logistics companies, or 4PLs). Recent survey evidence suggests
that logistics outsourcing accounts for about half of business spending on transportation and
close to 40 percent of spending on warehouse activities (Leuschner et al. 2014). Third- and
fourth-party logistics companies are classified in various industries, including warehousing,
transportation, and wholesale trade, making it difficult to observe trends in logistics contracting
from published government statistics. 10
Data Limitations
While case studies have provided important insights into the growth of contracting out in
various sectors, the information is inherently fragmented and of varying quality. In theory,
surveys conducted by the U.S. statistical agencies should provide more systematic time-series
data for understanding the extent of outsourcing, its growth, and implications for workers and
public policy. But official statistics have substantial limitations.
BEA input-output data are useful for showing broad trends in domestic outsourcing in the
national economy and for identifying which industries that provide intermediate goods and
services are expanding. They are less useful, however, for identifying the user industries of
specific intermediates because the data on which the I-O tables depend are often dated and
suffer from significant gaps. Although annual industry surveys conducted by the census are
used to update the I-O tables, the most detailed information for estimating the I-O structure of
the economy comes from the Economic Census, conducted every five years. BEA uses
10
Other research has documented the growth in outsourcing of janitorial and security functions (Dube and Kaplan
2010), food services (Lane et al. 2003), and call centers (Batt, Holman, and Holtgrewe 2009; Batt, Doellgast, and
Kwon 2006).
31
information from the Economic Census and other sources to revise the I-O tables (and other
national accounts), and it typically takes 5 or more years to integrate the latest Economic
Census data into the accounts. Thus, at any point in time, much of the information used to
estimate the I-O structure of the economy is 5 to 10 years old.
More important, while the Economic Census collects detailed information on material input
purchases, information in the Economic Census and annual census surveys on purchased
services is generally collected for highly aggregated categories. For example, census surveys
ask companies to report expenditures on all professional and technical services. In addition,
the data reported combine expenditures on domestic and imported goods and services. 11 In
sum, published estimates of industry input use are often derived from limited information, and
researchers should use them with caution. 12
Workers in contract arrangements are employees of the company contracting their services or
are self-employed as independent contractors. Household and establishment surveys
conducted by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) do not systematically provide information on
the characteristics of workers in various contract arrangements or the organizations using the
contract services (see Bernhardt 2014). The Supplement on Contingent and Alternative
Employment Arrangements to the CPS was designed to help fill this information gap. Concerns
have been raised, however, about the ability of individuals (or family members answering on
their behalf) to properly identify themselves as employed in a contingent or alternative work
arrangement. As noted, the share of workers reporting themselves as employed by temporary
help agencies in the CWS is considerably lower than the share derived from the establishment
survey (CES), fueling concerns about the quality of data on workers in alternative
arrangements. The most recent CWS survey was conducted in 2005, and budget problems
stalled efforts to replicate it. The 2016 announcement that it will be conducted again in May
2017 is a welcome development. The narrow coverage of contract workers and concerns about
data quality in earlier rounds of the CWS have limited its usefulness for understanding the
scope of domestic contracting out and its implications for workers. Researchers have begun
providing input to BLS and the Census Bureau that may improve the usefulness of the new data
to be collected in 2017 and that may involve supplementing information collected in the CWS
with new information from establishment surveys.
11
To estimate imported and domestic intermediate goods and services separately, BEA makes the assumption that
each industry uses imported inputs in proportion to its overall use of the input in the economy.
12
In recent years, the Census Bureau has collected information on companies’ expenditures on temporary help
and professional employer organizations and has added questions to various surveys about whether companies
use or provide contract manufacturing services. While the collection of such detailed data is currently piecemeal,
it represents an important step toward improving data on outsourcing and will provide a more complete picture of
the incidence across industries of certain types of contract arrangements.
32
In sum, available information points to rapid growth in domestic outsourcing in a wide range of
industries since the 1980s. Yet, data gaps limit our ability to understand the magnitude of the
phenomenon and its impact on job quality, and to fashion appropriate policy responses. In the
next section we lay out a major initiative on domestic outsourcing, detailing the questions it
should answer and providing a menu of research methodologies and potential data sources.
Research Questions
We suggest that three broad questions should drive future research on domestic outsourcing.
While no single study will be able to address all of these questions, they provide a conceptual
roadmap for the knowledge base that needs to be created.
1. How common is domestic outsourcing, has it grown over time, and how many workers are
affected?
a. At the firm (or establishment) level, what is the prevalence of outsourcing, and has it
grown over time? Possible measures include percent of firms that contract for
particular functions, and firms’ purchases of goods and services from other firms (or
independent contractors) as a share of economic output.
b. How many workers are employed by contractors, has that number grown over time, and
do the workers differ in demographics from their in-house counterparts?
c. In which industries are contract workers employed? How have jobs been reallocated
across sectors over time as a result of domestic outsourcing?
33
labor market and product market regulation, unions and social movements, consumer
demands, and political pressures).
b. What is the role of technology in facilitating domestic outsourcing and the forms it
takes?
c. Do contracting strategies vary by industry segment, ownership structure, business
strategy, or other organizational characteristics? What explains variation in firms’
contracting decisions within and across particular industries or product networks?
d. What are the important characteristics and types of firm-to-firm contracting
relationships? In particular, how is bargaining power distributed, and which actors in a
production network are setting the economic terms of contracts? How are contractor
industries changing over time, in terms of the degree of consolidation or
competitiveness?
e. Where relevant, what is the relationship between international outsourcing strategies
and domestic outsourcing strategies? What determines the mix of the two strategies,
and do they influence one another?
3. What is the effect of domestic outsourcing on job quality and the employment relationship?
a. Job quality measures include wages, benefits, hours, workload, job stability, schedule
stability, occupational safety and health, incidence of wage theft, and access to training
and promotions.
b. The employment relationship refers to the worker’s status under employment and labor
laws (e.g., whether the worker is covered by those laws, who the employer of record is,
whether the job is permanent or temporary).
c. What is the effect of domestic outsourcing on unionization and other sources of worker
leverage in the labor market?
d. Does the impact of outsourcing on jobs and workers differ, and if so, what are the
sources of that variation? In particular, what is the role of specialized skills or skill
requirements of jobs?
Industry Studies
Few nationally representative datasets contain the types of measures and the detail needed to
capture the outsourcing phenomenon and its effect on job quality. Aggregate data also does
not lend itself to explaining the causal mechanisms linking changes in the organization of
production to changes in the quality of jobs. Moreover, the characteristics of contracting (such
as factors driving its use, its structure, and impacts on workers) vary substantially by industry
and business function. A broad undertaking of industry and firm-based research that engages a
cohort of researchers from diverse disciplines is needed to identify the factors that govern
interfirm contractual relationships, including the important role of the lead firm’s business
34
strategy, the relative bargaining power of lead and contractor firms, and the effects of variation
in these factors on wages and working conditions. In addition, because businesses increasingly
rely on contracting and supply chain management, trade associations and marketing and
consulting firms have become important players and may be the source of proprietary data on
a range of important industry trends. As a result, our assessment is that better data are often
available at the industry level.
We therefore propose the type of multi-method research design that is frequently used in
industry studies, combining analysis of (a) government data, including micro data from
government household and business surveys or administrative data (e.g., state Unemployment
Insurance wage records data available through Census Data Research Centers); (b) proprietary
or novel datasets from industry trade groups or marketing/consulting firms; (c) structured case
studies 13 of a number of firms and contractors, ideally chosen to understand different types of
contracting relationships; (d) interviews with industry experts, including unions where present,
and analysis of industry trade press and management publications; and (e) new data collection
where feasible. The exact mix of these components will vary across studies.
Given the variation in contracting relationships across different industry contexts, researchers
may decide to focus their studies in one of several ways:
• Contracting industries as the unit of analysis, such as financial services, retail, or hospitality.
• Contractor industries as the unit of analysis, such as professional and business services,
including information technology services, third-party logistics companies, and online
staffing platforms.
• Production networks as the unit of analysis, such as the health care sector, the logistics
sector, or the food supply chain.
• Business functions as the unit of analysis (see Nielsen and Sturgeon [2014] for a well-
developed categorization).
Examples of each of these approaches are found in the empirical studies we have cited in this
paper. The contracting industry approach is illustrated in Weil (2014) and Ji and Weil (2015) on
the hotel and other service industries. In this research, the authors combine extensive field
research with proprietary data and government administrative data to capture the relationship
between complex outsourcing structures, the quality of jobs, and labor law and safety and
health violations. The contractor industry approach is represented in the extensive research on
the temporary services industry, where the growth of the industry and its implications for
workers compensation, job stability, and long-term employment and earnings trajectories were
13
See, for example, the controlled case study design used by some researchers in Appelbaum, Bernhardt, and
Murnane (2003).
35
captured by combining government survey data (the Longitudinal Employer-Household Data
and Occupational Employment Statistics), government administrative data, proprietary
company data, and evidence from case studies and structured interviews. 14 Studies of the
logistics industry draw on the production network approach; for example, Bonacich and Wilson
(2008) combine industry data, interviews with industry experts, managers and workers, and
archival research to map out and analyze the impact of the logistics revolution in the U.S., using
southern California ports as their entry point. Finally, call center research has used the business
function as the unit of analysis (Batt, Holman, and Holtgrewe 2009; Batt and Nohara 2009; Batt,
Doellgast, and Kwon 2006). Given the lack of national data on business functions, that research
combined extensive field work in companies with a nationally representative random survey of
in-house and outsourced call centers whose frame drew on a database of 60,000 call center
subscribers to a trade journal. Results showed systematic differences in the wages, benefits,
job security, union coverage, and other job attributes of in-house and outsourced call center
jobs.
Even at the level of a specific industry, developing a research design to document and analyze
domestic outsourcing is conceptually difficult. One approach, developed by Gary Gereffi to
analyze commodity chains, identifies four analytical dimensions to consider: an input-output
structure, a geographical configuration, a governance structure, and an institutional context
(see Bair 2009). This approach may be useful because it highlights the importance of
integrating an analysis of changes in the economic structure as well power relations that shape
the distribution of outcomes among different firms and groups of workers.
14
Studies include Andersson, Holzer, and Lane (2005); Autor and Houseman (2006, 2010); Benner, Leete, and
Pastor (2007); Hamersma, Heinrich, and Mueser (2014); Heinrich, Mueser, and Troske (2005, 2009); Houseman
(2001); Houseman and Heinrich (2015); Kalleberg, Reynolds, and Marsden (2003); and Lane et al. (2003).
36
Note also that firms’ contracting decisions may change over time, with some functions being
outsourced only to be brought back in-house later, as the circumstances specific to a firm
change. More generally, in any industry at any point in time, some firms will outsource certain
functions as others bring the same functions back in-house. In analyzing the effect of
outsourcing over time in an industry or network, it will be important to identify the net changes
that constitute trends, along with the drivers behind those trends and their implications for
wages and working conditions.
In addition, important effects on wages and working conditions may originate from the
contractor firms themselves. Contractor industries may consolidate or fragment; new business
models and product markets may emerge; and regulatory or broader institutional contexts may
change. Even if the prevalence of domestic outsourcing does not change, such shifts on the
contractor side of the equation may have important implications for jobs and workers.
In selecting industries or production networks for study, researchers should have some a priori
evidence that a) the level of domestic outsourcing has significantly increased or the nature of
interfirm contracting relationships has changed, and b) these changes have potentially
important implications for compensation and other aspects of job quality. Based on our review
of the existing literature, some examples of important sectors for researchers to study include,
but are not limited to, the following:
• Health care: hospitals, outpatient facilities, nursing homes, home health care 15
• Logistics: transportation, warehousing, wholesale
• Professional and business services
• Computer and information technology
• Retail, restaurants, hotels, arts and entertainment
• Food supply chain
• Energy and utilities
• Finance, insurance, and real estate
• Pharmaceuticals, chemicals, and other bio-tech companies
• On-demand platforms: Uber, Upwork, TaskRabbit, etc.
• Public sector: federal, state, local
15
A detailed discussion of health care restructuring as an illustrative example is available from the authors.
37
restructuring has similar or differential effects on distinct groups in the occupational hierarchy,
potentially leading to greater or less inequality.
The industry studies proposed above would largely exploit available data from government
surveys and proprietary sources, combined with interview evidence, to shed light on the causes
and consequences of outsourcing in key industries. In addition, despite its weaknesses,
valuable insights may still be gained from using economy-wide data to arrive at benchmark
prevalence estimates. For example, to our knowledge, no recent analysis has comprehensively
examined patterns of growth in domestic outsourcing and the number and types of workers
affected using input-output data and industry employment matrixes for the U.S. economy.16
Similarly, tax data could be better leveraged to help resolve debates about the size of the
independent contractor workforce.
The second involves new data collection. Academic researchers and staff of government
statistical agencies should join efforts to develop new measures and data sources that will allow
precise estimates of domestic outsourcing and direct analysis of its impact on job quality. Given
the significant budget constraints on federal agencies, the priority should be on identifying
ways to leverage existing government surveys to gather more detailed data, add new measures,
and expand sampling frames; private funding could help pilot such changes. Academic
researchers could also develop and test new surveys – for example, of on-demand workers –
that could serve as models for future government surveys.
16
Clinton (1997) provides a useful example of triangulating trends in domestic contracting from employment,
occupational, and industry output and input data.
38
number of contract workers and their distribution by client industry (in addition to the industry
of their employer) may need to be collected from multiple surveys and estimates may need to
be modeled. Household surveys, such as the CWS, may provide the best vehicle for estimating
the number of on-site contract workers who typically work for one client and also the industry
of the client firm, though improvements to existing survey instruments may be desirable to
reduce reporting error. In contrast, it is unlikely that information on off-site contracting
relationships, which are more complex, can be reliably obtained from respondents to
household surveys. This information will need to be collected through establishment or firm
surveys, and the information collected in such surveys will be limited to information that
businesses typically maintain for tax and other accounting purposes. Because businesses that
outsource work do not systematically record information on the number of workers hired
through contractors—only their expenditures on contract services—contract services
expenditure data must be collected from businesses, and the number of contract workers by
client industry must be modeled. 17
Finally, and equally important, rigorously studying the effects of outsourcing on job quality will
often require the linking of data from various agencies at the federal and state level. This in
turn will require greater cooperation among agencies and improved access for researchers to
confidential government micro data. The planned addition of BLS data to existing census
research data centers is a good start and should be expedited.
17
Similarly, contract companies cannot consistently and reliably allocate their workers by client industry.
39
References
Abraham, Katharine G. 1990. “Restructuring the Employment Relationship: The Growth of Market-
Mediated Work Arrangements.” In New Developments in the Labor Market: Toward a New
Institutional Paradigm, Katharine Abraham and Robert McKersie, eds. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, pp. 85–119.
Akerlof, George A., and Janet L. Yellen. 1990. “The Fair Wage-Effort Hypothesis and
Unemployment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(2): 255–283.
Andersson, Fredrik, Harry J. Holzer, and Julia I. Lane. 2005. Moving Up or Moving On: Who Advances
in the Labor Market? New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Appelbaum, Eileen, Thomas Bailey, Peter Berg, and Arne Kalleberg. 2000. Manufacturing
Advantage. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, ILR Imprint.
Appelbaum, Eileen, and Rosemary Batt. 2014. Private Equity at Work: When Wall Street Manages
Main Street. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Appelbaum, Eileen, Annette Bernhardt, and Richard Murnane, eds. 2003 Low-Wage America: How
Employers are Reshaping Opportunity in the Workplace. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Armbruster, William. 2003. “Stacking Up: Manufacturers are Pleased with Gains from Outsourcing
of Warehouse Management.” Journal of Commerce December: 1–7.
Autor, David H., and Susan N. Houseman. 2006. “Temporary Agency Employment: A Way Out of
Poverty?” In Working and Poor: How Economic and Policy Changes Are Affecting Low-Wage
Workers, Rebecca M. Blank, Sheldon H. Danziger, and Robert F. Schoeni, eds., New York:
Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 312–337.
———. 2010. “Do Temporary Help Jobs Improve Labor Market Outcomes for Low-skilled Workers?
Evidence from ‘Work First.’” AEJ: Applied Economics 2(3): 96–128.
Bair, Jennifer. 2009. “Global Commodity Chains: Genealogy and Review.” In Frontiers of Commodity
Chain Research, Jennifer Bair, ed. Stanford: Stanford University Press, pp. 1–34.
Baker George P., and Thomas N. Hubbard. 2003. “Make versus Buy in Trucking: Asset Ownership,
Job Design and Information.” American Economic Review 93(3): 551–572.
Balland, Pierre-Alexandre, Mathijs De Vaan, and Ron Boschma. 2013. “The Dynamics of Interfirm
Networks Along the Industry Life Cycle: The Case of the Global Video Game Industry, 1987–
2007.” Journal of Economic Geography 13(5):741–765.
Barenberg, Mark. 2015. Widening the Scope of Worker Organizing: Legal Reforms to Facilitate
Multi-Employer Organizing, Bargaining and Striking. Roosevelt Institute Report. New York:
Roosevelt Institute. http://rooseveltinstitute.org/widening-the-scope-of-worker-organizing/
(accessed February 16, 2016).
Barney, Jay. 1991. “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage.” Journal of
Management 17(1): 99–120.
Barth, Erling, Alex Bryson, James C. Davis, and Richard Freeman. 2014. “It’s Where You Work:
Increases in Earnings Dispersion across Establishments and Individuals in the U.S.” NBER
Working Paper No. 20447. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Batt, Rosemary, Virginia Doellgast, and Hyunji Kwon. 2006. “Service Management and Employment
Systems in U.S. and Indian Call Centers.” In Brookings Trade Forum 2005: Offshoring White-
collar Work—The Issues and Implications, Susan M. Collins and Lael Brainard, eds.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, pp. 335–372.
40
Batt, Rosemary, David Holman, and Ursula Holtgrewe. 2009. “The Globalization of Service Work:
Comparative Institutional Perspectives on Call Centers.” Introduction to a Special Issue of
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 62(4): 453–488.
Batt, Rosemary, and Hiro Nohara. 2009. “How Institutions and Business Strategies Affect Wages: A
Cross National Study of Call Centers.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 62(4): 533–552.
Belzer, Michael. 1994. “The Motor Carrier Industry: Truckers and Teamsters under Siege.” In
Contemporary Collective Bargaining in the Private Sector, Paula Voos, ed. Madison, WI:
Industrial Relations Research Association, pp. 259–302.
———. 2002. “Technological Innovation and the Trucking Industry: Information Revolution and the
Effect on the Work Process.” Journal of Labor Research 23(2): 375–395.
Benner, Chris, Laura Leete, and Manuel Pastor. 2007. Staircases or Treadmills? Labor Market
Intermediaries and Economic Opportunity in a Changing Economy. New York: Russell Sage
Foundation.
Berger, Suzanne. 2005. How We Compete: What Companies around the World are Doing to Make it
in Today's Global Economy. New York: Random House and Doubleday.
Berlingieri, Giuseppe. 2014. “Outsourcing and the Rise of Services.” Centre for Economic
Performance Working Paper No. 1199. London: London School of Economics and Political
Science.
Bernhardt, Annette. 2014. “Labor Standards and the Reorganization of Work: Gaps in Data and
Research.” Institute for Research on Labor and Employment Working Paper No. 100-14.
Berkeley: University of California, Berkeley.
Bernhardt, Annette, Heather Boushey, Laura Dresser, and Chris Tilly. 2008. “Introduction.” In The
Gloves-Off Economy. Annual Research Volume, Labor and Employment Relations
Association. Champaign, IL: University of Illinois Press, pp. 1–29.
Bernhardt, Annette, Laura Dresser, and Erin Hatton. 2003. “The Coffee Pot Wars: Unions and Firm
Restructuring in the Hotel Industry.” In Low-Wage America: How Employers are Reshaping
Opportunity in the Workplace, Eileen Appelbaum, Annette Bernhardt, and Richard Murnane,
eds. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 33–76.
Bernhardt, Annette, and Jessica Garrick. 2013. “Interim Report: Research on the Prevalence and
Impact of Subcontracting in the U.S.” Manuscript. New York: National Employment Law
Project. On file at the UC, Berkeley Institute for Research on Labor and Employment.
Bernhardt, Annette, Siobhan McGrath, and James DeFilippis. 2007. “Unregulated Work in the Global
City: Employment and Labor Law Violations in NYC.” New York: Brennan Center for Justice,
New York University.
Boden, Leslie I., Emily A. Spieler, and Gregory R. Wagner. 2016. “The Changing Structure of Work:
Implications for Workplace Health and Safety in the U.S.” Paper prepared for the Future of
Work Symposium, U.S. Department of Labor.
Blois, K. J. 1972. “Vertical Quasi Organization.” Journal of Industrial Economics 20(3): 253–272.
Bonacich, Edna, and Jake Wilson. 2008. Getting the Goods: Ports, Labor, and the Logistics
Revolution. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, ILR Imprint.
Brav, Alon, Wei Jiang, and Hyunseob Kim. 2015. “The Real Effects of Hedge Fund Activism:
Productivity, Asset Allocation, and Labor Outcomes.” Review of Financial Studies 28(10):
2723–2769.
Brown, Clair, Timothy Sturgeon, and Julia Lane. 2014. “Using a Business Function Framework to
Examine Outsourcing and Offshoring by U.S. Organizations.” IRLE Working Paper No. 121-
41
14. Berkeley, CA: University of California, Berkeley.
http://irle.berkeley.edu/workingpapers/121-14.pdf (accessed February 16, 2016).
Cappelli, Peter, ed. 1999. Employment Practices and Business Strategy. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Card, David, Thomas Lemieux, and W. Craig Riddell. 2004. “Unions and Wage Inequality.” Journal of
Labor Research 25(4): 519–559.
Chandler, Alfred. 1977. The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
———. 1990. Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press (with assistance from Takashi Hikino).
Clinton, Angela. 1997. “Flexible Labor: Restructuring the American Work Force.” Monthly Labor
Review 120(8): 3–17.
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4(16): 386–405.
Davis, Gerald. 2009. Managed by the Markets: How Finance Reshaped America. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Davis, Gerald, and J. Adam Cobb. 2010. “Corporations and Economic Inequality around the World:
The Paradox of Hierarchy.” Research in Organizational Behavior 30: 35–53.
Deblaere, Jo G., and Jeffrey D. Osborne. 2010. “Industrialize and Innovate." Outlook (1).
Dey, Matthew, Susan Houseman, and Anne Polivka. 2010. “What Do We Know about Contracting
Out in the United States? Evidence from Establishment and Household Surveys.” In Labor in
the New Economy, Katharine G. Abraham, James R. Spletzer, and Michael J. Harper, eds.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 267–304.
———. 2012. “Manufacturers’ Outsourcing to Staffing Services.” Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 65(3): 533–559.
Doellgast, Virginia, Katja Sarmiento-Mirwaldt, and Chiara Benassi. 2016. “Institutions, Cost
Structures, and the Politics of Externalization: Explaining Variation in Boundary Strategies
for Call Center Jobs.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review.
Doeringer, Peter J., and Michael Piore. 1971. Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis.
Lexington, MA: Heath Lexington Books.
Donaldson, Gordon. 1994. Corporate Restructuring: Managing the Change Process from Within.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School.
Dore, Ronald. 1986. Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the Japanese
Economy, 1970–1980. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Dube, Arindrajit, and Ethan Kaplan. 2010. “Does Outsourcing Reduce Wages in the Low-wage
Service Occupations? Evidence from Janitors and Guards.” Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 63(2): 287–306.
Dyer, Jeffrey and Wujin Chu. 2000. “The Determinants of Trust in Supplier-Automaker Relationships
in the U.S., Japan, and Korea. Journal of International Business Studies 31(2): 259–285.
Erickcek, George, Susan Houseman, and Arne L. Kalleberg. 2003. “The Effects of Temporary Services
and Contracting Out on Low-Skilled Workers: Evidence from Auto Suppliers, Hospitals, and
Public Schools.” In Low-Wage America: How Employers Are Reshaping Opportunity in the
Workplace, Eileen Appelbaum, Annette Bernhardt, and Richard J. Murnane, eds. New York:
Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 368–403.
Fields, Gary. 2004. Territories of Profit: Communications, Capitalist Development, and the
Innovative Enterprises of GF Swift and Dell Computer. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University
Press.
42
Fine, Charles. 1998. Clockspeed: Winning Industry Control in the Age of Temporary Advantage. New
York: Perseus Books.
Fixson, S.K. 2005. “Product Architecture Assessment: A Tool to Link Product, Process, and Supply
Chain Design Decisions.” Journal of Operations Management 23(3-4): 345–369
Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Foley, Michael, John Ruser, Glenn Shor, Harry Shuford, and Eric Sygnatur. 2014. “Contingent
Workers: Workers’ Compensation Data Analysis Strategies and Limitations.” American
Journal of Industrial Medicine 57(7): 764–775.
Foulkes, Fred. 1980. Personnel Policies in Large Nonunion Companies New York: Prentice Hall.
Freeman, Richard. 2005. “China, India, and the Doubling of the Global Labor Force: Who Pays the
Price of Globalization?” Asia-Pacific Journal: Japan Focus 3(8). http://apjjf.org/-richard-
freeman/1849/article.html (accessed February 16, 2016).
Friedman, Milton. 1970. “The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits.” New York
Times Magazine, September 13: 32–33, 122–124.
Gautie, Jerome, and John Schmitt. 2010. Low-Wage Work in the Wealthy World. New York: Russell
Sage Foundation.
Gereffi, Gary, John Humphrey, and Timothy Sturgeon. 2005. “The Governance of Global Value
Chains.” Review of International Political Economy 12(1):78–104.
Goldschmidt, Deborah, and Johannes F. Schmieder. 2015. “The Rise of Domestic Outsourcing and
the Evolution of the German Wage Structure.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 9194. Bonn:
Institute for the Study of Labor.
Gompers, Paul, and Andrew Metrick. 2001. “Institutional Investors and Equity Prices.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 116(1): 229–259.
Gospel, Howard, and Mari Sako. 2010. “The Unbundling of Corporate Functions: The Evolution of
Shared Services and Outsourcing in Human Resource Management.” Industrial and
Corporate Change 19(5): 1367–1396.
Greenwald, Judy. 1999. “Insurers Outsource More Functions.” Business Insurance 33(34): 2–3.
Greer, Charles R., Stuart A. Youngblood, and David A. Gray. 1999. “Human Resource Management
Outsourcing: The Make or Buy Decision.” Academy of Management Executive 13(3): 86–96.
Grimshaw, Damian, Hugh Willmott, and Jill Rubery. 2005. “Inter-organizational Networks: Trust,
Power, and the Employment Relationship,” In Fragmenting Work: Blurring Organizational
Boundaries and Disordering Hierarchies, Mick Marchington, Damian Grimshaw, Jill Rubery,
and Hugh Willmott, eds. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 63–88.
Hall, Brian J., and Jeffrey B. Liebman. 1998. "Are CEOs Really Paid like Bureaucrats?" Quarterly
Journal of Economics 112(3): 653–691.
Hamersma, Sarah, Carolyn J. Heinrich, and Peter Mueser. 2014. “Temporary Help Work: Multiple
Job-Holding and Compensating Differentials.” Industrial Relations 53(1): 72–100.
Handwerker, Elizabeth. 2015. “Increased Concentration of Occupations, Outsourcing, and Growing
Wage Inequality in the United States.” BLS Working Paper. Washington, DC: Bureau of Labor
Statistics.
Handwerker, Elizabeth, and James Spletzer. 2015. “The Concentration of Occupations and the Role
of Establishments in Wage Inequality.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 9294. Bonn: Institute for
the Study of Labor.
Hayes, Robert H., and William J. Abernathy. 1980. “Managing our Way to Economic Decline.”
Harvard Business Review 58(4): 67–77.
43
Heinrich, Carolyn J., Peter R. Mueser, and Kenneth R. Troske. 2005. “Welfare to Temporary Work:
Implications for Labor Market Outcomes.” Review of Economics and Statistics 87(1): 154–
173.
———. 2009. “The Role of Temporary-Help Employment in Low-Wage Worker Advancement.” In
Studies of Labor Market Intermediation, David H. Autor, ed. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, pp. 399–436.
Helper, Susan, John Paul MacDuffie, and Charles Sabel. 2000. “Pragmatic Collaborations: Advancing
Knowledge While Controlling Opportunism.” Industrial and Corporate Change 9(3): 443–
488.
Helper, Susan, and Mari Sako. 2010. “Management Innovation in Supply Chain: Appreciating
Chandler in the Twenty-First Century.” Industrial and Corporate Change 19(2): 399–429.
Holmes, John. 1986. “The Organization and Locational Structure of Production Subcontracting.” In
Production, Work, and Territory, Allen Scott and Michael Storper, eds. Boston: Allen and
Unwin, pp. 80–106.
Holmstrom, Bengt and Steven N. Kaplan. 2001. “Corporate Governance and Merger Activity in the
United States: Making Sense of the 1980s and 1990s.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
15(2): 121–144.
Houseman, Susan N. 2001. “Why Employers Use Flexible Staffing Arrangements: Evidence From an
Establishment Survey.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 55(1): 149–170.
———. 2014. “Trade Competitiveness and Employment in the Global Economy.” Employment
Research 21(1): 1–4. http://research.upjohn.org/empl_research/vol21/iss1/1/ (accessed
February 16, 2016).
Houseman, Susan, and Carolyn Heinrich. 2015. “Temporary Help Employment in Recession and
Recovery.” W.E. Upjohn Institute Working Paper No. 15-227. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn
Institute for Employment Research. http://research.upjohn.org/up_workingpapers/227/
(accessed February 16, 20016).
Houseman, Susan, and Machiko Osawa, eds. 2003. Nonstandard Work in Developed Economies:
Causes and Consequences. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
Jacobides, Michael G. 2005. “Industry Change through Vertical Disintegration: How and Why
Markets Emerged in Mortgage Banking.” Academy of Management Journal 48(3): 465–498.
Jacobides, Michael G., and Sidney G. Winter. 2005. “The Coevolution of Capabilities and
Transaction Costs: Explaining the Institutional Structure of Production.” Strategic
Management Journal 26(5): 395–413.
Jacoby, Sanford. 1985. Employing Bureaucracy: Managers, Unions and the Transformation of Work
in American Industry 1900–1945. New York: Columbia University Press.
Jaikumar, Ramchandran. 1986. “Postindustrial Manufacturing.” Harvard Business Review 64(6): 69–
76.
Jarrell, Gregg A. 1983. “State Anti-Takeover Laws and the Efficient Allocation of Corporate Control:
An Economic Analysis of Edgar v. Mite Corp.” Supreme Court Economic Review 2: 111–129.
Jensen, Michael. 1986. “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance and Takeovers.”
American Economic Review 76(2): 323–329.
Jensen, Michael, and William Meckling. 1976. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency
Cost, and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–360.
Jensen, Michael, and Kevin J. Murphy. 1990. “CEO Incentives—It’s Not How Much You Pay But
How.” Harvard Business Review May-June: 138–153.
44
Ji, MinWoong, and David Weil. 2015. “The Impact of Franchising on Labor Standards Compliance.”
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 68(5): 977–1006.
Kalleberg, Arne. 2013. Good Jobs, Bad Jobs. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Kalleberg, Arne, Jeremy Reynolds, and Peter V. Marsden. 2003. “Externalizing Employment: Flexible
Staffing Arrangements in U.S. Organizations.” Social Science Research 32(4): 525–552.
Kochan, Thomas, Harry C. Katz, and Robert McKersie. 1986. The Transformation of American
Industrial Relations. New York: Basic Books.
Kogut, Bruce, and Udo Zander. 1992. “Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the
Replication of Technology.” Organization Science 3(3): 383–397.
Kraemer, K.L., and Jason Dedrick. 2002. “Strategic Use of the Internet and Ecommerce: Cisco
Systems.” Journal of Strategic Information Systems 11(1): 5–29.
Krueger, Alan B. 2016. “Work in the Sharing Economy.” Presentation made at a session of the Labor
and Employment Relations Association, Allied Social Sciences Association meeting, January
3, in San Francisco.
Lakhani, Tashlin, Sarosh Kuruvilla, and Ariel Avgar. 2013. “From the Firm to the Network: Global
Value Chains and Employment Relations Theory.” British Journal of Industrial Relations
51(3): 440–472.
Lane, Julia, Philip Moss, Harold Salzman, and Chris Tilly. 2003. “Too Many Cooks? Tracking Internal
Labor Market Dynamics in Food Service with Case Studies and Quantitative Data.” In Low-
Wage America: How Employers Are Reshaping Opportunity in the Workplace, Eileen
Appelbaum, Annette Bernhardt, and Richard J. Murnane, eds. New York: Russell Sage
Foundation, pp. 229–269.
Langley, C. John, and Capgemini Consulting. 2015. 2015 Third-Party Logistics Study: The State of
Logistics Outsourcing. http://www.3plstudy.com/ (accessed February 16, 2016).
Langlois, Richard N. 1992. “Transaction Cost Economics in Real Time'. Industrial and Corporate
Change 1(1): 99–127.
Lazonick, William. 1992. “Controlling the Market for Corporate Control: The Historical Significance
of Managerial Capitalism.” Industrial and Corporate Change 1(3): 445–488.
———. 2014: “Profits without Prosperity.” Harvard Business Review September: 3–11.
Lepak, David P., and Scott A. Snell. 1999. “The Human Resource Architecture: Toward a Theory of
Human Capital Allocation and Development.” Academy of Management Review 24(1): 31–
48.
Leuschner, Rudolf, Craig R. Carter, Thomas J. Goldsby, and Zachary S. Rodgers. 2014. “Third-Party
Logistics: A Meta-analytic Review and Investigation of its Impact on Performance.” Journal
of Supply Chain Management 50(1): 21–43.
Lieb, Robert, and Brooks A. Bentz. 2005. “The Use of Third-Party Logistics Services by Large
American Manufacturers: The 2004 Survey.” Transportation Journal 44(2): 5–15.
Locke, Richard. 2013. The Promise and Limits of Private Power Promoting Labor Standards in a
Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Locke, Richard M., Fei Qin, and Alberto Brause. 2007. “Does Monitoring Improve Labor Standards?
Lessons from Nike.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61(1): 3–31.
MacDuffie, John Paul. 1995. “Human Resource Bundles and Manufacturing Performance:
Organizational Logic and Flexible Production Systems in the World Auto Industry.” Industrial
and Labor Relations Review 48(2):197–201.
———. 2011. “Inter-organizational Trust and the Dynamics of Distrust.” Journal of International
Business Studies 42: 35–47.
45
MacDuffie, John Paul, and Susan Helper. 2006. “Collaboration in Supply Chains, With and Without
Trust.” In The Corporation as a Collaborative Community: The Reconstruction of Trust in the
Knowledge Economy, Charles Hecksher and Paul S. Adler, eds. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, pp. 417–466.
Milkman, Ruth. 2006. L.A. Story: Immigrant Workers and the Future of the U.S. Labor Movement.
New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
———. 2008. “Putting Wages Back into Competition: Deunionization and Degradation in Place-
Bound Industries.” In The Gloves-Off Economy, Annette Bernhardt, Heather Boushey, Laura
Dresser, and Chris Tilly, eds. Annual Research Volume, Labor and Employment Relations
Association. Champaign, IL: University of Illinois Press, pp. 65–90.
Morris, J.A., 1999. “Injury Experience of Temporary Workers in a Manufacturing Setting: Factors
that Increase Vulnerability.” Workplace Health & Safety 47(10): 470.
Muzaffar, Saeher, Kristin Cummings, Gerald Hobbs, Paul Allison, and Kathleen Kreiss. 2013. “Factors
Associated with Fatal Mining Injuries among Contractors and Operators.” Journal of
Occupational and Environmental Medicine 55(11): 1337–1344.
Nielsen, Peter, and Timothy Sturgeon. 2014. “Using Business Functions to Measure International
Trade and Economic Globalization.” Prepared for the International Conference on Trade and
Economic Globalization, held September 29–October 1, 2014, in Aguascalientes, Mexico.
http://unstats.un.org/unsd/trade/events/2014/mexico/documents/session3/Business%20F
unctions%20UNFOC%20final%20Sept29_2014.pdf (accessed Febraury 16, 2016).
Penrose, Edith. 1959. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Piore, Michael. 1989. “Administrative Failure: An Hypothesis about the Decline of the US Union
Movement in the 1980s.” Unpublished paper. Cambridge, MA: Department of Economics,
MIT.
Piore, Michael, and Charles Sabel. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity.
New York: Basic Books.
Porter, Michael. 1985. Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. New
York: The Free Press.
Powell, Walter W. 1990. “Neither Market nor Hierarchy: Network Forms of Organization.” Research
in Organizational Behavior 12: 295–336.
Powell, Walter W., Kenneth W. Koput, Laurel Smith-Doerr. 1996. “Inter-organizational Collaboration
and the Locus of Innovation: Networks of Learning in Biotechnology.” Administrative
Science Quarterly 41(1): 116–145.
Prahalad, C.K., and Gary Hamel. 1990. “The Core Competence of the Corporation.” In Knowledge
and Strategy, Michael H. Zack, ed. Cambridge: Routledge, pp. 41–60.
Rebitzer, James B. 1995. “Job Safety and Contract Workers in the Petrochemical Industry.”
Industrial Relations 34(1): 40–57.
Rees, Albert. 1993. “The Role of Fairness in Wage Determination.” Journal of Labor Economics
11(1): 243–252.
Rubery, Jill, Jill Earnshaw, and Mick Marchington. 2005. “Blurring the Boundaries to the
Employment Relationship: From Single to Multi-Employer Relationships.” In Fragmenting
Work: Blurring Organizational Boundaries and Disordering Hierarchies, Mick Marchington,
Damian Grimshaw, Jill Rubery, and Hugh Willmott, eds. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.
63–88.
Rugman, Alan, Jing Li, and Chang Hoon Oh. 2009. “Are Supply Chains Global or Regional?”
International Marketing Review 26(4/5): 384–395.
46
Sako, Mari, George Chondrakis and Paul Vaaler. 2013. “How Do Firms Make-and-Buy? The Case of
Legal Services Sourcing by Fortune 500 Companies?” Oxford University Working Paper.
Oxford: Novak Druce Centre for Professional Firms.
Saxenian, AnnaLee. 1996. Regional Advantage. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
———. 2005. “From Brain Drain to Brain Circulation: Transnational Communities and Regional
Upgrading in India and China Studies.” Comparative International Development 40(2): 35–
61.
Sharpe, Murem. 2001. “Outsourcing, Organizational Competitiveness and Work.” Journal of Labor
Research 18(4): 535–549.
Smith, Caroline K., Barbara A. Silverstein, David K. Bonauto, Darrin Adams, and Z. Joyce Fan. 2010.
“Temporary Workers in Washington State.” American Journal of Industrial Medicine 53(2):
135–145.
Sturgeon, Timothy. 2002. “Modular Production Networks. A New American Model of Industrial
Organization.” Industrial and Corporate Change 11(3): 451–496.
Teece, David J. 1988. “Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm.” In Technical Change and
Economic Theory, Giovanni Dosi, Christopher Freeman, Richard Nelson, Gerald Silverberg,
and Luc Soete, eds. London and New York: Pinter Publishers, pp. 256–281.
Teece, David, Gary Pisano, and Amy Shuen. 1997. “Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic
Management.” Strategic Management Journal 18(7): 509–533.
Timmer, Marcel P., Bart Los, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2015. “Incomes and Jobs in Global Production
of Manufacturers: New Measures of Competitiveness Based on the World Input-Output
Tables.” In Measuring Globalization: Better Trade Statistics for Better Policy, Susan N.
Houseman and Michael Mandel, eds. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment
Research, pp. 121–164.
Ulrich, Karl T., and Steven D. Eppinger. 1995. Product Design and Development. 1st ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Useem, Michael. 1996. Investor Capitalism: How Money Managers are Changing the Face of
Corporate America. New York: Basic Books.
Uzzi, Brian. 1996. “The Sources and Consequences of Embeddedness for the Economic
Performance of Organizations: The Network Effect.” American Sociological Review 61(4):
674–698.
Weil, David. 2014. The. Fissured Workplace. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Williamson, Oliver. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York:
Free Press.
———. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.
Yuskavage, Robert E., Erich H. Strassner, and Gabriel W. Medeiros. 2008. “Outsourcing and
Imported Services in BEA’s Industry Accounts.” In International Flows of Invisibles: Trade in
Services and Intangibles in the Era of Globalization, Marshall Reinsdorf and Matthew
Slaughter, eds. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 247–288.
Zorn, Dirk M. 2004. “Here a Chief, There a Chief: The Rise of the CFO in the American Firm.”
American Sociological Review 69(June): 345–364.
Zorn, Dirk, Frank Dobbin, Julian Dierkes, and Man-Shan Kwok. 2005. “Managing Investors: How
Financial Markets Reshaped the American Firm.” In The Sociology of Financial Markets,
Karen Knorr-Cetina and Alex Preda, eds. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 269–289.
47
SECTOR-BASED TRAINING STRATEGIES: THE CHALLENGES OF MATCHING
WORKERS AND THEIR SKILLS TO WELL-PAYING JOBS
Harry J. Holzer
McCourt School of Public Policy
Georgetown University
December 2015
This paper has been prepared for the Symposium on the Changing Structure of Work at the US
Department of Labor, December 10, 2015.
DISCLAIMER: This report was prepared for the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL), Chief Evaluation Office. The
views expressed are those of the authors and should not be attributed to DOL, nor does mention of trade names,
commercial products, or organizations imply endorsement of same by the U.S. Government.
48
Abstract
This paper reviews what we know about sector-based training strategies to date, and why they
have become so popular with policymakers. It also reviews several major challenges to
expanding them while trying to maintain their quality. These challenges include the fact that only
workers with strong basic skills and employability are likely to benefit from these strategies; the
likely tradeoffs between short- and long-term impacts and between general and more specific
training; the difficulties of replicating and scaling the best models; and uncertain future labor
demand. The paper concludes with a number of policy recommendations in light of the
challenges sector-based strategies face.
49
In a labor market that rewards worker education and skills very heavily, and where employers
frequently complain about their difficulties finding workers with appropriate skills, how can we
provide less-educated workers the skills they need to attain well-paying jobs?
Increasingly, policy makers and labor market practitioners have turned to “demand-driven” or
“sectoral” training to meet the skill needs of both workers and employers. This model has been
used to train both for disadvantaged adults and youth, as well as workers dislocated from
previous jobs. It has recently been embraced by the Obama Administration in its job training
initiatives, by Congress in its recent reauthorization of federal job training programs, and by
governors and mayors around the country.
Despite the apparent enthusiasm for demand-driven training, and its widespread adoption, there
are some major challenges involved in bringing these programs to a scale sufficient to really
improve outcomes for less-educated workers, while maintaining program quality. For instance,
some workers might not have sufficient basic or employability skills to be able to master the
training (often of a technical nature); and sometimes the training might be too narrow or specific
to be portable to other firms and economic sectors when they change jobs. In addition,
practitioners might have difficulty replicating and scaling the most successful models observed
elsewhere; and identifying high-demand sectors and jobs over time while meeting their evolving
skill needs might be difficult as well.
Below I briefly review what we know about demand-driven training, including the evaluation
evidence. I will try to account for the enthusiasm with which these models have been embraced,
as well as the challenges of expanding the best of them. I will then propose some solutions to
these challenges, both specific and general in nature.
Job-driven or sector-based training actively tries to match worker skills on the supply side of the
labor market with what employers seek on the demand side of the market. While they need to
engage with specific employers, they also target broader economic sectors, usually at the local or
regional levels, with the following characteristics:
50
• the sub-BA jobs pay well enough for workers in them to escape poverty and perhaps
enter the middle class.
Sectoral training typically involves creating a “partnership” between several institutional actors –
employers or their industry associations, training providers (often community colleges),
workforce boards and an intermediary organization. The intermediary often takes the lead in
recruiting the industry and educational partners, figuring out employer skill needs, establishing
the training guidelines, recruiting low-income workers to these programs and providing them
with supports, and ultimately making sure employers get job candidates who will perform well
and meet their needs. A range of different organizations can play the intermediary role; some
(like the Wisconsin Regional Training Partnership or Jewish Vocational Services) have
traditionally focused on a few key industries like health care or manufacturing, while others (like
the Chicago Jobs Council) have a broader focus on the sectors leading local or regional
economic growth. Community-based organizations can also play the intermediary role.
The sectoral model first appeared in specific localities the 1980s, mostly in health and elder care,
and then began spreading to other locations and sectors in the 1990s (Conway and Giloth,
2014). 1 Today they are most frequently found in health care, advanced manufacturing,
information technology, construction, transportation/logistics, and hospitality to fill jobs with
specific skill requirements that often fall short of BA degrees.
Closely related to sector strategies are “career pathway” models, which combine classroom
training, work experience and credential attainment to move workers through a set of jobs and
occupations within particular sectors, such as health care (Fein, 2012). As an example, a health
career pathway could begin with a certified nurse assistant (CNA) credential and related
employment while eventually leading to a licensed practical nurse (LPN) degree and perhaps
ultimately a BS degree in nursing.
The pathways can begin in high school, as part of a district’s career and technical education
(CTE) offerings, and involve certificate or AA (or AS) attainment in community or four-year
colleges as well. The work experience components can be provided through apprenticeships or
other forms of work-based learning. Programs often seek to provide “on and off ramps” between
the labor market and educational institutions at various points along the pathways, to meet the
needs of both younger and older students and workers, including those who are either
disadvantaged or dislocated from earlier jobs.
Since most of the demand-driven training occurs at the local or regional level, many efforts to
expand this training have focused there. The most important of these is the National Fund for
Workforce Solutions, with financial support from several national foundations (Dyer, 2014). But
1
Among the earliest models in the 1980s were the Extended Care Career Ladder Initiative (ECCLI) in
Massachusetts, the Paraprofesesional Healthcare Institute (PHI) and its Cooperative Home Care Associates (CHCA)
in New York, and Focus: Hope which helped trained machinists for the auto industry in Detroit.
51
important activity occurs at the state level too, often with encouragement from the federal
Departments of Education and Labor.
Nearly a decade ago, Pennsylvania was one of the first states to begin organizing their workforce
strategies around key economic sectors; since then, many others have followed suit. A range of
competitive grant programs in the Bush (43) and Obama Administrations supported their
expansion at the state and regional/local levels during this time period. 2 At this time, most states
use sector strategies and career pathways as parts of their workforce strategies (National
Governors Association, 2013). Various networks of states have been organized to support this
development. 3 It is now also being encouraged by the newly reauthorized Workforce Innovation
and Opportunity Act (WIOA), as well as by a set of workforce initiatives under by the Obama
Administration (National Skills Coalition, 2014; White House, 2014).
What accounts for the rapid and widespread adoption of sector-based and pathways approaches
in workforce development in the past decade? I would argue that several factors have contributed
to this. For one thing, by the 1990s there was growing dissatisfaction with more traditional forms
of job training for adults and youth that were more disconnected from the world of higher
education, and from employers and labor demand as well. Evaluation evidence of programs
funded by the Job Training Partnership Act (JTPA) showed modestly positive impacts on
earnings for adults that tended to fade with time, while those for youth were zero or even
negative (Heckman et al., 1999). Partly as a result of these findings, funding for training in JTPA
and its successor, the Workforce Investment Act (WIA), has continually diminished over time
(though worker use of services provided by One-Stop centers grew). Since the labor market
returns to higher education credentials were rising over the same time period, and especially after
Pell grant funding for higher education among the poor began rising as well, the focus of
workforce development shifted to higher education and especially community colleges. 4
Workforce practitioners and policy advocates also came to see the value of a “dual customer”
approach in which employers as well as disadvantaged workers are seen as clients, whose
interests need to be served. In such an approach, the training for workers would be more
carefully tailored to existing jobs, which the trainees would now have much better chances of
2
These grant programs included the High Growth Job Training Initiative (HGJTI) and Workforce Innovation in
Regional Economic Development (WIRED) grants during the Bush administration; as well as the Trade Adjustment
Assistance Community College and Career Training (TAACCCT), Workforce Innovation Fund and Social Innovation
Fund grants during the Obama years. See Haskins (2014) for an account for how evaluation evidence was used to
structure the programs under President Obama.
3
State networks that have been set up to help them develop systemic approaches with measured outcomes
include the National Network of Sector Partnerships, the Alliance for Quality Career Pathways, and the Pathways
to Prosperity Network.
4
Heinrich et al. (2011) and Andersson et al. (2013) show nonexperimental evidence of significant positive impacts
of WIA training on employment outcomes for disadvantaged adults but less so for displaced workers. The growth
of Pell grants during the past decade and their use in workforce programs, especially for independent and older
students, is documented in the College Board (2013).
52
obtaining (Conway and Giloth, 2014). If employers were pleased with the trainees whom
intermediaries sent their way, they were more likely to participate in the future, perhaps
expanding the numbers of such workers whom they hired. Other employers in the sector were
then more likely to participate in the partnerships as well, and perhaps mold their workplace
organizations and human resource (HR) functions accordingly.
And, very importantly, governors began to see sectoral training as part of their state economic
development activities. For major employers whom they were recruiting to the state, or trying to
retain, helping them meet their skill needs would come to play an important part of the benefits
provided by the state as part of that process. Unlike other kinds of economic development
activities – which often amount to a zero sum game nationally in which states bid against each
other to lure major employers away from their competitor states – the sectoral training approach
generates net new value added for the employers and their workers, and are therefore better from
a national perspective (Bartik, 2012).
All of these considerations gained more weight as employers in key sectors also became
increasingly and vocally dissatisfied with their own abilities to recruit and retain skilled workers,
at either the BA level or below. At least in theory, this problem should not really exist in well-
functioning labor markets – or at least not for very long. A rising demand for workers at a
particular skill level should, all else equal, cause wages to rise for that skill; workers, in turn,
should then invest more in obtaining those skills, so that shifts in the supply of the skill follow
the shifts in demand (Becker, 1996).
There might be some temporary local shortages, during which workers obtain the necessary
skills, and perhaps move geographically to areas of strong demand; but eventually the adjustment
process should occur (Blanchard and Katz, 1992; Goldin and Katz, 2008). Indeed, the large
relative wage increases associated with higher education, beginning around 1980 or so, kicked
off such a process; in response, higher education enrollment soon began to rise. And, though
there was a long time lag before adjustments in the supply of students with postsecondary
credentials began to occur in sufficient quantities to meet the demand for them, this seems to
finally be happening at the national level. 5
5
Autor (2014) shows that the premium to workers with college degrees has finally flattened in the 2000s because
the growth in the supply of college-educated workers has finally caught up with labor demand for them. Weakness
in the aggregate labor market, especially in the aftermath of the Great Recession, contributed to flat or declining
real earnings of workers at all education levels. But Beaudry and Sand (2013) argue that there has even been some
reversal in the relative demand for higher education and cognitive skills in the labor market during this time
period. Autor (2015) argues that the bursting of the technology bubble around 2000 and the housing/financial
market bubbles in 2006-08 likely contributed to this reversal, while rising imports (especially from China) reduced
labor demand at all levels.
53
Yet, employers in key sectors continue to complain about their inability to recruit and retain such
workers; their complaints have now persisted, and grown more vocal, for years or even decades. 6
Some economists have been skeptical about these claims – arguing that employers always
complain about their workers’ skill levels. Wage increases have failed to materialize in any such
labor markets since 2000, and these economists infer that there must not be any real skill
shortages in these markets (Rothstein, 2012). Others argue that on-the-job training appears to be
shrinking nationwide, which also seems inconsistent with notions of skill shortage (Cappelli,
2014). Lengthy vacancy durations in manufacturing appear to be quite rare, despite the vocal
complaints of employers in that sector (Osterman and Weaver, 2014). Separately, a body of
research has shown that demand in the middle of the labor market – defined as employment and
wage trends in occupations whose average wages have been in the middle deciles of the wage
distribution - has been shrinking over time, and that therefore it should not be difficult to meet
skill needs there (Autor, 2010; Naimovich and Siu, 2012).
At the same time, the claims about tight labor markets (if not full-fledged skill shortages) in
particular sectors and regions might be at least partly legitimate. While part of the middle of the
labor market is shrinking – specifically, the well-paying production and clerical jobs available to
workers with high school or less education – other parts that require some postsecondary
education or training, like health technicians or very skilled production workers, seem to be
growing (Holzer, 2015a). And it is frequently in these sectors that employers complain the most
about their ability to attract and retain skilled workers.
Given these difficulties, why aren’t real wages growing? Perhaps we will soon observe more
such growth, especially in key labor market sectors, as we recover more fully from the Great
Recession. On the other hand, such increases might continue to be limited in industries facing
strong international competitive forces (like manufacturing) or other pressures to contain costs
(health and elder care) or generate higher profits (From the capital markets); and this is
especially true if employers feel that their relative wage increases in the past did little to resolve
their skilled labor supply problems. 7 For these reasons, limited real wage growth alone is not
sufficient to prove that firm difficulties with skilled labor aren’t real.
Regarding on-the-job training, some observers question whether it is declining in the aggregate
(Lerman, 2015); and, in sectors like health care and advanced manufacturing where the supply of
skills seems limited, employers are more engaged in newer efforts to generate more such supply
(Ross, 2015). But it may not always be economically sensible for firms to invest in such training,
6
See Shemkus (2015) and the Manufacturing Institute (2014) for examples of press accounts and reports that
claim a strong shortage of workers with middle-level skills in manufacturing and other key sectors of the economy.
7
In conversations with private employers one often hears that the jobs they are trying to fill (like those for
machinists and precision welders in advanced manufacturing) already pay quite well, after wage increases in
earlier decades, but that the skills needed are still not being generated in sufficient quantity. Some discuss the
inability of current high school graduates to master the technical nature of the training many now provide or
employability skills as measured by drug tests. Many prefer to adjust to high and unfilled demand along other
“margins” such as recruiting activity or outsourcing the work to other firms.
54
given its general nature and the limited skills of the potential trainees. A variety of market
failures might also limit their willingness to provide such training, or to create high-paying (or
“high road”) jobs, where their ability to be competitive is based on high worker productivity and
low turnover rather than just low labor costs (Appelbaum et al., 2003; Ton, 2014). 8
Overall, the validity of employers complaints about their hiring difficulties in the middle of the
skill distribution, and especially on technical jobs, continue to be debated. But, in the meantime,
employer concerns in this area resonate with many in the political and policy arenas, and they
frequently turn to sectoral strategies to try to better meet these needs. 9
And, finally, rigorous evaluation evidence on the impacts of sectoral training on the earnings of
disadvantaged workers became available. These consistently show relatively large positive
impacts of about 30 percent for both adults and youth within two years of the beginning of
training. 10 These impacts are much larger than those that have been observed for JTPA or WIA
more generally. Given the strong earnings premium associated with attaining at least some
postsecondary credentials – particularly those with technical content – any efforts that help
disadvantaged workers gain more such credentials (above what they would obtain anyway)
should generate similarly large effects on their earnings as well. 11
II. What are the Major Challenges that Limit Expansion of Demand-Driven
Strategies?
Despite the popularity of job-driven/sector training strategies, and the widespread efforts to
expand their use, we face some significant challenges in trying to do so.
8
Labor market failures that inhibit additional training include lack of information among employers about how to
provide more of it, wage rigidities that prevent them from paying lower wages to trainees for general training, and
coordination failures that keep small firms from sharing the fixed costs of setting up and managing training. Unions
often played the latter role in construction or manufacturing in earlier decades. Employer investment in training
their workers will also be limited if they think their basic skills are weak or that they will have high turnover, which
might explain why American employers tend to provide much more training to their professional and managerial
employees than to others.
9
See the National Research Council (2015) for a recent report highlighting the difficulties of generating employees
with middle-level technical skills relative to employer demand for them.
10
See Maguire et al (2010) for rigorous evidence on impacts from three well-known sector programs and Roder
and Elliott (2011) for evidence from a program called Year Up for youth. Popovich (2014) reviews data on inputs
and outcomes of National Fund sites while Michaelides et al. (2015) provides quasi-experimental evidence on
impacts of programs supported by the National Fund in Ohio.
11
Backes et al (2015) and Stevens et al. (2015) show strong labor market returns to a range of more technical
certificate and associate degree programs in Florida and California very recently.
55
A. Job-Driven Training: For Whom?
Job-driven training seems to constitute an effective anti-poverty strategy while, at the same time,
it meets the needs and concerns of employers in the hiring process. Yet there can sometimes be
tensions between these two policy goals.
Simply put, to maintain the confidence of employers, the workforce intermediaries must only
send them workers whose skills and pending performance are not in doubt. This, in turn, requires
the intermediaries to screen out any candidates whom they view as potentially weak along these
dimensions – either sooner or later in the process. In addition, the frequently technical nature of
the training requires that trainees have fairly strong basic academic (or “foundational”) skills,
with reading and math abilities at least at the 9th or 10th grade levels.
In other words, job-driven strategies can be successful antipoverty efforts for those who currently
are among the working poor, with solid workforce attachment and good basic skills, but not
among the hard-to-employ with poor reading/math skills and perhaps other barriers to steady
employment like substance abuse or depression (Zedlewski and Loprest, 2001). James
Heckman’s notion that “skill begets skill” (Heckman, 2008) has some strong support in this
context. And the percentages of Americans whose basic skills are deficient are quite high,
relative to residents of other countries (OECD, 2013).
This tension between who can benefit from sectoral training and who most needs the help
constitutes a real barrier to attempts to expand such training on community college campuses,
where most such training now occurs. Community colleges around the country are largely open-
access institutions, with few admissions requirements beyond having a high school diploma or
general equivalency degree (GED). Yet, before students can take courses for academic credit in
many places, they must demonstrate proficiency in reading and in math (usually at the level of
Algebra 1). Because of their inability to do so, as many as 60 percent of community college
entrants are assigned to “developmental education” (or remediation) classes from which most
never successfully emerge (Bailey et al., 2015).
For this and other reasons, the completion rates of students who enter community college AA or
AS programs are very low. Without counting those who transfer to four-year colleges to pursue
BAs, only about 20 percent in associate’s programs overall and somewhat higher in certificate
ones. 12 The completion rates for older students are below these averages and for younger
students right out of high school they are higher. But, while many of the younger ones plan on
transferring to a four-year college for a BA, only 25 percent actually transfer and only 15 percent
get the BA.
12
Completion rates in AA programs for students out of high school are about 30 percent (Backes et al., op. cit;
Holzer and Dunlop, 2012) but much lower among older, independent students. Completion rates in certificate
programs are in the 40-50 percent range.
56
Reforms in the academic requirements for admission to for-credit classes, and in how
“developmental education” is administered, could potentially improve the ability of many
students to enter and complete job-driven training programs. Successful “bridge” programs and
other efforts in in the K-12 years might also help address student deficiencies before they arrive
at community college. 13
But, even among those who can avoid remediation or for whom it is successful, an inability to
pass important “gateway” classes – like anatomy in health technology programs – likely limits
success for others. (Goldrick-Rab, 2010). To become a machinist, or even a precision welder,
math requirements are not trivial. The degree programs in these cases are often for AS rather
than AA degrees; the market value of the former very often exceeds that of the latter (Backes et
al., 2015; Stevens et al., 2015), but with higher math and science requirements along the way.
Of course, not all health technology or manufacturing programs are quite as academically
rigorous as these. Some of the less rigorous ones require individuals to complete certificates,
rather than AA or AS degrees. And these can frequently have greater labor market value than
AA degrees (though less than AS ones, as noted by Backes et al., op. cit.).
At the same time, the certificate programs do not always provide academic credit, which might
limit their appeal and their usefulness in a “career pathway,” since they cannot count towards
higher degree attainment. Indeed, whether a certificate program has academic credit or not can
often be fairly arbitrary, with similar programs in adjacent districts or states being treated
differently (McCarthy, 2014). But those that do not confer credit, or are short-term in nature,
cannot currently be paid for with Pell grants, thus limiting their usefulness to many low-income
students.
Another source of tension in demand-driven training strategies involves the extent to which
training is specific to certain occupations and sectors or more general. Part of the appeal of
sectoral training, and likely part of its effectiveness in raising earnings of disadvantaged workers,
is the direct participation of employers in devising it, and the availability of good-paying jobs
with those employers when workers finish it. Such training is often quite specific to an industry
and an occupation (or a set of occupations on a career pathway). In some cases, community
colleges even obtain contracts to provide “customized” training to individual employers.
So what happens when workers change jobs and employers, and perhaps industry sectors? We
currently have little evidence on this, since the rigorous evaluations went out only 2 years after
the point of “random assignment” to the treatment and control groups. Furthermore, the dynamic
13
See Long (2014) and Bettinger et al. (2013) for reviews of evidence on development programs and their impacts.
Martin and Broadus (2013) show significant impacts on GED attainment and college enrollment of the LaGuardia
Community College Bridge program, though success rates remain quite low.
57
nature of US labor markets imply that high-demand sectors today might not be the same ones
tomorrow, as we will note further below, which could increase involuntary turnover over time.
There might well be some tradeoff between the amount and quality of general training these
individuals receive, which might be better for their longer-term earnings prospects, and the
specific training which is clearly better in in the shorter term. As noted earlier, employers will be
less interested in the former, and will invest fewer of their own resources, the more general the
training is. The firm might still be willing to provide some training, but it would have to be paid
for out of worker wages; and if these wages are downwardly rigid, the training will not occur.
Accordingly, there is a stronger argument for investment of public resources in such training
when the latter is at least partly general; President Obama and others have frequently said that
the training must be “portable” to merit public support. This needn’t always be absolutely true –
there might be equity-based reasons to support relatively specific training, if that training goes to
workers who would not be hired and trained by employers in the absence of government efforts.
But, on average, more general training is somewhat better in the long run, given the frequency
with which workers change jobs, and the dynamic and uncertain nature of future labor demand.
Of course, there are also key worker benefits to the more specific parts of the training. For one
thing, it helps them accumulate the work experience that the labor market rewards. And there is
some reason to be hopeful that the sector-specific training has some valuable general content.
For instance, there has been strong evaluation evidence that Career Academies, which provide
sector-specific education and training to high school students within broader high schools, have
large impacts on their earnings. For at-risk young men, these earnings increases are nearly 20
percent in magnitude. And quite importantly for this discussion, they last for eight years after the
assignment to treatment and control groups, with little sign of erosion, despite the fact that many
students change employers and industry sectors. Evidently, students learn something about the
labor market from their training and work experience that seems portable across employers and
sectors. And there has also been some evidence that apprenticeships with particular employers
have some lasting effects after workers switch occupations or industries, at least in other
countries. 14
Clearly, getting the right balance between specific and general training should be a high priority
for those building demand-driven programs. For instance, when workers obtain an AA or
certificate from their training, the credential should signal to other employers the potential
breadth of the worker’s skill-building. A new trend in this work towards smaller, “stackable”
credentials along the career pathway could make these signals even more apparent, as would
14
See Kemple (2008) for evidence on the long-term effects of Career Acadaemies while Geel and Backes-Gellner
(2011) show that vocational training in Europe generates general skills with lasting impacts even after workers
change jobs and sectors.
58
other reforms in the credentialing process in the US to make the process easier for workers and
firms to navigate and less fractured and duplicative while making the credentials themselves
more transparent (Lumina Foundation, 2015).
And, in a world where demand shifts will always cause some amount of worker displacement
and therefore obsolescence of specific skills, strengthening the potential availability of high-
quality “lifelong learning” to all who need it is critical as well. In addition, workers trained in the
past in particular high-demand occupations, like welding, might have few of the more technical
skills employers now seek in those same occupations (Uchitelle, 2009); making it easier for them
to upgrade those occupational skills would be helpful to them and to employers who seek those
skills and have difficulty finding them. 15
Current efforts to scale demand-driven training programs in states around the country, and
federal support of those efforts, have been at least partly driven by the strong impacts that were
found in the rigorous evaluations of sector programs cited above. But the three or four programs
in question had each been in the field for years and had developed reputations for high quality.
Can these be easily replicated in newer efforts? And can we scale these successful efforts,
building job-driven workforce systems rather than isolated training programs?
The problem of replicating and scaling successful but small model programs has vexed social
and educational policy efforts for years in many contexts. 16 A particular effort to do so in the
context of demand-driven training occurred around efforts to replicate the Center for
Employment and Training (CET) in San Jose CA. While not a specifically sectoral program,
CET had some other elements common to such efforts – particularly the close relationships
between intermediaries who ran the program and employers in the community who often hired
the trainees afterwards. The strong program impacts on worker earnings observed in the
evaluation of the original program excited the field and led to desires to replicate and scale the
approach elsewhere. But subsequent efforts to do so by the Department of Labor were difficult,
and ultimately not successful. 17 Indeed, the close relationships between employers and
intermediaries in San Jose (mostly within a fairly tight-knit Hispanic community) proved one of
the most difficult aspects of CET in San Jose to replicate elsewhere.
Some analysts, like Mark Elliott of the Economic Mobility Corporation, have argued strongly
that it takes years to build these successful programs and relationships. Intermediaries must gain
experience in what works and what doesn’t, and they must prove to employers that they are
trustworthy; in other words, the program and relationships need time to mature, and this process
15
For evidence on within-occupation skill upgrading see Autor and Handel (2009).
16
For instance, very large impacts of pre-school in programs like Perry and Abcedarian from the 1960s and 1970s
have been difficult to replicate in larger programs at the state level. See Cascio and Schanzenbach (2014).
17
See Melendez (1996) for evidence of large impacts in the San Jose cite but Miller et al. (2005) for disappointing
impacts in the replication study conducted by the Department of Labor.
59
should not necessarily be rushed in efforts to scale these programs, or to rigorously evaluate
them (Elliott and Roder, 2015).
Even where successful programs are replicated at the firm level, we often find dozens or even
hundreds of partnerships at the state level (National Governors Association), but the scale of
each in terms of numbers of students trained and hired can be very small. Still, a few recent
efforts to achieve scale in building demand-driven programs seem to be bearing fruit in this
regard and are noteworthy. The National Fund described above has built sectoral training
programs in over thirty localities and regions around the country, and it has learned many lessons
in the process that are likely benefitting their newer efforts (Dedrick, 2014). Other efforts to
scale sector programs at the local or state level have similarly borne fruit. 18 It might still take
years to build the partnerships and successful efforts, but we are no longer doing so in a
knowledge vacuum.
Another prominent effort to watch is the Health Professions Opportunity Grants (HPOG), run by
the US Department of Health and Human Services (HHS). Beginning as part of the federal
American Recovery and Reconstruction Act (ARRA) in 2009-10, over 30 sites were given
HPOG grants to build health care training programs in the one sector where rising demand over
time is virtually a certainty, due to the ongoing process of Baby Boomer retirements. HPOG is an
effort to build a systemic approach across many localities and states that can perhaps be
replicated in other industries, if it proves successful. 19
While these efforts are encouraging, there are some other structural problems that might limit
successful scaling – and these reside in the community college system. These 2-year colleges
remain the primary training providers in sectoral efforts around the country. In many ways, this
makes sense – as noted above, the role of community colleges in workforce development has
steadily grown for decades, as higher education plays a more and more important role in the US
labor market. Many low-income students earn certificates or associate degrees in order to
increase their earnings with jobs in health care, IT, manufacturing and other parts of the service
sector; and the experience that the colleges have gained in providing this service remains very
important as we seek to scale up their involvement in sector-specific strategies.
At the same time, some major problems remain. The over 1200 community colleges around the
country vary a great deal in their abilities to carry out the workforce functions we now expect
from them. Traditionally, their primary missions have been more academic than workforce-
related – and that continues to be the case for most. Preparing workers for academic transfer to
four-year colleges remains what most focus on – even if the percentages who actually transfer,
and who ultimately complete a BA, remain quite low.
18
See Leung (2014) for a description of SkillWorks in Boston as an example of a sectoral approach that achieved
some scale at the municipal level.
19
For a description of HPOG see the Administration for Children and Families (2015).
60
For students who expect a certificate or an associate’s degree as their final product, and who
want to enter the workforce quickly thereafter and earn a strong return, the overall statistics are
grim, as we noted earlier. But, in addition to the problems associated with low academic
preparation for many students, the institutions themselves generate difficulties. Very little
academic or career counseling of any kind is provided in many places, and too little structure
exists for many students to be correctly guided along to their careers (Bailey et al., 2015). This
might be less true of new sectoral workforce programs developed with industry input than it is
more generally at these colleges, but it remains a broad concern.
Furthermore, the colleges face other disincentives in trying to scale up sector-specific efforts.
Most of their (often tenured) faculty are trained to teach liberal arts, not health care or IT; the
latter instructors need to be hired as adjunct faculty from the private sector. The costs of
providing such instruction are often higher per student in technical classes than in the liberal arts
– due to high costs of equipment and labs (as well as the salaries needed to be paid to nursing or
engineering teachers).
But colleges get the same tuition payments and the same subsidies from the state, regardless of
the classes students take, and regardless of whether they complete the coursework and obtain a
well-paying job afterwards. As a result, the incentives and limited resources facing the colleges
limit their ability or willingness to expand the very courses that offer the greatest labor market
rewards. This is particularly true in an era of very tight budgets, and given the multitude of roles
we expect community colleges to play.
Engaging employers at scale can also be very challenging. American employers are extremely
heterogeneous in terms of exactly what and how they produce, their human resource (HR)
activities, their size and locations, and overall attitudes. Small- and medium-sized employers
frequently know very little about workforce development outside their current approaches; and
the fixed costs of engaging them in partnerships can be very high. Efforts to engage them in
partnerships are necessarily very “retail” in nature. Among larger employers there is more
knowledge among their HR staffs but less so among top executives who often have other
priorities.
Many employers are also quite skeptical about participating directly in publicly-funded activities
of any kind. Though this is somewhat less true today than in earlier periods, policy activities at
the state and federal levels remain fairly “siloed” within their respective agencies, as are funding
sources. For instance, federal workforce development funding is available through WIOA, the
Perkins Act (for CTE), the Higher Education Act, Temporary Assistance to Needy Families
(TANF) and even Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Programs (SNAP, or Food Stamps). State
and local authorities have often learned to “braid” the many sources, and common performance
rules and measures (especially under WIOA) are helping. “Alignment” across agencies is
growing. But many funding sources are also temporary – especially competitive grants – and a
61
lack of permanent sources makes it harder for partnerships to become sustainable over time, as
well as scalable.
As long as the structural problems remain, and incentives to expand expensive workforce
instruction remain limited, scaling up successful efforts will remain problematic, in my view.
How do we know when demands for certain skills are sufficiently strong, relative to their supply,
that it makes sense to build sectoral training programs and career pathways in those areas? And
how do we build demand-driven training systems in a dynamic labor market when future demand
itself is so uncertain?
The answer to the first question has been made somewhat easier by the enormous growth in the
availability of and access to employment data in the past several years (Zinn and Van Kluenen,
2014; Reamers, 2015). Inferences about the levels of and trends in employment demand in any
particular state can be made from a variety of sources.
The best of these are often the administrative education and earnings data in the state
longitudinal data systems (SLDS) which the Obama administration has urged them to make
public and to analyze themselves. The educational data contain records on each individual
student who has participated in public education in the state, including at all public
postsecondary institutions. These data are frequently linked to those on individual quarterly
earnings from the Unemployment Insurance system, which can be broken down by industry. As
a result, state analysts can identify trends in employment in higher- v. lower-earning sectors, and
the educational preparation needed to attain it. Variance in these trends across regions within a
state can be analyzed. Though the data have some limitations – such as the absence of workers
who have moved out of state for education and/or work – the benefits of the data are still
enormous. 20
In addition, real-time data on job vacancies are now becoming more available and more
complete from sources that scrape the internet for such information, both public and private. 21
Though these are shorter-term in nature, they give us a sense over time of the set of jobs which
employers have had some greater difficulty filling. Finally, these data can be merged with
O*NET data on occupational tasks from the Department of Labor to giver researchers and state
20
The National Student Clearinghouse data can track students who went to college out of state and often enable
researchers using state-specific administrative data to get some handle on the problem of student outmigration
for higher education. But these data do not cover subsequent earnings. The Longitudinal Employer Household
Dynamics (LEHD) program at the US Census Bureau can track worker movements across states but access to the
microdata are very restricted.
21
Private data on real-time job vacancies based on internet coverage are held by the National Association of State
Workforce Agencies (NASWA) and Burning Glass.
62
analysts some sense of the tasks that need to be performed on the jobs in high demand, which in
turn give us some sense of the skills that need to be provided in these sectors.
While encouraging, the data also have their limitations. It is far more difficult to identify “labor
shortages,” even in the short run, than one might think (Barnow et al., 2013). The existence of
vacancies alone does not do so, as some vacant jobs always exist (along with unemployed
workers). A rise in the job vacancy rate, relative to unemployed workers, also does not prove that
a shortage or “mismatch” between workers and jobs exists, as the recent debate about rising
aggregate job vacancy rates suggests. 22
On the other hand, combining data on employment trends over time and current vacancies with
evidence on the flow of trained workers in an occupation or industry, coupled with conversations
with employers in any industry, can likely give us a good sense of the tightness of a labor market
today and for the next few years. This can also help state and local determine whether and what
kind of a flow of trained workers might be sufficient to meet a given level of demand without
creating a glut of these workers.
But it takes years to set up a partnership between employers, training providers and
intermediaries, and even more years to establish the pathways needed for training and to work
out glitches in that process. By time all of this is accomplished, the industry (and particular
occupations) might no longer be high in demand (especially relative to the supply of skilled
workers now being generated). New technologies and their applications often change the product
and labor market environments in which companies operate; they need to be nimble in response
to these changes. Yet the partnerships set up so painstakingly over time usually lack this
characteristic.
Of course, demand fluctuations are an economic fact of life in modern capitalist economies, as so
many Americans painfully learned in the Great Recession. In the weak labor markets that
accompanied our recovery from the recession, there were often fears that jobs would not be
available to those who had taken time and resources to train for new work (Watson, 2014). As
the labor market continues to recover and to tighten up, these particular fears should be less
worrisome to workers who seek training.
But how can we deal with the possibility (or likelihood) that high-demand sectors and
occupations today may not be so tomorrow (or in a few years)? Structural changes in product and
labor markets will continue to occur, and may even pick up speed. Some computer scientists,
such as Eric Brynjolffson and Andrew Macafee of MIT, argue that the pace of such structural
change in the labor market will quicken over time, as new applications of “artificial intelligence”
and other digital capabilities will grow. For instance, driverless cars and trucks might mean much
22
Analysis of movements in the job vacancy rate over time, relative to the unemployment rate, suggest some
possible increase in the “natural rate” of unemployment (Daly et al., 2012), but further analysis suggests that
vacancy durations have gotten longer as employer pressure to fill them has declined (Davis et al., 2013).
63
less demand for transportation workers; or digital implants might generate much more data on
individual health that might reduce the demand for health care workers who currently help
generate such data and diagnose illnesses.
Labor economists are often skeptical of fears that technological change will render huge numbers
of workers unemployed, and note that the employment fears of Luddites and others regarding
automation has existed for decades or even centuries, as have almost always been proven wrong
(Autor, 2015). 23Economies and labor markets adjust to these dislocations. For instance, the new
technologies make production cheaper, so lower prices result in higher real income among
consumers that generates more demand for products and labor either in the industry or outside it.
Many kinds of employment are complementary with the new technologies – and not just those
requiring technical skills. For instance, those who can master web design skills can prosper in the
new environment, as do many in the arts communities facing new demand from newly
prosperous citizens.
Yet the fears remain, and some might be reasonable. The pace and scope of technological
changes might simply be larger and faster than anything in the past, perhaps overwhelming the
traditional adjustment mechanisms. And the adjustments themselves might leave more “middle-
skill” workers facing reduced demand. In recent years, employers have begun demanding BAs or
higher for many jobs that historically have required “middle-skill” credentials like certificates
and AAs – often without the corresponding increases in earnings that the BAs should attract
(Modestino et al., 2015; Hershbein and Kahn, 2015). Whether this is primarily a temporary result
of the Great Recession, or something more structural (and thus more permanent) remains unclear
at the moment.
One additional source of uncertainty exists with regards to future demand. We often think of
labor demand as being something determined “exogenously,” by technological and market forces
that occur separately from decisions taken by policymakers and practitioners. Indeed, this
assumption is very strongly implicit in future employment projections by occupation or industry,
whether these are generated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics or private sources (like the
Georgetown Center on Education and the Workforce). 24
But, over the long term, labor demand decisions by employers are likely very endogenous to our
workforce system and its (in)ability to meet their skill needs. In many European countries, where
high school graduates often have strong technical skills which are further honed by
apprenticeships, employers can create middle-skilled and middle-wage jobs and have them filled
by such high school graduates and apprentices; in the U.S., where high-quality CTE has never
been widely available and most high school graduates have little in the way of analytical or
23
While most economists do not expect a large increase in unemployment over time associated with rapid
technological change, there is now a broad consensus that digital technologies have contributed to higher
inequality through “skill-biased technical change” (e.g., Goldin and Katz, 2008; Autor, 2015).
24
See Carnevale et al. (2013).
64
communication skills that employers value – much less specific occupational skills – employers
create fewer of these jobs. 25 As another example, when German manufacturers began relocating
their advanced manufacturing facilities to the US – often drawn by lower energy costs and less
regulation – they are frequently shocked at the very weak nature of our occupational training
systems, and will hesitate to build plants here until they generate a reliable flow of trained
technicians and engineers. 26
If the quantity and quality of US jobs at the sub-BA level depends on the quality and flow of
skilled workers to employers, then it is possible that generating such supply will lead to more
demand. Public policies that help or incentivize firms to improve job quality might be rendered
more effective by strong sectoral skills-building systems. Indeed, there have been sectoral
training effort whose explicit goal has also been to upgrade job quality and skill needs on the
demand side of the labor market. 27
But, overall, sufficient uncertainty may exist on the future directions of skill demands in any
particular sector to undermine our confidence in the ability of greater supplies of skills to
generate them.
Given the widespread interest in developing more and better demand-drive training systems for
workers, and also given the strong impacts of such programs in evaluation evidence, it is
inevitable that we should, and will, continue to do so in the U.S. How, then, can we respond to
the challenges listed in the previous section, when doing so?
For each of these challenges, the specific policies and programs needed to address them have
been discussed above. Regarding the access of very unskilled workers to sectoral training at
community colleges, we need reforms in “developmental education” (Long, 2014) and also in
accreditation processes, to make sure that less-demanding certificate programs with labor market
value are accessible to Pell grant recipients. Effective “bridge” programs for students can also
help them prepare before they arrive on campus, thus mitigating the need for developmental
education.
25
In the framework of labor economists, improving the supply of skills in high-demand sectors would reduce the
cost to employers of generating them, which in turn could raise employer demand and job creation. In other
words, such outward supply shifts would move employers along their demand functions.
26
See Nelson Schwartz’ article (2013) on how German manufacturers in the US have adapted their apprenticeship
models to generate more skilled workers here. The well-known example of the gas turbine engine plant built by
Siemens in North Carolina – and their decision to build it only after making arrangements with local community
and four-year colleges for a steady stream of technicians and engineers - highlights the extent to which labor
demand decisions can depend on the supply of skills.
27
ECCLI and PHI (both described above) are examples of sectoral programs in health care which explicitly worked
to improve job quality decisions by employers. The Restaurant Opportunities Center (ROC) has tried to improve job
quality and worker skills in the restaurant industry (Jayaraman, 2014).
65
Improving academic preparation and its links to the job market in the K-12 years are also very
important in this regard. Providing more high-quality CTE is critical. The best of these options
do not “track” students away from higher education; instead, they provide a range of “pathways”
to college and/or careers for all students (Symonds et al., 2011). Indeed, perhaps some career
exploration should be universal, and should start earlier – to inform students about the usefulness
of various kinds of skill development and better motivate them in the process. Making CTE
universal would reduce the stigma currently associated with CTE. Contextualized instruction
through work-based or project-based learning might also make skill acquisition more effective
for students who have not performed as well academically in the traditional classroom setting.
To better prepare workforce trainees for long-term and general labor market skill needs we
should expand apprenticeships and other forms of work-based learning, while also making sure
that they provide a broad mix of general and sector-specific skills. Encouraging them to be
combined with certificate and AA or AS programs in community colleges would help. Making
better sense of and rationalizing the many forms of postsecondary credentials in the US, from
private industry as well as the full range of educational institutions, would also be helpful, so
both employers and workers would better understand the supply of and demand for credentials
and which skills they signal to each other. And creating more and better opportunities for
individuals to obtain “lifelong learning” when their specific skills become obsolete or need
upgrading could be extremely important in a dynamic labor market with lots of technological
change and restructuring.
Replicating and scaling the best job-driven models requires that we encourage reforms in
community colleges, perhaps along the lines suggested by Tom Bailey and his colleagues that
would encourage more structured and “guided” pathways to credentials and the labor market.
But more likely needs to be done to encourage this process, and to make sure colleges build
sufficient instructional capacity in the pathways they create in high-demand fields.
Care must be taken to structure the incentives in ways that do not simply award the colleges for
“cream-skimming” the best applicants while avoiding disadvantaged ones. While for-profit
colleges already face market incentives to respond, they need further regulation to improve the
28
For instance, career counseling at community colleges could likely be improved by colocating more American
Jobs Center (One Stop) cites on their campuses.
66
outcomes they provide to students in return for the high tuition levels they charge and the debts
student incur in the process (Cellini and Chaudhury, 2014).
And governments at the federal, state and local levels should do more to engage employers in
training partnerships, and perhaps to more frequently take the “high road” to competition by
investing more in upgrading their workers’ skills (Holzer, 2015b). A range of methods, using
both financial incentives (like grants and tax credits as well as preferences in receiving
government procurement contracts) and technical assistance might help them do so. South
Carolina, among other states, provides tax credits to employers for every apprenticeship created,
and they market the apprenticeships to employers quite effectively. In a few short years they
have convinced 700 employers to create apprenticeships (Lerman, 2014).
Some states have been exploring how to achieve scale in their partnerships, by encouraging
participation in various consortia or networks of employers through various incentives. This
moves them towards systemic efforts rather than individualized programs. For instance,
Minnesota now allocates its Perkins funds only to such consortia of schools and employers.
Kentucky’s Federation for Advanced Manufacturing Education (FAME) is a systemic model for
advanced manufacturing training that might be replicable for other industries. But, given how
little we know about what works or doesn’t work cost-effectively in this area, a great deal of
experimentation and evaluation needs to be done to learn that.
Broadly speaking, all of the specific ideas above could be categorized into the following broader
recommendations for moving forward:
• A wide range of public efforts should be made to incentivize and assist community
colleges and employers – on both the supply and demand sides of the market – to create
both better-paying jobs and the workers with the skills to fill them;
• Efforts to scale these approaches and make them systemic, by encouraging participation
in a range of partnerships and consortia, remain high priorities;
• We should experiment with and rigorously evaluate a range of such efforts at the state
and local levels, while continuously providing feedback to both on “best practices” based
on these evaluations;
• All such efforts should work to create a mix of general and specific skills and credentials
that the labor market rewards over the short-term and long-term;
• Workforce preparation efforts should begin earlier, with high-quality and universal
career and technical education in middle schools and high schools, while also providing
much better opportunities for adults to update their skills later in their lives through
“lifelong learning” options; and
• Innovative efforts of states to forecast the demand for and supply of skills in fast-
changing economic environments, and to adjust their partnerships accordingly, should be
encouraged and evaluated as well.
67
REFERENCES
Andersson, Fredrik et al. 2013. “Does Federally Funded Job Training Work? Nonexperimental
Impact Estimates Using Longitudinal Data on Workers and Firms.” NBER Working Paper.
Appelbaum, Eileen et al. 2003. Low-Wage America. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Autor, David. 2010. “The Polarization of Job Opportunities in the US Labor Market.” The
Hamilton Project, Brookings Institution and Center for American Progress.
Autor, David. (2014). “Skills, Education and the Rise in Earnings Inequality among the Other 99
Percent.” Science. 344: 6186, 843-851.
Autor, David. 2015. “Why Are There Still So Many Jobs? The History and Future of Workplace
Automation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. Vol. 29, No. 3.
Autor, David and Michael Handel. 2009. “Putting Tasks to the Test: Human Capital, Job Tasks
and Wages.” NBER Working Paper.
Backes, Benjamin et al. 2015. “Is It Worth It? Postsecondary Education and Labor Market
Outcomes for the Disadvantaged.” IZA Journal of Labor Policy. 4:1.
Bailey, Thomas et al. 2015. Redesigning Community Colleges. Cambridge MA: Harvard
University Press.
Barnow, Burt et al. 2013. Occupatioanl Labor Shortages: Concepts, Causes, Consequences and
Cures. Kalamazoo MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute of Employment Research.
Bartik, Timothy. 2012. “The Future of State and Local Economic Development Policy: What
Research is Needed.” Economic Growth and Cultural Change, Vol. 43, No. 4
Beaudry, Paul and David Sand. 2013. “The Gerat Reversal in the Labor Market for Education
and Cognitive Skills.” NBER Working Paper.
Becker, Gary. 1996. Human Capital. Second Edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bettinger, Eric et al. 2013. “Student Supports: Developmental Education and Other Academic
Programs.” The Future of Children, Vol. 23, No. 1.
Blanchard, Olivier and Lawrence Katz. 1992. “Regional Evolutions.” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity.
Brynjolffson, Eric and Andrew Macafee. 2014. The Second Machine Age.
Cappelli, Peter. 2014. “Skill Gaps, Skill Shortages and Skill Mismatches.” NBER Working
Paper.
68
Carnevale, Anthony et al. 2014. Recovery: Job Growth and Educational Requirements Through
2020. Washington DC: Georgetown Center on Education and the Workforce.
Cascio, Elizabeth and Diane Schanzenbach. 2014. “Expanding Pre-School Access for
Disadvantaged Children.” In M. Kearney and B. Harris eds. Policies to Address Poverty in
America. The Hamilton Project, Brookings Institution, Washington DC.
Cellini, Stephanie Riegg and Latika Chaudhary. 2014.“The Labor Market Returns to a For-Profit
College Education.” Economics of Education Review, Vol. 43: 125.
Conway, Maureen and Robert Giloth. 2014. “Introduction.” In M.Conway and R. Giloth eds.
Connecting People to Work: Workforce Intermediaries and Sector Strategies. Washington DC:
Aspen Institute.
Daly, Mary et al. 2012. “A Search and Matching Approach to Labor Markets: Did the Natural
Rate of Unemployment Rise?” Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Davis, Steven et al. 2013. “The Establishment Level Behavior of Vacancies and Hiring.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Dyer, Barbara et al. 2014. “Philanthropic Innovations for Workforce Impact: The National Fund
for Workforce Solutions, 2003-2013.” In M.Conway and R. Giloth eds. Connecting People to
Work: Workforce Intermediaries and Sector Strategies. Washington DC: Aspen Institute.
Elliott, Mark and Anne Roder. 2015. “Workforce Development and Random Control Trial
Evaluations.” Unpublished memo, Economic Mobility Corporation, New York City.
Fairchild, Denise. 2014. “Emerald Cities Collaborative: Case Study of a High Road Sector
Initiative.” In M.Conway and R. Giloth eds. Connecting People to Work: Workforce
Intermediaries and Sector Strategies. Washington DC: Aspen Institute.
Fein, David. 2012. Career Pathways as a Framework for Program Design and Evaluation.
Office of Planning and Research Evaluation, Administration of Children and Families, US
Department of Health and Human Services.
Geel, Regula and Uschi Backes-Gellner. 2011. “Occupational Mobility Within and Between
Skills Clusters: An Empirical Analysis Based on the Skills-Weights Approach.” Empirical
Research in Vocational and Employment Training. Vol. 3, No. 1.
Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence Katz. 2008. The Race Between Education and Technology.
Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Goldrick-Rab, Sara. (2010). “Challenges and Opportunities for Improving Community College
Student Success.” Review of Educational Research, 80:3, 437-469.
69
Heckman, James. 2008. “Schools, Skills, and Synapses.” NBER Working Paper.
Heckman, James et al. 1999. “The Economics and Econometrics of Active Labor Market
Programs.” In O. Ashenfelter and D. Card eds. Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3A.
Amsterdam: North Holland.
Hershbein, Brad and Lisa Kahn. 2015. “Is College the New High School? Evidence from
Vacancy Postings.”
Holzer, Harry. 2015a. Job Market Polarization and Worker Skills: A Tale of Two Middles. Policy
Brief, Economic Studies, Brookings Institution, Washington DC.
Holzer, Harry. 2015b. Higher Education and Workforce Policy: Creating More Skilled Workers
(and Jobs for Them to Fill). Policy Brief, Economic Studies, Brookings Institution, Washington
DC.
Holzer, Harry and Erin Dunlop. 2013. “Just the Facts Ma’am: Postsecondary Education and
Labor Market Outcomes in the US.” CALDER Working Paper, American Institutes for
Research, Washington DC.
Jayuraman, Saru. 2014. “Restaurant Opportunities Centers United: Service the Service Sector.”
In M.Conway and R. Giloth eds. Connecting People to Work: Workforce Intermediaries and
Sector Strategies. Washington DC: Aspen Institute.
Kemple, James. 2008. Career Academies: Long-Term Impacts on Work, Education and
Transitions to Adulthood. New York: MDRC.
Lerman, Robert. 2015. “Do Employers Train Enough? Theory, Evidence and Implications for
Policy.” Commissioned Paper, Study on the Supply Chain for Middle-Skill Jobs. National
Academies of Science, Washington DC.
Leung, Loh-Sze. 2014. “A Brief History of SkillWorks: Partners for a Productive Workforce.” In
M.Conway and R. Giloth eds. Connecting People to Work: Workforce Intermediaries and Sector
Strategies. Washington DC: Aspen Institute.
Long, Bridget Terry. 2014. “Addressing the Academic Barriers to Higher Education.” In M.
Kearney and B. Harris eds. Policies to Address Poverty in America. The Hamilton Project,
Brookings Institution.
70
Loprest, Pamela and Sheila Zedlewski. 2001. “Will TANF Work for the Most Disadvantaged
Families?” In R. Blank and R. Haskins eds. The New World of Welfare. Brookings Institution
Press, Washington DC.
Lumina Foundation. 2015. Making the Case for Reforming the US Credential System.
Washington DC.
Maguire, Sheila et al. 2010. Tuning Into Local Labor Markets. Philadelphia: PPV>
Martin, Vanessa and Joseph Broadus 2013. Enhancing GED Instruction to Prepare Students for College
and Careers: Early Success in LaGuardia Community College's Bridge to Health and Business Program.
New York: MDRC.
Manufacturing Institute. 2014. Manufacturing Skills and Training Study. Washington DC.
McCarthy, Mary Alice. 2014. Beyond the Skills Gap: Making Education Work for Students,
Employers and Communities. Washington DC: New America Foundation.
Michaelides, Marios et al. 2015. Evidence on the Effectiveness of Three Workforce Partnership
Programs in Ohio. IMPAQ, Washington DC.
Modestino, Alicia et al. 2015. “Upskilling: Do Employers Demand More Skills When Workers
are Plentiful?” Unpublished, Northeastern University.
Naimovich, Nir and Henry Siu. 2012. “The Trend is the Cycle: Job Polarization and Jobless
Recoveries.” NBER Working Paper.
National Governors Association.2013. Sector Strategies Come Of Age. Center for Best Practices,
Washington DC.
National Research Council. 2015. Study on the Supply Chain for Middle Skills Jobs. National
Academies Press, Washington DC.
OECD. 2013. Skills Outlook 2013: First Results from the Survey of Adult Skills. Paris.
Osterman, Paul and Andrew Weaver. 2014. “Why Claims of Skills Shortages in Manufacturing
are Overblown.” Economic Policy Institute, Washington DC.
Popovich, Mark. “Journeys and Destinations: The National Fund for Workforce Solutions.” In
M.Conway and R. Giloth eds. Connecting People to Work: Workforce Intermediaries and Sector
Strategies. Washington DC: Aspen Institute.
Reamer, Andrew. 2013. “Using Real time Labor Market Information on a Nationwide Scale,”
policy brief, Credentials That Work Initiative, Jobs for the Future.
Roder, Anne and Mark Elliott. 2011. “A Promising Start: Year Up’s Initial Impacts on Low-
Incme Young Adults’ Careers.” New York: Economic Mobility Corporation.
71
Ross, Martha. 2015. Unemployment Among Young Adults: Exploring Employer-Led Solutions.
Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Rothstein, Jesse. 2012. “The Labor Market Four Years Into the Crisis: Assessing Structural
Explanations.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review. Vol. 65, No. 3.
Schwartz, Nelson. 2013. “Where Factory Apprenticeship is Latest Model from Germany.” The
New York Times. November 30.
Shemkus, Sarah. 2015. “Growing Skills Gap: 80% of Small Businesses Can’t Find Qualified
Staff.” The Guardian. June 22.
Stevens, Ann et al. 2015. “Career and Technical Education and Labor Market Outcomes:
Evidence from California Community Colleges.” NBER Working Paper.
Symonds, William et al. 2011. Pathways to Prosperity. Cambridge MA: Graduate School of
Education, Harvard University.
Uchitelle, Louis. 2009. “Despite Recession, High Demand for Skilled Labor.” The New York
Times. June 23.
Watson, Orson. 2014. “Workforce Intermediaries in a Slack Labor Market: Who Pays and for
What?” In M.Conway and R. Giloth eds. Connecting People to Work: Workforce Intermediaries
and Sector Strategies. Washington DC: Aspen Institute.
White House. 2014. Job-Driven Training and American Opportunity. Washington DC.
Zeidenberg, Matthew et al. 2010. “Washington State’s I-BEST Program: New Evidence of
Effectiveness.” Community College Research Center, Columbia University.
Zinn, Rachel and Andy Van Kluenen. 2014. Making Workforce Data Work. Washington DC:
National Skills Coalition
72
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
David A. Pratt
Professor of Law
Albany Law School
DISCLAIMER: This report was prepared for the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL), Chief Evaluation Office. The
views expressed are those of the authors and should not be attributed to DOL, nor does mention of trade names,
commercial products, or organizations imply endorsement of same by the U.S. Government.
73
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1 INTRODUCTION 75
2 SOCIAL SECURITY 76
4 HEALTH PLANS 86
4.1 Introduction 86
4.2 Access and Coverage 87
4.3 Employee Costs for Health Insurance Coverage 88
4.4 Retiree Health Benefits 89
4.5 The “Cadillac” Tax 90
6 WORKER (MIS)CLASSIFICATION 93
10 CONCLUSION 98
74
1. INTRODUCTION
In 2014, Dr. David Weil published an important book in which he discusses the “fissured
workplace” and its consequences for workers:
The fissured workplace reflects competitive responses to the realities of modern capital and
product markets. The boundaries of firms have been redrawn as a result of new technology
and the falling costs of information. As detailed in Part II, the consequences of the fissured
workplace are profound. Wage determination changes dramatically, often to the detriment of
workers whose work has been shifted outward. Blurring lines of responsibility increase the
risks for bad health and safety outcomes. And the pressure to cut corners and not comply with
basic labor standards intensifies. 1
Anne-Marie Slaughter, among others, has written of the problems women face in the “toxic
workplace”:
The problem is even more acute for the 42 million women in America on the brink of
poverty. Not showing up for work because a child has an ear infection, schools close for a
snow day, or an elderly parent must go to the doctor puts their jobs at risk, and losing their
jobs means that they can no longer care properly for their children -- some 28 million -- and
other relatives who depend on them. They are often suffering not only from too little
flexibility but also too much, as many low-wage service jobs no longer have a guaranteed
number of hours a week.
THE problem is with the workplace, or more precisely, with a workplace designed for
the “Mad Men” era, for “Leave It to Beaver” families in which one partner does all the work
of earning an income and the other partner does all the work of turning that income into care
the care that is indispensable for our children, our sick and disabled, our elderly. Our families
and our responsibilities don’t look like that anymore, but our workplaces do not fit the
realities of our lives. 2
Add to this the continuing effects of the recession (unemployment, underemployment, stagnating
wages, uncertain work schedules) and the picture for many, if not most, working families is not
encouraging.
Qualified employer retirement plans have been regulated under the Internal Revenue Code (the
“Code”) since the 1920s. The Social Security Act and the National Labor Relations Act were
enacted in 1935. The Fair Labor Standards Act was enacted in 1938. Medicare and Medicaid
were enacted in 1965. The Employee Retirement Income Security Act (“ERISA”), which
regulates employee benefit plans (including both retirement plans and health and welfare plans),
was enacted in 1974. These statutes were enacted at times when, by comparison to today, the
1
David Weil The Fissured Workplace: Why Work Became So Bad for So Many and What Can be Done to Improve
It (hereafter, “Weil”), Harvard Univ. Press, 2014, at 180.
2
Anne-Marie Slaughter, A Toxic Work World, New York Times, Sept. 20, 2015, at SR 1.
75
labor market was vastly different, employers were less fixated on quarterly earnings, income
inequality was less pronounced and life expectancies were generally shorter.
In contrast, the Affordable Care Act 3 is only 5 years old: though it has already significantly
increased access to health care, eliminated many questionable insurance practices and reduced
the number of uninsured Americans, it has been subjected to incessant attacks and threats of
repeal. If one looked only at statements made by our elected representatives, one could conclude
that Americans do not want retirement security or access to good health care (at least, not for
other people). I believe that this is incorrect, but people must make their voices heard to convince
employers and politicians that these are vital issues for the survival of America as a great,
prosperous and compassionate society.
2. SOCIAL SECURITY
Social Security continues to be the largest single source of income for elderly Americans. In
2012, Americans aged 65 or older received 38% of their income from Social Security, with
another 18.4% coming from pensions and annuities. 4
“Social Security is the major source of income for most of the elderly.
Nine out of ten individuals age 65 and older receive Social Security benefits.
Social Security benefits represent about 39% of the income of the elderly.
Among elderly Social Security beneficiaries, 53% of married couples and 74% of unmarried
persons receive 50% or more of their income from Social Security.
Among elderly Social Security beneficiaries, 22% of married couples and about 47% of
unmarried persons rely on Social Security for 90% or more of their income.” 5
The following shows estimated Social Security benefits for workers reaching retirement age (age
66) in 2015 at different earnings levels and illustrates the downward gradation in Social Security
replacement levels, that occurs as earnings levels increase. Low earnings 44.5%; medium
earnings 32.9%; high earnings 27.3%. These replacement ratios will decline over the next 20 to
30 years. Reasons for this decline include the legislated increase in the “full-benefit age” for
3
The Affordable Care Act (or ACA) is a shorthand name for two separate statutes, the Patient Protection and
Affordable Care Act, P.L. 111-148, signed on March 23, 2010, and the Health Care and Education Reconciliation
Act, P.L. 111-152, signed on March 30, 2010.
4
Employee Benefit Research Institute, Databook on Employee Benefits, chapter 3, chart 3.1b, updated July 2014.
For 1974, the corresponding percentages were 42% and 14%. Id., chart 3.1a. See also Social Security
Administration, Income of the Population 55 or Older, 2012, available at www.ssa.gov.
5
Social Security Basic Facts, October 13, 2015, https://www.socialsecurity.gov/news/press/basicfact.html. See also
Ke Bin Wu, Sources of Income for Older Americans, 2012, AARP Public Policy Institute, www.aarp.org, finding
that “Social Security accounts for about four out of every five dollars of income for older people with low to
moderate incomes” and that “In 2012, Social Security benefits kept about 15 million people aged 65 and older out of
poverty. Without Social Security income, the poverty rate for this group would rise from 9.1 percent to 44.4
percent.”
76
receiving Social Security benefits, increased income taxation of Social Security benefits, and
rising Medicare premiums that are deducted directly from Social Security benefits. 6
It is clear that the financing of Social Security needs to be recalibrated, but the situation is
nowhere near as dire as the alarmists suggest. And one solution advocated by many, including
several Presidential candidates, raising the retirement age across the board, would affect lower
income retirees drastically:
Advocates of the idea usually argue the reform makes sense because life spans are rising. If
we leave the Social Security retirement age unchanged, the increase in life expectancy means
payments from the program must cover more years, even though the number of years we
expect workers to remain employed will remain unchanged. This argument would be more
convincing if increases in life expectancy were spread evenly across the workforce. They are
not. Workers who earn low wages throughout their careers have seen little or no improvement
in life expectancy. It seems unfair to ask low-earners to take a benefit cut to pay for the added
benefits high-earners enjoy because of longer life spans….Researchers in the Social Security
Administration and elsewhere have found that men near the bottom of the earnings
distribution and women with below-average schooling and in families with low incomes have
seen little or none of the improvement in life expectancy that higher income groups have
enjoyed.
Low income workers always had shorter life expectancies than workers with higher incomes.
New research shows that the gaps in life expectancy are growing…. These new estimates
[from the National Academy of Sciences] indicate that life expectancies are typically higher
for men and women with higher incomes, but that remaining life expectancy at age 50 has
remained almost unchanged or fallen at the bottom of the distribution, whereas it has
increased substantially at the top. 7
In fact, there is a strong argument that Social Security should be expanded: it is the most efficient
part of the overall retirement system, it protects beneficiaries against inflation, investment risk,
longevity risk and cognitive risk, and by redistributing (to some extent) resources to lower-
earning beneficiaries it can fill some of the gaps in the private retirement system. 8
6
Social Security Administration, Office of the Chief Actuary, Actuarial Note Number 2014.9, July 2014, http://
www.socialsecurity.gov/OACT/NOTES/ran9/an2014-9.pdf.
7
Gary Burtless, Raising everyone’s retirement age undercuts a key goal of Social Security, Oct. 22, 2015,
http://www.brookings.edu/research/opinions/2015/10/22-raising-everyones-retirement-age-undercuts-key-goal-of
social-security-burtless. See also Esmé E Deprez, Margarte Newkirk, Republican Plans to Raise Retirement Age
Fall Heavily on Poor: “In wealthy Fairfax County, just outside Washington, the average woman can expect to
celebrate her 84th birthday, and men their 81st. Travel 130 miles (210 kilometers) south to Petersburg, a poor,
majority-black city near Richmond, and those figures plummet by 11 years for women and 14 for men. In 2010, a
50-year-old man in the poorest quintile could expect to die 13 years earlier than his counterpart in the richest,
according to a report last month by the National Academies of Sciences, Engineering and Medicine. In 1980, the
difference was just five years. Life expectancy for the least educated white people (education is often used as a
proxy for income) has actually fallen since 1990, according to a 2012 study by the journal Health Affairs.”
8
See, e.g., Monique Morrissey, The State of U.S. Retirement Security: Can the Middle Class Afford to Retire?,
March 12, 2014, testifying before the U.S. Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs
Subcommittee on Economic Policy,
77
Why is Social Security the subject of such virulent attacks? According to Paul Krugman,
“The decline of private pensions has left working Americans more reliant on Social Security than
ever…. By a very wide margin, ordinary Americans want to see Social Security expanded. But
by an even wider margin, Americans in the top 1 percent want to see it cut.” 9
In 1974, when ERISA was enacted, the defined benefit plan still dominated the landscape. Since
then, the number of defined benefit plans, and the number of participants accruing benefits under
defined benefit plans, have declined sharply. According to the Employee Benefit Research
Institute (EBRI), in 1974-1975 43.7% of private nonfarm wage and salary workers were
participating in a defined benefit plan and there were 103,346 defined benefit plans: by 2003
2004, these numbers had declined to 16.8% and 26,000, respectively. 11
In 1974, it would have seemed inconceivable that iconic companies like IBM and General
Electric would cease providing defined benefit plans to new employees. However, they have
done so, along with other household names, including Boeing, Honda, Chrysler, General Motors,
Bank of America, Disney and Anheuser Busch. 12
As of January, 2013, the number of single employer defined benefit plans covered by the
Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation (“PBGC”) insurance program fell to 22,697, an all-time
low. In 1985, PBGC insured more than 112,000 single employer plans. “Only 11 Fortune 100
companies offered traditional defined benefit plans to new employees as of June 30, down from
78
19 in 2009.” 19 more companies offered hybrid plans, down from 35 in 2004. 13 In 1998, 90
percent of Fortune 100 companies offered defined benefit plans to new salaried employees. 14
The percentage of workers covered by a traditional defined benefit (DB) pension plan that
pays a lifetime annuity, often based on years of service and final salary, has been steadily
declining over the past 25 years. From 1980 through 2008, the proportion of private wage and
salary workers participating in DB pension plans fell from 38 percent to 20 percent. In
contrast, the percentage of workers covered by a defined contribution (DC) pension plan—
that is, an investment account established and often subsidized by employers, but owned and
controlled by employees—has been increasing over time. From 1980 through 2008, the
proportion of private wage and salary workers participating in only DC pension plans
increased from 8 percent to 31 percent. More recently, many employers have frozen their DB
plans. 15
In 2011, defined benefit plans covered 67 percent of union employees but only 13 percent of
nonunion workers, and covered 22 percent of full-time workers but only 8 percent of part
timers. 16
Commentators have advanced many reasons for the decline of defined benefit plans. One major
reason, for both large and small employers, has been the volatility and unpredictability of the
required minimum contributions. Around 2000, the combination of historically low interest rates
and stock market volatility caused a “perfect storm”.
Recent legislative and regulatory developments have not encouraged employers to look more
kindly on defined benefit plans. The Pension Protection Act of 2006 tightened the funding
requirements significantly. More recently, the budget agreement, HR 1314, signed by the
President on November 2, 2015, includes the third PBGC premium hike for single employer
plans since 2012. The flat rate premium increases from $64 in 2016 to $80 after 2018. The
variable rate premium is $30 per $1,000 of unfunded vested benefits in 2016 and increases to
$41 in 2019.
In response to concerns that information regarding pension obligations and assets should be more
useful and transparent for investors, the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) changed
the balance sheet rules. Under Statement of Financial Accounting Standards (SFAS) 158,
“Employers’ Accounting for Defined Benefit Pension and Other Postretirement Plans,” adopted
13
Jerry Geisel, Number of defined benefit plans hit all-time low, Business Insurance, Feb. 28, 2013.
14
Jerry Geisel, Fewer Employers Offering Defined Benefit Pension Plans to New Salaried Employees, Workplace,
October 3, 2012.
15
Barbara A. Butrica, Howard M. Iams, Karen E. Smith, and Eric J. Toder, The Disappearing Defined Benefit
Pension and Its Potential Impact on the Retirement Incomes of Baby Boomers, Social Security Bulletin, Vol. 69,
No. 3, 2009 at 1. See also William J. Wiatrowski, The last private industry pension plans: a visual essay, Monthly
Labor Review, December 2012, pp. 3-18, stating that “In 2011, only 10 percent of all private sector establishments
provided defined benefit plans, covering 18 percent of private industry employees…. 78 percent of state and local
government workers had such coverage in 2011.” and noting that 35 percent of private industry workers had such
coverage in the early 1990s. “Among establishments with fewer than 50 workers, 8 percent offered a defined benefit
plan. In contrast, among establishments with 500 or more workers, 48 percent offered a plan.” Id.
16
Wiatrowski, note 15 above, at 7.
79
in 2006, plan sponsors must now recognize plan assets and obligations in their balance sheets.
SFAS 158 made no change in the way net pension expense is included in the plan sponsor’s
income statement, but FASB is reviewing those rules as well. 17 SFAS 158 makes balance sheets
much more volatile.
In the period from 1993 to 2010, real income grew by 13.8%. For the bottom 99% of the
income distribution, the real growth rate was 6.4%, while for the top 1% the real growth rate
was 58%.... Between 1979 and 2009, productivity rose by 80%. Over the same period,
however, average hourly wages increased by only 7%, and average hourly compensation
(wages plus benefits) increased by 8%. 18
The average male worker’s real earnings have declined: “The typical man with a full-time job–
the one at the statistical middle of the middle–earned $50,383 last year, the Census Bureau
reported this week. The typical man with a full-time job in 1973 earned $53,294, measured in
2014 dollars to adjust for inflation.” 19 According to one recent report, ‘Out of a total of 160.1
million full-time and part-time American workers with earnings, 115.2 million workers (72%)
make less than the U.S. mean (average) income of $54,964.” 20
According to Harvard economist Larry Katz, “Economists differ over how much of this [wage
inequality] is the result of globalization, technological change, changing social mores, and
government policies, but there is no longer much dispute about the fact that inequality is
increasing.” 21
Wage stagnation, unemployment, underemployment and unstable work patterns result in lower
Social Security benefits and make it more difficult for individuals to save for long-term needs,
such as retirement, when they are having difficulty paying their bills. 22 Defined benefit plans are
not inherently superior to defined contribution plans. However, they do have some characteristics
that provide important safeguards to plan participants, particularly those who have lower
incomes and/or are financially unsophisticated. In the private sector, defined benefit plans are
almost always funded entirely by the employer and participation is automatic. Defined benefit
17
See Denise Lugo, FASB Approves Proposal on Presentation of Net Benefit Cost, BNA Pension and Benefits
Reporter, Nov. 2, 2015, 42 BPR 1952.
18
Weil, note 1 above. at 281.
19
David Wessel, The typical male U.S. worker earned less in 2014 than in 1973,
http://www.brookings.edu/research/opinions/2015/09/17-male-us-worker-earned-less-in-2014-than-in-1973
wessel.
20
Chuck Vollmer, Jobenomics U.S. Unemployment Analysis, Q 3 2015, Nov. 10, 2015, www.jobenomics.com.
21
Wessel, note 19, citing Larry Katz.
22
“Lower income employees cannot be expected to provide for the future when current income is barely adequate
for a minimum standard of living.” Daniel I. Halperin, Special Tax Treatment for Employer-Based Retirement
Programs: Is It ‘Still’ Viable as a Means of Increasing Retirement Income? Should It Continue?, 49 Tax L. Rev. 1
(1993), at 14.
80
plans also protect individuals against investment risk, longevity risk, and cognitive risk (the risk
that your assets will last longer than your wits).
Numerous studies establish that most individuals are not saving enough for retirement, including
those aged 55 to 64:
Retirement savings are unequally distributed across and within income fifths. Among middle-
income households, for example, only half (52 percent) had savings in these accounts in 2010.
The average among all households was $34,981, which means those with positive savings
averaged around $67,000 ($34,981/52 percent). The median (50th percentile) balance in these
accounts was much lower ($23,000) than the mean, reflecting an unequal distribution of
retirement savings even for middle-income households with positive balances. In 2010,
households in the top income-fifth accounted for 72 percent of total savings in retirement
accounts. Disparities in retirement savings, part of a larger problem of rising wealth
inequality, are only partly explained by income inequality.
The trends exhibited in these figures paint a picture of increasingly inadequate savings and
retirement income for successive cohorts and growing disparities by income, race, ethnicity,
education, and marital status. Even women, who by some measures appear to be narrowing
gaps with men (in large part because men are faring worse than they did before) are ill-served
by an inefficient retirement system that shifts risk onto workers, including the risk of outliving
one’s retirement savings. The existence of retirement system (sic) that does not work for most
workers underscores the importance of preserving and strengthening Social Security,
defending defined-benefit pensions for workers who have them, and seeking solutions for
those who do not. 23
In order for a 401(k) plan to provide adequate retirement savings for an employee, the employee
should (1) start to contribute at the earliest possible date; (2) contribute each year, without
interruption,24 at least the amount required to obtain the maximum available match, and increase
23
Natalie Sabadish and Monique Morrissey, Retirement Inequality Chartbook: How the 401(k) revolution created a
few big winners and many losers, September 6, 2013, www.epi.org/publication/retirement-inequality-chartbook/.
See also the studies published by, among others, the Employee Benefit Research Institute, available at
www.ebri.org, and the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, http://crr.bc.edu/. The Government
Accountability Office found that about half of households age 55 and older have no retirement savings in a 401(k)
plan or IRA. About 29 percent have neither retirement savings nor a defined benefit plan. Among the 48 percent of
households with some retirement savings, the median amount is approximately $109,000, equivalent at current rates
to an inflation-protected annuity of $405 per month for a 65-year-old. About 55 percent of households age 55-64
have less than $25,000 in retirement savings, including 41 percent who have zero. 27 percent of this age group have
neither retirement savings nor a DB plan. For the 59 percent of households age 55-64 with some retirement savings,
the estimated median amount is about $104,000. While about 15 percent of these households have retirement
savings over $500,000, 11 percent have retirement savings below $10,000 and 24 percent have savings of less than
$25,000. GAO, Most Households Approaching Retirement Have Low Savings, GAO-15-419, May 12, 2015. For
comments on the report, see Jack VanDerhei, GAO Report on Retirement Savings: Overall Gaps Identified, but the
Focus of Retirement Security Reform Should be on the Uncovered Population, June 4, 2015. See also Retirement
Savings Shortfalls: Evidence from EBRI’s Retirement Security Projection Model, February 2015, EBRI Issue Brief
#410, available at www.ebri.org, noting “the extreme importance of longevity risk and nursing home and home
health care costs in simulating Retirement Savings Shortfalls.”
24
This is difficult for the vast majority of employees who have several jobs during their lifetimes, as each
employer’s plan will typically require satisfaction of a waiting period.
81
the rate of contributions as he or she ages; (3) consistently make good investment choices and
avoid paying excessive fees; 25 and (4) avoid depleting the account by taking in-service
distributions (e.g., for hardship) or failing to keep accumulated savings in an employer plan or
IRA. After retirement, the individual must continue to manage the fund astutely for life and be
able to respond to changing financial needs (e.g., for health care or long term care) and declines
in cognitive ability. Where did we get the idea that this was within the capacity of every
American worker?
If we assume, as we must, that 401(k) plans will continue to be the lynchpin of the private
pension system in the USA for the foreseeable future, then we must increase the level of plan
participation; increase the amounts contributed by employers and employees; ensure that those
contributions are invested successfully; reduce the amount of pre-retirement leakage; provide
more effective lifetime income options; and do all this at an acceptable cost in terms of tax
incentives. In addition, simplification would help to make plans more attractive to employers and
reduce the cost of compliance.
A report by the Center for Effective Government and the Institute of Policy Studies found that
the 100 largest U.S. CEO retirement packages are worth $ 4.9 billion, equal to the entire
retirement savings of 41% of American families. 26 “In contrast, nearly half of all working age
Americans do not have access to a retirement plan at work. The median 401(k) balance was
$18,433 at the end of 2013, enough to generate a $104 monthly retirement check for life, the
report said.” 27
Corporate executives have strong incentives to increase profits to boost stock prices (and thus the
value of stock options) by reducing expenses (including workers’ wages and benefits). “And
since more than half of executive compensation is tied to the company’s stock price, every dollar
not spent on employee retirement security is money in the CEO’s pocket. YUM Brands former
CEO David Novak is sitting on the largest retirement nest egg in the Fortune 500, with $234
million, while hundreds of thousands of his Taco Bell, Pizza Hut, and KFC employees have no
company retirement assets whatsoever.” 28
Past attempts to restrain executive compensation through the tax law 29 have not been very
successful. However, there is no doubt that executives do derive substantial current economic
benefits from deferring compensation, and that some attempt should be made to tax this benefit
25
See, e.g., The Effects of Conflicted Investment Advice on Retirement Savings, Council of Economic Advisers,
Feb. 2015; Christian E. Weller and Teresa Ghilarducci, The Inefficencies of Existing Retirement Savings
Incentives, Center for American Progress. Oct. 29, 2015; Matthew O’Brien, The Crushingly Expensive Mistake
Killing Your Retirement, The Atlantic, Feb. 15, 2004; John Chalmers and Jonathan Reuter, Is Conflicted Investment
Advice Better Than No Advice, Sept. 24, 2015 (concluding that the answer is no).
26
A Tale of Two Retirements, http://www.foreffectivegov.org/two-retirements.
27
Meaghan Kilroy, 100 largest CEO retirement accounts equal 41% of American families' retirement savings-
report, October 28, 2015, http://www.pionline.com/article/20151028/ONLINE/151029838/100-largest-ceo
retirement-accounts-equal-41-of-american-families-retirement-savings-8212-report.
28
Kilroy, note 27 above. The percentage of executive pay represented by performance based compensation, such as
stock options, has increased dramatically since the enactment of Code section 162(m), which places a $1 million
annual cap on the deductibility by public companies of compensation of “covered employees” but provides an
exception for “performance-based compensation”.
29
Primarily, Code sections 162(m), 280G and 409A.
82
currently. The basic argument for imposing special lower limits on employees of governmental
and non-profit employers is that those employers do not lose a current tax deduction as the price
for providing deferred compensation. Perhaps there should be annual limits on the amount
deferred by an employee of any employer, even if the limit for businesses is higher than for
governments and non-profits. In any event, the current regime under Code sections 409A, 457
and 457A is unnecessarily complex, and cries out for simplification.
The Bureau of Labor standards (“BLS”) found that “Retirement benefits were available to 66
percent of private industry workers in the United States in March 2015…. Employer-provided
retirement benefits were available to 31 percent of private industry workers in the lowest wage
category (the 10th percentile). By contrast 88 percent of workers in the highest wage category
(the 90th percentile) had access to retirement benefits. In state and local government, 61 percent
of workers in the lowest wage category had access to retirement benefits, compared with 98
percent of workers in the highest wage category. (See chart 1 and table 1.)” 30 However, because
participation in 401(k) plans is voluntary, unlike most defined benefit plans, the take up rate was
74% so the actual percentage of workers who were participating was only 49%. 31 Among full-
time workers, the access and participation rates were 76% and 59%, respectively: for part-time
workers, the rates were only 37% and 19%. For union workers, the access and participation rates
were 92% and 82%: for non –union workers, they were only 63% and 46%. 32 Firm size also had
a significant effect: for firms with 1 to 99 workers, the access and participation rates were 51%
and 35%: for firms with 100 or more workers they were 84% and 65%. 33
The evidence is clear: retirement plan access and participation are strongly correlated with higher
incomes; full-time status; union membership; and larger employers. As discussed in section 4.1
below, the same patterns apply to employer-provided health plan access and coverage.
“Many employees who are offered a plan do not participate, generally because they do not wish
to, or feel that they cannot afford to, contribute. Other workers are excluded, temporarily or
permanently, by the plan’s eligibility rules: they have not completed a year of service, or are
under the age of 21, work too few hours, are in an ineligible class of employees, or are classified
as independent contractors. In America, we generally have a strong preference for voluntary
programs rather than government mandates: however, it is unrealistic to expect that a system
where employer sponsorship of a plan, employer contributions to a plan and employee
contributions to a plan are all voluntary will succeed in providing adequate retirement income for
most Americans, even when supplemented by Social Security.” 34
30
BLS News Release, July 24, 2015, Employee Benefits In The United States –March 2015. www.bls.gov/ebs.
31
Id., Table 1.
32
Id.
33
Id.
34
David Pratt, Private Pension Reform, New York University Review of Employee Benefits and Executive
Compensation, forthcoming, 2015.
83
Part of the problem results from unemployment and underemployment: “the low participation
rates of lower-income respondents are driven primarily by weak labor force attachment and
working for a firm without a pension. Only about half of the lower-income individuals are
working and, among those who are working, only about 60 per-cent work for firms that offer a
pension. These figures indicate serious trouble spots for participation. Eligibility and take-up
rates among the lower income also help to explain their low participation, but these factors are
considerably less important as both are between 85-90 percent. Of course, providing universal
pension coverage in the workplace would still leave a large fraction of lower-income individuals
without coverage due to their low employment rates. Thus, the only way to further expand
participation would be through measures to boost employment.” 35
Why don’t small employers offer retirement plans? According to the 2002 Small Employer
Retirement Survey (SERS) (involving employers with 5 to 100 full-time workers), the most
commonly cited “most important” reasons for not having a plan were: employees prefer wages
and/or other benefits; revenue is too uncertain to commit to a plan; a large portion of workers are
seasonal, part time or high turnover; required company contributions are too expensive; and it
costs too much to set up and administer a plan. 36 According to a 2001 U.S. Department of Labor
Working Group Report, “Significant reasons why more employers do not sponsor pension plans
for any or some of their employees include: concerns over the business realities of revenues and
profit; the nature of the employer’s workforce; employee preferences for cash and health
insurance; the decline in unionization; the cost of setting-up and administering a plan; concerns
about government regulation and liability; and a lack of information or knowledge among
employers and employees.” 37
In February, 2012, Phyllis C. Borzi, assistant secretary of labor for the Employee Benefits
Security Administration, said that unless pensions and retirement savings plans are more
attractive to employers, efforts to expand coverage and participation will fall short of what is
necessary. 38 One recent study noted that “Legal reforms now offer employers tax credits for
sponsoring a plan, special plans with little or no discrimination tests like the auto-enrollment safe
harbor 401(k) plan, and reduced fiduciary liability through participant investment discretion and
the use of Qualified Default Investment Alternatives as investment options. Yet there has been
no appreciable increase in the percentage of employers, particularly small to mid-size employers,
willing to offer plans.” 39
Under a defined benefit (DB) plan, employees are automatically enrolled and (in the private
sector) rarely have to contribute. With most DC plans, the majority of which are now 401(k)
type plans, workers are responsible for their own financial security. Barbara Butrica and her
coauthors wrote that if plans don’t “include automatic features, workers have to actively decide
to participate, how much to contribute, which investments to put their money in, and how to
35
April Yanyuan Wu, Matthew S. Rutledge, and Jacob Penglase, Why Don’t Lower-Income Individuals Have
Pensions?, Center for Retirement Research, April 2014.
36
2002 Small Employer Retirement Survey, Summary of Findings, www.ebri.org.
37
U.S. Department of Labor, Report of the Working Group on Increasing Pension Coverage, Participation and
Benefits, November 13, 2001.
38
BNA Pension & Benefits Reporter, 39 BPR 396, Feb. 28, 2012.
39
C. Eugene Steuerle, Benjamin H. Harris and Pamela J. Perun, Entitlement Reform and the Future of Pensions,
September 2014, PRC WP2014-08, Pension Research Council.
84
manage their benefits through retirement.” 40 Consequently, in 2013 the participation rates of
“private wage-and-salary workers who were offered an employer retirement plan were 87
percent in defined benefit pensions but only 71 percent in DC plans.” DC plans with automatic
enrollment features, in which employees must opt out of participating in the plan instead of
affirmatively enrolling, see higher participation rates, around 80 percent or more. 41
Ideally, employees would begin to save for retirement as soon as they enter the workforce and
contribute continuously throughout their working lives. The current eligibility rules impede that
goal:
A plan may require the completion of a year of service before an employee is eligible. Most
workers have several jobs during their lives, and thus have to satisfy several separate waiting
periods during which they are not covered by a plan.
A plan may exclude permanently workers who are part time, are in an ineligible job category or
are not classified as employees of the sponsoring employer.
The administration’s 2016 budget proposal would require retirement plans to allow long-term
part-time workers to participate, by permitting an employee to make salary reduction
contributions if the employee has worked at least 500 hours per year with the employer for at
least three consecutive years. The proposal would not require them to receive any employer
contributions. The proposal would also require a plan to credit, for each year in which such an
employee worked at least 500 hours, a year of service for purposes of vesting. With respect to
employees newly covered under the proposed change, employers would receive
nondiscrimination testing relief (similar to current-law relief for plans covering otherwise
excludable employees), including permission to exclude these employees from top-heavy vesting
and benefit requirements. 42
“This proposal is a start, but it does not go far enough. The one year waiting period should be
reduced to no more than 90 days (the permissible waiting period for health plan coverage under
the Affordable Care Act); part-time employees should be covered; and the ability of employers
to exclude classes of employees (other than union employees and non-resident aliens) should be
severely curtailed, possibly by increasing the 70% coverage threshold.” 43
The Obama administration is monitoring the automatic enrollment strategies being adopted in
other countries: “Mark Iwry, the Treasury Department’s deputy assistant secretary for retirement
and health policy, recently told a conference audience that “the administration is monitoring
retirement innovations around the globe and is particularly interested in the approach being
developed in the U.K. In October 2012, the U.K. launched a broad retirement savings initiative,
which included the creation of a low-cost savings platform known as the National Employment
40
Barbara A. Butrica et al., “Flattening Tax Incentives for Retirement,” Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center (June
30, 2014), available at http://www.brookings.edu.
41
Harris et al., “Tax Subsidies for Asset Development: An Overview and Distributional Analysis,” at 13 (the Urban
Institute, 2014), available at http://www.taxpolicycenter.org.
42
General Explanations of the Administration’s Fiscal Year 2016 Revenue Proposals (the “Green Book’), pp. 140
141.
43
Pratt, note 34 above; Code section 410(b).
85
Savings Trust (NEST). By statute, all employers in the U.K. must automatically enroll eligible
employees in an approved retirement savings system, a NEST product, or a traditional pension-
and make annual contributions. Iwry conceded that the administration's myRA program-
launched nationwide Nov. 4 (see related article in this issue)-is modest compared with the U.K.
model. Unlike the U.K. model, the myRA program doesn’t require employers to make
contributions to the accounts.” 44
In addition to the myRA program, there is a push to enable States to enact coverage expansion
laws that would not be preempted by ERISA. DOL issued a proposed rule on November 18,
2015. 45
4 HEALTH PLANS
4.1 Introduction
The patterns of health plan coverage are similar to those of retirement plan coverage: large
employers are significantly more likely to offer coverage to at least some of their employees;
coverage is also closely correlated with higher income, union membership and full-time rather
than part-time status. There are two additional factors. First, the cost of health coverage has
increased for many years at a rate significantly higher than the general inflation rate, putting
increased financial strain on both employers and employees. “Health care costs at current levels
override the incentives that have historically supported employer-based health insurance. Now
that health costs loom so large, companies that provide generous benefits are in effect paying
some of their workers much more than the going wage—or, more to the point, more than
competitors pay similar workers. Inevitably, this creates pressure to reduce or eliminate health
benefits. And companies that can’t cut benefits enough to stay competitive—such as GM—find
their very existence at risk.” 46
Second, the Affordable Care Act, while improving access and coverage generally, caused
employers to question whether they should continue to offer coverage. The most recent evidence
is encouraging: “While Mercer’s surveys have consistently shown that large employers remain
committed to offering health coverage, in the early days of the health reform debate sizable
numbers of small employers thought it was likely that they would drop their plans and send
employees to the public exchange. In 2013, 21% of employers with 50-499 employees said they
were likely to drop their plans within the next five years; this number fell to 15% in 2014 and to
44
Michael J. Bologna, Administration Looks to U.K. for Retirement Savings Model, Pension & Benefits Daily
(BNA), Nov. 4, 2015.
45
80 Fed. Reg. 72,006, Nov. 18, 2015. See also the DOL Fact Sheet, State Savings Programs for Non-Governmental
Employees, Nov. 16, 2015, available at www.dol.gov/ebsa/newsroom/.
46
Paul Krugman & Robin Wells, The Health Care Crisis and What To Do About It, The N.Y. Review of Books 38,
39 (Mar. 23, 2006) (reviewing Henry J Aaron et al., Can We Say No? (2005), Julius Richmond & Rashi Fein, The
Health Care Mess (2006), John F. Cogan, et al., Healthy, Wealthy, and Wise (2005)).
86
just 7% this year. Among employers with 500 or more employees, just 5% say they are likely to
drop their plans, essentially unchanged from 4% last year.” 47
In March, 2015, according to BLS, “For private industry, 87 percent of workers in management,
professional, and related occupations had access to medical care, compared with 41 percent in
service occupations. In state and local government, the corresponding figures were 89 percent
and 82 percent, respectively. (See table 2.) For civilian workers, access rates to medical care
ranged from 53 percent for the smallest establishments (those with fewer than 50 workers) to 90
percent for the largest establishments (those employing 500 workers or more)…. Access to
medical care benefits for private industry workers was 86 percent in goods-producing industries,
compared with 66 percent for workers in service-providing industries.” 48
Health benefits were available to 86% of full-time private sector workers but only 21% of part-
time private sector workers: the participation rates were 64% and 12%. 49 The access and
participation rates for union workers were 95% and 79%, compared to 67% and 47% for non
union workers. The access rates for workers in the lowest 25% and the lowest 10% of average
wages were only 34% and 23%, and the participation rates were 20% and 11%. 50 Private sector
employers with fewer than 50 employees offered coverage to 53% of their workers and 38%
participated. For firms with 100 or more employees, the rates were 84% and 62%. 51
Most plans impose a waiting period, and in 2015 the average waiting period is 2 months.
“Before eligible employees may enroll, almost three-quarters (74%) of covered workers face a
waiting period, although the average length of waiting periods for covered workers with waiting
periods has decreased in each of the last two years.” 52
These coverage patterns matter because of the large number of part-time and other contingent
workers; the continuing decline in, and state level attacks on, union membership; and the large
number of workers who work for small employers or other firms that are at or near the bottom of
the fissured workplace pyramid described by David Weil.
47
Mercer, With the Excise Tax in their Sights, Employers Hold Health Benefits Cost Growth to 3.8% in 2015, Nov.
19, 2015, available at www.mercer.com/newsroom, discussing the Mercer National Survey of Employer-Sponsored
Health Plans.
48
Bureau of Labor Standards, News Release, Employee Benefits in the United States-March, 2015,
www.bls.gov/ebs.
49
Id. See also Kaiser Family Foundation, 2015 Employer Health Benefits Survey, Section 2: “Among firms offering
health benefits, relatively few offer benefits to their part-time and temporary workers…. In 2015, 19% of all firms
that offer health benefits offer them to part-time workers (Exhibit 2.6). Firms with 200 or more workers are more
likely to offer health benefits to part-time employees than firms with 3 to 199 workers (35% vs. 18%) (Exhibit 2.9).
Among firms offering health benefits to at least some employees, relatively few report that they stopped offering
benefits to part-time workers in the last year (2%) (Exhibit 2.7). A small percentage (3%) of firms offering health
benefits offer them to temporary workers (Exhibit 2.8). More large firms (200 or more workers) offering health
benefits elect to offer temporary workers coverage than small firms (11% vs. 3%) (Exhibit 2.10).”
50
BLS, note 48, Table 2.
51
Id.
52
Kaiser Family Foundation, note 49, Section 3.
87
4.3 Employee Costs for Health Insurance Coverage
According to BLS, “The share of premiums workers were required to pay for their medical
coverage [in March, 2015] varied by bargaining status. Private industry nonunion workers were
responsible for 23 percent of the total single coverage medical premium, whereas the share of
premiums for union workers was 13 percent. The share of premiums for family coverage was 35
percent for nonunion workers and 16 percent for union workers. (See chart 2 and tables 3 and
4.)…. The employee share of family medical premiums was 27 percent for workers in goods-
producing industries and 33 percent for workers in service-providing industries. (See tables 2 and
4.) ” 53
The share of the premium paid by the worker also varied by full-time or part-time status (21%
for full-timers, 27% for part-timers) and by average wages (20% for the highest paid 10% but
30% for the lowest paid 10%). 54
For family coverage, employers paid 68% of the premium for full-time workers, and 63% for
part-timers; 84% for union workers and 65% for non-union workers; 72% for the 10% of
workers with the highest average wages and 57% for the 10% with the lowest wages. Firms with
500 or more workers paid 76% of the family premium; firms with fewer than 50 employees paid
62%. 55
According to the Kaiser Family Foundation 2015 Employer Health Benefits Survey,56 “Annual
premiums for employer-sponsored family health coverage reached $17,545 this year, up 4
percent from last year, with workers paying on average $4,955 towards the cost of their
coverage. Employer-sponsored insurance covers over half of the non-elderly population, 147
million people in total. The average annual single coverage premium is $6,251.”
With respect to responses to the ACA, “Relatively small percentages of employers with 50 or
more full-time equivalent employees reported switching full-time employees to part time status
(4%), changing part-time workers to full-time workers (10%), reducing the number of full-time
employees they intended to hire (5%) or increasing waiting periods (2%) in response to the
employer shared responsibility provision which took effect for some firms this year.” 57
Between 2005 and 2015, “total premiums for family coverage increased by 61%. The worker
contribution increased by 83% and the employer contribution by 54%. As with total premiums,
the share of the premium contributed by workers varies considerably…. the average annual
premium contributions in 2015 are $1,071 for single coverage and $4,955 for family
coverage.” 58
53
BLS, note 48 above.
54
Id., Table 3.
55
Id., Table 4.
56
Kaiser Family Foundation 2015 Employer Health Benefits Survey, Sep. 22, 2015, www.kff.org, Summary of
Findings.
57
Id.
58
Id. See also Exhibit 1.12 Average Annual Premiums for Covered Workers with Family Coverage, by Firm Size,
1999-2005
88
There has been a significant increase in participation in high deductible plans. “Almost a quarter
(24%) of covered workers are enrolled in HDHP/SOs in 2015; enrollment in these plans has
increased over time from 13% of covered workers in 2010.” 59 This trend raises policy concerns,
particularly with respect to lower income workers. “Enrollment in HDHP/SOs is higher for
covered workers employed at firms with many low-wage workers (at least 35% of workers earn
$23,000 per year or less) than firms with fewer low-wage workers.” 60 This suggests that at least
some workers are enrolling in high deductible plans because their share of the premium is less
than it would be under another type of plan. “The average worker contribution in HDHP/SOs is
lower than the overall average worker contributions for single coverage ($868 vs. $1,071) and
family coverage ($3,917 vs. $4,955) (Exhibit 6.5).” 61 However, these individuals may incur
much higher out of pocket medical expenses. “The average annual out-of-pocket maximum for
single coverage is $3,866 for HDHP/HRAs and $4,085 for HSA-qualified HDHPs (Exhibit
8.7).” 62
Not surprisingly, “The cost of health insurance remains the primary reason cited by firms for not
offering health benefits. Among small firms (3-199 workers) not offering health benefits, 41%
cite high cost as “the most important reason” for not doing so, followed by “employees are
generally covered under another plan” (26%) (Exhibit 2.14). Relatively few employers indicate
that they did not offer because they believe that employees will get a better deal on the health
insurance exchanges (4%).” 63
Retiree health benefits are an important part of retirement security in view of the substantial, and
increasing, out of pocket medical costs incurred by the elderly, including Medicare premiums,
deductibles and co-payments. According to EBRI, “In 2015, a 65-year-old man needs $68,000 in
savings and a 65-year-old woman needs $89,000 if each has a goal of having a 50 percent chance
of having enough money saved to cover health care expenses in retirement. If either instead
wants a 90 percent chance of having enough savings, $124,000 is needed for a man and
$140,000 is needed for a woman. This analysis does not factor in the savings needed to cover
long-term care expenses. Savings targets increased between 6 percent and 21 percent between
2014 and 2015. For a married couple both with drug expenses at the 90th percentile throughout
retirement who want a 90 percent chance of having enough money saved for health care
89
expenses in retirement by age 65, targeted savings increased from $326,000 in 2014 to $392,000
in 2015.” 64
According to the Kaiser Family Foundation, “Twenty-three percent of large firms that offer
health benefits in 2015 also offer retiree health benefits, similar to the percentage in 2014 (25%).
Among large firms that offer retiree health benefits, 92% offer health benefits to early retirees
(workers retiring before age 65), 73% offer health benefits to Medicare-age retirees, and 2%
offer a plan that covers only prescription drugs. Employers offering retiree benefits report
interest in new ways of delivering them. Among large firms offering retiree benefits, seven
percent offer them through a private exchange and 26% are considering changing the way they
offer retiree coverage because of the new health insurance exchanges established by the
ACA….There has been a downward trend in the percentage of firms offering retirees coverage,
from 34% in 2006 and 66% in 1988 (Exhibit 11.1)…. Large firms with at least some union
workers are more likely to offer retiree health benefits than large firms without any union
workers (37% vs. 18%) (Exhibit 11.3).” 65
Beginning in 2020, employer health plans will be assessed a non-deductible 40% excise tax on
the value of the total cost of their plans, on a per-employee basis, above indexed dollar
thresholds. [Note that, since this paper was written, the effective date was postponed from 2018
to 2020 by the Consolidated Appropriations Act, enacted on December 18, 2015] The total cost
includes any FSA contributions made by the employee on a salary reduction basis, premium
costs, and employer HRA contributions. Some employers have already begun making changes to
their health benefits. “Among firms who have conducted an analysis to determine their liability
under the high-cost plan tax, 12% believe their plan with the largest enrollment will exceed the
thresholds in 2018 (Exhibit 14.14). Some employers have already taken action to mitigate the
anticipated impacts of the high-plan excise tax; 13% of large firms (200 or more employers) and
7% of small firms have made changes to their plans’ coverage or cost sharing to avoid exceeding
the limits. Eight percent of both large and small firms have switched to a lower cost plan.
Looking at firms that took one of these two actions, 11% of small firms (3-199 workers) and
16% of large firms reported either changing their plan or switching carriers to reduce the cost of
their plan in anticipation of the assessment. Among large firms (200 or more workers) who
indicated changing their plan or switching carriers to reduce the cost of their plan, 64% have
increased cost sharing, 10% have reduced the scope of covered services, 34% have moved
benefit options to account-based plans such as an HRA or HSA, 18% have increased incentives
to use less costly providers, and 16% have considered offering health insurance through a private
exchange in anticipation of the excise tax (Exhibit 14.15).” 66
64
EBRI Notes, Oct. 2015, Amount of Savings Needed for Health Expenses for People Eligible for Medicare: Unlike
the Last Few Years, the News Is Not Good, www.ebri.org.
65
Kaiser Family Foundation, 2015 Employer Health Benefits Survey, section 11, www.kff.org.
66
Id. Section 14.
90
Amazingly, for a system that revolves around identifying employers, employees, and employee
benefit plans, the fundamental definitions are woefully inadequate, and have become more so
over time as workplace conditions have changed dramatically since ERISA was enacted in 1974.
Under ERISA, “The term ‘employer’ means any person acting directly as an employer, or
indirectly in the interest of an employer, in relation to an employee benefit plan, and includes a
group or association of employers acting for an employer is such capacity.” 67 The definition of
‘employee’ is equally unilluminating: “The term 'employee' means any individual employed by
an employer”. 68 As David Weil has written, “A positive path forward requires revisions of
existing workplace laws so that they adequately recognize the far more complex nature of the
modern workplace and the growing presence of multiple organizations with roles in employment
decisions.” 69
In its most recent ERISA decision directly addressing this issue, which itself is more than 20
years old, the Supreme Court pointed out that the ERISA definition of employee “is completely
circular and explains nothing.” 70 The Court decided unanimously to “adopt a common-law test
for determining who qualifies as an ‘employee’ under [ERISA].” The Court relied on its earlier
opinion in a case interpreting the term “employee” as used in the Copyright Act of 1976,
identifying “the hiring party’s right to control the manner and means by which the product is
accomplished” as the proper test, and listing factors that bear on whether the purported employer
exercised sufficient control to make the other party an employee. 71
Although the Court’s decision is supported by precedent,72 relying on a test that dates back to
18th century master and servant rules, intended primarily to determine when the master was
67
ERISA section 3(5).
68
ERISA section 3(6).
69
Weil, note 1 above, at 289. He has also pointed out that “Defining who is the employer and who is the employee
turns out to be a far less straightforward task than one might imagine. The definitions differ across federal, state, and
common law. Federal workplace statutes (the focus of this discussion) do not use a single definition, but rather
multiple ones, from fairly expansive definitions that acknowledge the range of relationships that may actually arise
in the workplace (as in the Fair Labor Standards Act [FLSA]) to narrow descriptions built around the archetypical
large employer (think General Motors) with thousands of employees (as in the National Labor Relations Act
[NLRA]…. For many decades following passage of the FLSA and other federal statutes, subtle differences in
definitions of employment were less consequential for much of the economy: ii was relatively clear who the
employer and the employee were, just as were the boundaries of the firm. The more the work place has fissured, the
more the subtleties raised by definitions of employment matter.” Weil, note 1 above, at 184-185.
70
Nationwide Mutual Ins. Co. v. Darden, 503 U.S. 318 (1992).
71
Community for Creative NonViolence v. Reid, 490 U.S. 730 (1989).
72
In Darden, the United States Court of Appeals for the Fourth Circuit observed that “Darden most probably would
not qualify as an employee” under traditional principles of agency law but found the traditional definition
inconsistent with the “declared policy and purpose” of ERISA. The Supreme Court said that “In taking its different
tack, the Court of Appeals cited NLRB v. Hearst Publications, Inc., 322 U.S. at 120-129, and United States v. Silk,
331 U.S. at 713, for the proposition that “the content of the term ‘employee’ in the context of a particular federal
statute is ‘to be construed “in the light of the mischief to be corrected and the end to be attained.”” Darden, 796 F.2d
at 706, quoting Silk, supra, at 713, in turn quoting Hearst, supra, at 124. But Hearst and Silk, which interpreted
“employee” for purposes of the National Labor Relations Act and Social Security Act, respectively, are feeble
precedents for unmooring the term from the common law. In each case, the Court read “employee,” which neither
statute helpfully defined, to imply something broader than the common-law definition; after each opinion, Congress
amended the statute so construed to demonstrate that the usual common-law principles were the keys to meaning.
See United Ins. Co., supra, at 256 (“Congressional reaction to [Hearst] was adverse and Congress passed an
amendment . . . the obvious purpose of [which] “as to have the . . . courts apply general agency principles in
91
responsible for acts of the servant, makes no sense in interpreting employment legislation in the
21st century. 73
Darden also involved an issue simpler than most that arise in this area: it was clear that the key
relationship was between Darden and Nationwide, so the only question was whether he was an
employee or an independent contractor. In today’s workplace, there are often several different
entities with some control over the worker. The question is which one or more of them should be
responsible for complying with labor and employment laws, and the answer is not necessarily the
entity that gives the worker a W 2 or 1099 tax form.
Other countries have recognized that not all service-provider/service-recipient relationships fit
neatly within the traditional employee/independent contractor dichotomy by establishing a third
category, a dependent contractor, who receives some of the protections afforded to employees. 74
The drafters of ERISA recognized that the minimum coverage and nondiscrimination rules for
qualified retirement plans could easily be circumvented by splitting employees among a number
of employers related by common ownership. ERISA and subsequent legislation broadened the
employee group that must be taken into account, by enacting the controlled group, affiliated
service group and leased employee rules, and giving the Treasury Department broad regulatory
authority to prevent the avoidance of employee benefit requirements through the use of separate
organizations, employee leasing or other arrangements. 75 It is time for these anti-avoidance
concepts to be broadened, to reflect the realities of the 21st century economy in which control can
be exercise without common ownership.
6 WORKER (MIS)CLASSIFICATION
distinguishing between employees and independent contractors under the Act”); Social Security Act of 1948, ch.
468, § 1(a), 62 Stat. 438 (1948) (amending statute to provide that term “employee’ “does not include . . . any
individual who, under the usual common-law rules applicable in determining the employer-employee relationship,
has the status of an independent contractor”) (emphasis added); see also United States v. W. M. Webb, Inc., 397
U.S. 179, 183-188, 25 L. Ed. 2d 207, 90 S. Ct. 850 (1970) (discussing congressional reaction to Silk)…. To be sure,
Congress did not, strictly speaking, “overrule”our interpretation of those statutes, since the Constitution invests the
Judiciary, not the Legislature, with the final power to construe the law. But a principle of statutory construction can
endure just so many legislative revisitations, and Reid’s presumption that Congress means an agency law definition
for “employee” unless it clearly indicates otherwise signaled our abandonment of Silk’s emphasis on construing that
term ‘”in the light of the mischief to be corrected and the end to be attained.”’ Silk, supra, at 713, quoting Hearst,
supra, at 124. The definition of “employee” in the FLSA evidently derives from the child labor statutes, see
Rutherford Food, supra, at 728, and, on its face, goes beyond its ERISA counterpart. While the FLSA, like ERISA,
defines an “employee” to include “any individual employed by an employer,” it defines the verb ‘employ”
expansively to mean “suffer or permit to work.” 52 Stat. 1060, § 3, codified at 29 U. S. C. §§ 203(e), (g). This latter
definition, whose striking breadth we have previously noted, Rutherford Food, supra, at 728, stretches the meaning
of “employee”to cover some parties who might not qualify as such under a strict application of traditional agency
law principles. ERISA lacks any such provision, however, and the textual asymmetry between the two statutes
precludes reliance on FLSA cases when construing ERISA’s concept of “employee.”
73
Second 220 of the Restatement of the Law, Second, Agency, cited by the Court in Darden, is part of Chapter 7,
Liability of Principal to Third Person; Torts.
74
See also NLRB Member Wilma B. Liebman’s dissent in St. Joseph News-Press and Teamsters Union Local 460,
National Labor Relations Board, 345 N.L.R.B. 474 (2005), where she argued that the newspaper’s substantial
economic advantage over carriers resulted in a relationship of economic dependence on the newspaper, and was
persuasive evidence that the carriers were employees, not independent contractors.
75
Code sections 414(b), (c), (m), (n), (o) and (t). See also the separate line of business rules under section 414(r).
92
Subject to special rules for statutorily defined “leased employees,” 76 an employer who allows
individuals other than employees or owners (e.g., partners in the employer) to participate in a
qualified retirement plan would jeopardize the plan’s qualification, as a plan is required to be for
the exclusive benefit of the employees or their beneficiaries. 77 This issue has two separate
aspects: misclassification of workers, and whether it would be feasible to allow participation by
other individuals within the present framework, which is based on the assumption that all
participants will either be employees or owners of the business.
Worker misclassification has been a serious issue for many years. Employers have an incentive
to classify workers as independent contractors, not only to avoid providing retirement and other
benefits, but also to avoid having to pay Social Security taxes, unemployment compensation
premiums and worker’s compensation premiums. 78 “It is common for employers to inaccurately
and illegally declare employees to be contractors. A 2000 study by the U.S. Department of
Labor, for instance, found that 10–30 percent of audited employers misclassified workers…. In
many states, there is no mechanism for workers to challenge their bosses’ designation except for
filing unemployment or workers’ compensation claims-meaning one must be fired or injured
before there is any legal avenue for contesting one’s status…. In some industries,
misclassification has become so commonplace that well-meaning employers are under pressure
to wrongly classify their employees in order to not be undercut by less ethical competitors…. At
the federal level, a 2009 report from the Government Accountability Office estimated that
misclassification costs the federal government nearly $3 billion per year.” 79
Francoise Carre notes that “Numerous state-level studies show that between 10 and 20 percent of
employers misclassify at least one worker as an independent contractor.” 80
This results in a large loss of income and employment tax revenue. The misclassified employees
typically do not pay the full self-employment taxes and are wrongly left uninsured or
underinsured, without benefits and without job security. 81
76 Under IRC § 414(n), a “leased employee” who performs services for any person (the “recipient”) pursuant to an
agreement between the recipient and any other person (the “leasing organization”) is treated for certain purposes,
including discrimination testing, as an employee of the recipient. A “leased employee” is defined as any person who
provides services to the recipient but who is not an employee of the recipient, if such services (1) have been
performed on a substantially fulltime basis for a period of at least one year, and (2) are performed “under primary
direction or control by the recipient.” There is a limited safe harbor exception for leased employees who are covered
by a sufficiently generous money purchase pension plan of the leasing organization, provided that leased employees
do not constitute more than 20 percent of the recipient’s nonhighly compensated work force. IRC § 414(n)(5).
77
Code section 401(a).
78
“Unfortunately, current tax, labor and employment law gives employers and employees incentives to create
contingent relationships not for the sake of flexibility or efficiency but in order to evade their legal obligations. For
example, an employer and a worker may see advantages wholly unrelated to efficiency or flexibility in treating the
worker as an independent contractor rather than an employee. The employer will not have to make contributions to
Social Security, unemployment insurance, workers' compensation, and health insurance, will save the administrative
expense of withholding, and will be relieved of responsibility to the worker under labor and employment laws. The
worker will lose the protection of those laws and benefits and the employer's contribution to Social Security, but
may accept the arrangement nonetheless because it gives him or her an opportunity for immediate and even
illegitimate financial gains through underpayment of taxes. Many low-wage workers have no practical choice in the
matter.” DOL, Contingent Workers, www.dol.gov/_sec/media/reports/dunlop/section5.htm.
79
Weil, note 1 above, at 212-215.
80
Françoise Carré, (In)dependent Contractor Misclassification, June 8, 2015
http://www.epi.org/publication/independent-contractor-misclassification/.
93
IRS enforcement has been hampered by section 530 of the Revenue Act of 1978, which allows a
service recipient to treat a worker as an independent contractor for employment tax purposes,
even though the worker may be an employee under the common law rules, if the service
recipient has a reasonable basis for so doing and certain other requirements are met. If a service
recipient meets these requirements, the IRS is prohibited from reclassifying the worker as an
employee. The classification may continue indefinitely, even if it is incorrect. This section also
prohibits the IRS from issuing generally applicable guidance addressing worker classification.
The administration’s 2016 budget proposal would allow the IRS to require prospective
reclassification of workers who are misclassified. 82 Treasury and the IRS also would be
permitted to issue generally applicable guidance on the proper classification of workers under
common law standards. Service recipients would be required to give notice to independent
contractors, when they first begin performing services for the service recipient, that explains how
they will be classified and the consequences. The IRS would be permitted to disclose to the
Department of Labor information about service recipients whose workers are reclassified.
Congress enacted the separate line of business (“SLOB”) rules in 1986 to provide relief for
organizations that, while connected by common ownership, were in fact separate. The
regulations add highly detailed and restrictive requirements that make the SLOB rules available
to only very few employers. IRS should issue new, more workable regulations
A major problem today is the opposite situation: organizations that are not connected by
common ownership, but are not truly separate (e.g., many franchisor-franchisee relationships). 83
Many of the industries in which fissured workplaces are common (e.g., as a result of franchising
or supply chain management) “account for a disproportionate share of low-wage workers. For
example, while food services and drinking places employed about 6.4% of the workforce, it
comprised about 12.4% of all low-wage workers in 2010; retail workers comprised 10.2% of the
workforce but 18.9% of low-wage workers; and the roughly 1.8 million workers in the hotel and
motel industry accounted for 1.2% of employment but twice that percentage of low-wage
workers.” 84
81
Id.
82
Green Book, pp. 223 et seq.
83
See Weil, note 1 above, passim.
84
Id. at 269-270.
94
Weil points out that the definition of “employee” under the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) is
broader than under other federal statutes, such as ERISA: “The FLSA defines an employee as
“any individual who is employed by an employer” and that “employer includes to suffer or
permit to work.” This obscure phrase offers the broadest definition of “employee” of any federal
statute. It goes beyond the definition offered by common law focus on the degree of actual
control of the employee. Instead, courts have noted that the phrase “to suffer or permit” implies
that even broad knowledge of work being done on an employer’s behalf is sufficient to establish
a relationship. Given the wide latitude implied by this definition, courts have applied an
economic realities test to evaluate the particular economic situation surrounding a worker and his
or her employer or employers. The broad definition of “employer” under the FLSA (and under
most state minimum wage laws) provides the potential for interpretations that capture the
complexities of the fissured workplace even though courts have historically tended to hew to
relatively narrow definitions of employment.” 85
As Weil argues, “Reform of existing workplace legislation and new policy initiatives could
broaden the responsibility of lead organizations in the realm of employment so that it is
consistent with the roles played in their other relationships with subordinate businesses. The
principle here is one of parallelism: if a company exerts minute control over aspects of quality,
production, and delivery of services, that control should extend more fully to the domain of
employment as well those aspects of business that are directly valuable to the company.” 86
A similar argument is made by Matthew Bodie: “The critical insight is that employment is
defined not by control, but by participation-participation in team production. Although the notion
of control has dominated the common law test, most of the other factors in that test reflect the
degree of participation in the enterprise. Within the common boundaries of the firm, employers
have an obligation to pay minimum wage and overtime; provide family and medical leave; avoid
discrimination; bargain with collective representatives; adhere to certain requirements as to
retirement and health care benefits; and provide insurance in case of unemployment….
Employers have the responsibility to provide these things because employees are participants in
the employer’s common enterprise…. Team production justifies obligations from the team to the
individual Members.” 87
85
Id., at 184.
86
Weil, note 1 above, at 205.
87
Matthew T. Bodie, Participation as a Theory of Employment, 89 Notre Dame L. Rev. 661 (2013).
95
often subjected to exploitation and are usually not entitled to traditional employer-provided
retirement and health benefits. The non-core category includes independent contractors, self-
employed workers and standard part-time workers who work fewer than 35 hours per week.
Non-core workers generally seek nonstandard work agreements as a matter of choice.
Jobenomics views the non-core workforce as a positive economic force that will grow
significantly via the emerging digital economy. On the other hand, Jobenomics views the core
contingency as a major challenge as more and more citizens work for substandard wages,
become frustrated, and seek alternative ways of income.” 88
Anthony Atkinson notes that “In the twentieth century, employment in OECD countries was
largely characterised by regular jobs, but the twenty-first century is witnessing a significant
return to what is now regarded as nonstandard employment. Part-time work is the most
common…. The McKinsey Global Institute 2012 paper Help Wanted: The Future of Work in
Advanced Economies found that "managing employees and contract workers across the Internet,
companies now have the ability to make labor more of a variable cost, rather than a fixed one, by
engaging workers on an as-needed basis. Across the OECD... nations, part-time and temporary
employment among prime-age workers has risen 1.5 to 2 times as fast as total employment since
1990.... In our own surveys of US employers, more than one third say they plan to increase use
of contingent labor and part-time workers in the years ahead…. It is therefore increasingly
misleading to talk in terms of people having, or not having, a job. Work is not simply a (0,1)
activity. The twenty-first century labour market is more complex, and this has implications for
how we think about employment as a route out of poverty and full employment as a means of
assisting us on the way to less inequality.” 89
More than five million Americans are working part-time for economic reasons. This is down
from a peak of over 9 million but is much greater than the 4 million in 2006. 90 “About 31% of
workers worked in contingent employment situations in 2005, if one characterizes contingent
workers as those not employed in standard, full-time settings…. The number of workers
classified as independent contractors grew from 8.3 million to 10.3 million, and also increased as
a percentage of total employment, from 6.7% to 7.4%.” 91
In a recent report, the General Accountability Office (GAO) pointed out that “The size of the
contingent workforce as a proportion of the total U.S. employed labor force can range widely,
depending on how it is defined.” 92
GAO found that “Contingent work can be unstable, or may afford fewer worker protections than
standard work, depending on a worker’s particular employment arrangement. As a result,
contingent work tends to lead to lower earnings, fewer benefits (such as retirement plans and
health insurance), and a greater reliance on public assistance. Accounting for other factors that
88
Chuck Vollmer, Jobenomics U.S. Unemployment Analysis, Q 3 2015, Nov. 10, 2015, www.jobenomics.com.
89
Anthony B. Atkinson, Inequality: What Can Be Done? Harvard, 2015, at 135-137.
90
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment Level- Part-Time for Economic Reasons, All Industries (2015); Bureau
of Labor Statistics, Table A-8, Employed Persons by Class of Worker and Part-Time Status, Economic News
Release, March 6, 2015.
91
Weil, note 1, at 272-273.
92
Contingent Workforce: Size, Characteristics, Earnings, and Benefits, GAO-15-168R: Published: Apr 20, 2015.
Publicly Released: May 20, 2015.
96
affect earnings, contingent workers earn less than standard workers on an hourly, weekly, and
annual basis…. GAO also found that contingent workers are about two-thirds less likely than
standard workers to have a work-provided retirement plan and less than half as likely to have
work-provided health insurance.” 93
In 2007, one of the proposals made by the Conversation on Coverage was the establishment of a
national clearinghouse structure to administer portable individual retirement accounts. 94 In the
same year, the ERISA Industry Committee (ERIC) issued a comprehensive reform proposal. 95
ERIC proposed a new structure that would provide benefits through independent Benefit
Administrators, who would compete based on quality, use of information technology, plan
design and cost. Benefit Administrators, in many respects, would assume the role of today’s plan
sponsors and, particularly with regard to health care, would be organized on a geographic
basis. 96 Frank Cummings, one of the drafters of ERISA, viewed the proposal favorably: “The
ERIC Proposal is a beacon of light for a system losing its bearings in a storm of plan cutbacks,
freezes and terminations. It represents the only new upside after years of downside inventions....
At long last ERIC has propounded at least an invitation to some new thinking.” 97
Susan Stabile argues that the failures of the employer-based retirement system cannot be
rectified by incremental changes and that “there are really only two possible models. The first is
to jettison the employer-based system entirely and provide a government pension [providing a
livable pension for all elderly Americans] for everyone. The second is to retain the employment-
based system but move to a mandatory system with more stringent regulation of defined
contribution plans than currently exists.” 98
Katherine Stone argues that the current system of benefits originated in the industrial era of the
20th century, when employers sought to secure a stable workforce, that this employer-centered
model of benefits has largely outlived its usefulness in the new “boundaryless” workplace of the
93
Id.
94
Covering the Uncovered: Final Report of the Conversation on Coverage, www.conversationoncoverage.org.
95
The New Benefit Platform for Life Security, available at www.eric.org. As it states on its web site, ERIC is
“dedicated exclusively to representing the employee benefits and compensation interests of America’s major
employers.”
96
Id.
97
BNA Pension & Benefits blog, http://bnablog.bna.com/penben/2007/07/several-weeks-a.html#comments.
98
Stabile, Is it Time to Admit the Failure of an Employer-based Pension System?, 11 Lewis & Clark L. Rev. 305,
325 (2007). A similar argument was made by Daniel Halperin in 1993: “If, as a matter of public policy, it is
important for people to be able to maintain their standard of living upon retirement, or at least maintain a minimum
standard beyond what is provided by Social Security, rather than trying to encourage employer plans or individual
savings, it would be more straightforward either to enhance Social Security benefits or to require employers to
contribute to private plans for their employees.” Halperin, “Special Tax Treatment," supra note 22, at 44.
97
21st century, and that it must be replaced with an alternative that is more portable and more
affordable for the vast majority of workers. 99
More recently, Eugene Steuerle, Benjamin Harris and Pamela Perun have argued that “In a DC
plan system where the majority of the risks and responsibilities for saving fall on workers, where
independent financial services companies provide investments, and where professional
administrators manage the plan, it is self-defeating to continue to insist that employers as plan
sponsors remain the ultimate guarantors of the plan and all its functions. There is increasing
recognition that the next bold move in the evolution of the 401(k) plan system could be to
transform employers into facilitators of their employees’ saving. This merely requires activating
an employer’s payroll system to transfer employee contributions to a saving plan run by an
external entity. Such a system has been in place for decades in the 403(b) plan universe where
employers typically make supplemental savings plans available to their employees. In such
plans, employers are not fiduciaries, and their primary responsibility is to transfer elective
contributions, limited in amount as in the 401(k) world, to the plan chosen by the employee.” 100
10 CONCLUSION
The employer-based system of providing retirement and health benefits is failing too many
Americans, including disproportionate numbers of the poorer and more vulnerable members of
society. The largely incremental changes made over the last 30 years have not solved the basic
problems of access, coverage and adequacy. Accordingly, I suggest that it is time for a more
radical approach. One approach would be to redefine the terms” employer” and “employee” to
capture the realities of the 21st century workplace. However, any redefinition would be
susceptible to the development of new workplace relationships that work around the
redefinitions. Accordingly, the more promising approach is to provide a system in which
entitlement to some level of retirement and health benefits is independent of employment or
employment history, with employers remaining free to offer supplementary benefits to attract
and retain talented employees.
99
Katherine V.W. Stone, A Fatal Mismatch: Employer-centric Benefits in a Boundaryless World, 11 Lewis & Clark
L. Rev. 452 (2007).
100
C. Eugene Steuerle, Benjamin H. Harris and Pamela J. Perun, Entitlement Reform and the Future of Pensions,
September 2014, PRC WP2014-08, Pension Research Council.
98
The Changing Structure of Work:
March 7, 2016
Paper prepared for the Future of Work Symposium. U.S. Department of Labor, December 9-11, 2015
DISCLAIMER:This report was prepared for the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL), Chief Evaluation Office. The views expressed are
those of the authors and should not be attributed to DOL or the National Institute for Occupational Safety and Health, nor does
mention of trade names, commercial products, or organizations imply endorsement of same by the U.S. Government.
99
The Changing Structure of Work: Implications for Workplace Health and Safety in the
US
Leslie I. Boden, Emily A. Spieler, Gregory R. Wagner
Abstract: The structure and organization of work are continually changing. Changes may be cyclical, reflect ing
economic and social conditions, including business cycles and labor market structures. Other changes, often
resulting from new technologies, may be unidirectional. Whether or not the changes are temporary or
permanent, employment arrangements affect worker exposures to workplace hazards and their ability to
address them. In this paper, we focus on the effects on occupational safety and health (OSH) of relationships
that have been described as fissured or market-mediated, including the staffing agency model, the franchised
relationship, same site contracting, supply chain relationships, and contracting by a firm with many individuals.
Worker safety may be affected by several factors, including economic pressures on contracted employers, the
separation of control of the work environment from the employment relationship, and the short tenure of
workers in some dangerous jobs. After summarizing the limited number of studies that attempt to measure the
impact of these non-standard employment relationships on worker safety and health, we briefly discuss other
changes in the labor market that affect OSH, and then turn to the policy and legal implications of these
mediated relationships. Finally, we highlight the need for better data, safety and health surveillance, and
research when employment relationships are fissured. The paper focuses on changes and strategies in the U.S.,
but provides some references to relevant international studies.
100
Introduction
The structure and organization of work are continually changing. Changes may be cyclical, reflecting
economic and social conditions, including both business cycles and changing labor markets. Other
changes, often resulting from new technologies, may be unidirectional. Whether or not the changes
are temporary or permanent, there is legitimate concern that some of these changes result in
increased pressure on workers and working conditions and decreased regulatory effectiveness. The
starting premise of this paper is that there should be no variance in the level of protection from
workplace risks for workers, no matter what the employment relationship between employer and
employee and no matter what the contracting relationships among firms/ Today͛ s complex world of
work poses some new challenges while also retaining many of the risks that are the consequences of
work organization and hazards that have existed for a long time. The challenges for effective
intervention are therefore both continuing and evolving. We believe that this has always been true,
and it requires policy experts and regulators to continually re -evaluate strategies based upon new
risks, changing work organization, evolving technologies, and shifts in industrial mix.
Firms adopt various contracting and employment strategies in an effort to increase profitability , to
focus on core expertise, to increase flexibility, to affect labor relations, and to create new boundaries
that limit their statutory responsibilities or financial liabilities. These arrangements include firm to firm
contracting for goods (through supply chains), contracting for workers (through staffing/ temp
agencies or subcontracting to gain access to special expertise), delivering a branded product or service
(through franchising), and delivering services through individual workers who may, or may not, be
sufficiently independent to be classified accurately as independent contractors. In the ͞ standard͟
employment relationships – often mythologized as ubiquitous in the past – the lead firm directly
employs the workers and controls the site of work. In contrast, alternative employment arrangements
may divide the core or lead firm from the site of work or from the direct employ ment of the workers.
These arrangements may create uncertainty about responsibility for maintaining safe workplaces; lead
to inadequate training, personal protective equipment, and communication with workers exposed to
hazards; increase the number of workers in short-term or new places of employment (a known risk
factor for injuries); increase the likelihood that reporting of injuries or illnesses will be incomplete or
inaccurate; and decrease the ability of workers to communicate with each other and with the firm with
the greatest ability to control the hazards.
At the same time, the attractiveness of these work arrangements is influenced by technological
changes that enable firms to engage in control and monitoring techniques that further encourage the
use of contracting arrangements to maximize firm profits. These new technologies also enable entirely
new forms of work in what has become known as the ͞ gig͟ or ͞ sharing͟ economy, exemplified by Uber
and Lyft ride services and internet-based job bidding web sites such as Task Rabbit and Mechanical
Turk that have blurred the separation of work space and private space.
These new technologies also can result in increased oversight and monitoring within workplaces for
both direct and contracted workers. Innovative computer algorithms and widespread use of smart
phones have had a profound impact on some kinds of work and workplaces. Computer-enabled ͞ just
in time͟ staffing of enterprises to accommodate temporally variable client demand have changed
101
scheduling, created uncertainty for workers, and increased work-related stress in some segments of
the workforce.
Other changes are occurring at the same time. New materials such as manufactured nanoparticles are
being introduced into workplaces. Demographic and organizational changes within the workforce have
changed the way in which workers themselves can respond to risk. Shifting labor force participation of
female and older workers, decreasing worker voice as unions have declined, and a rise in the number
of immigrants with a diversity of languages all affect safety and health preventi on strategies.
This paper focuses on the nature of these employment relationships in relation to occupational safety
and health risks and the adequacy of current regulatory mechanisms to respond to workplace risks.
Contracting relationships may exert considerable downward pressure on wages and benefits, but
relationships may have varying effects on occupational safety and health (OSH): while decreased
attention to safety characterizes some models, there are also emerging relationships that may offer
new opportunities for improved management of health and safety risks. New forms of production may
include widespread adoption of less hazardous materials or processes. Shrinking of some higher-risk
occupations, such as underground coal mining, means that over-all population risks may decline, while
large and growing industries, such as health care, pose different and significant risks to workers.
These are all critical changes in the evolving nature of work, and some of them are beyond the scope of
this paper. Here, we consider the following issues.
First, Part I focuses on evolving employment arrangements between and within firms and summarizes
existing research regarding the effects of these changes on health and safety of workers. In discussing
these arrangements, we provide an analysis of labor-market relationships, and we point to the specific
consequences for OSH, noting both the potential opportunities for risk reduction and the areas of likely
increased risk for workers. Our discussion of changes in the structure of work is necessarily brief. For
more in-depth analyses, we refer the reader to Weil [2014] and Appelbaum et al. [2016].
In Part II of the paper, we turn to established regulatory models to ask how they function currently and
can best respond to these challenges. Some of the changes require continued application or expansion
of existing regulatory strategies. Others should motivate the development of new strategies. Changing
work and work organizational issues pose regulatory challenges, but, within the context of OSH, some
of these changes may present opportunities to leverage l imited inspection and enforcement resources
more effectively.
Part III briefly summarizes the challenges to injury and illness surveillance, data collection, and
research created by the changes in work. It provides limited recommendations for future research that
would focus on the effects of these changes in OSH and the effectiveness of regulatory interventions.
We reiterate one beginning point here: The inquiry with regard to health and safety effects of changing
workforce relationships is not completely parallel to the inquiry regarding effects on wages and
benefits. Pressures to reduce costs are likely to lead both to reduced wages and less attention to
health and safety conditions. However, other aspects of the structure of work may affect health an d
safety conditions and wages differentially. For example, franchising arrangements create a central lead
102
firm that might require improved equipment to be adopted by all franchisees that thus gives better
protection against hazards than equivalent independent small businesses might provide. We present
one example of how this has worked in our discussion below.
Part I. The effects of the changing labor market on safety and health
In Part I. A. we describe various employment relationships and the issue s of increased risk that may be
associated with these arrangements. Following this discussion, in Part I.B. we discuss some of the
other changes in work that also impact safety and health.
We begin this section with a description of the ͞ standard͟ employment relationship, which we believe
remains the primary work organization model in the U.S. at this time. We describe the evidence of
growth of alternative work arrangements and the evolving employment relationships that influence
the nature of work and the OSH risks at work: contracting relationships among firms, including
subcontracting and use of staffing agencies to provide labor; franchise arrangements and supply
chains; and, to some extent, individual contracting arrangements. Note that we do not address the full
category of contingent employment, which includes a variety of part-time and temporary work within
firms, although there may be substantial commonalities with some of the arrangements described
here.
103
We use the following definitional structure in discussing these models.
LEAD FIRM: The lead firm has the power to decide about contracting and to control the
contracts with host and staffing firms/ It is the ͚ top of the pyramid͛ or, as described by
David Weil, the firm that sits ͞ in the catbird͛ s seat/͟ [Weil 2014] p. 60.
SITE OR HOST FIRM: The site firm controls the work environment directly. In situations
involving multi-employer sites, the employing firm may also be at the site, but may not
have control over the full site. Note: OSHA refers to the primary contractor that has
overall responsibility at the site at a multi-employer site as the ͞ controlling contractor.͟
EMPLOYING FIRM: The employing firm directly employs the workers. The employing firm
generally hires, pays wages and obtains mandated insurance coverage for its workers
(unemployment, workers͛ compensation)/ In situations involving staffing agencies that
supply workers to a site, this employer will share responsibility for a wide range of OSH
issues with the host and lead firms.
The lead, host and employing firm may be the same firm, or not, depending on the
nature of the relationships.
104
The standard employment model
In the standard employment model, the lead, host and employing firm are all the same. Production is
carried out within the boundaries of a single firm, as differentiated from what Abraham and Taylor
[1996] call ͞ market-mediated work arrangements͟ and Weil [2014] calls ͞ fissured employment/͟ (We
will use both terms.).
During a significant portion of the last century, firms sought vertical integration, that is, all activities
from producing raw materials through sales to final consumers within the boundaries of a single firm.
Of course, total vertical integration is virtually impossible. For example, it would have been impossible
for an automobile company to do everything from mining coal, iron, and other raw materials through
selling the cars to consumers; moreover, it would have had to own the companies that provided
electricity to light its buildings and power its machinery, provided fuel to heat its factories, and so on.
In fact, historically, there has always been subcontracting.
When observers and researchers talk about the single firm model, they generally describe large,
profitable firms, typically of national or international scope. They also describe firms that have a
particular labor model: long-term employment engagements, much of promotion coming from within
the firm, and wages and benefits that often are better than could be expected in a firm that hired from
the outside at market wages. These are the internal labor markets as described in the 1950s by Clark
Kerr [1954] and later in more detail by Piore and Doeringer [1971].This type of employment
arrangement was typified by the ͞ big three͟ U/S/ automobile manufacturers in the 1950s/
Many much smaller firms also are unified, in the sense that the same firm operates at a site with
workers who were direct employees of the firm. The regulatory statutes governing employment that
were passed in the 20th century were largely designed to address issues within these types of firms,
where the lead firm, the firm that controls the worksite, and the firm that employs the workers are all
the same.
In this standard model, employment, wage, and OSH issues arise within a single firm, and they are
therefore easiest to regulate: the same firm controls the site, manages the workers, bears the risks,
and makes the profit. This is similar to the description of Kalleberg, Reynolds, and Marsden [2003],
although we do not distinguish here between part-time and full-time workers or between workers who
are directly hired for a limited duration or are on call and those who are not. This unified employment
arrangement, particularly in larger firms, often makes it simpler for an employer to maintain a safe and
healthy work environment.
Several factors may increase the attractiveness of having work done by individuals or firms outside the
umbrella of the centralized firm.
First, if the firm experiences fluctuations in demand, it can respond by using workers who are not part
of the regular workforce during those periods, rather than choosing to keep a regular workforce that
will be fully employed only at peak demand, or scheduling substantial overtime work during periods of
105
high demand, or hiring workers directly during times of high demand and then laying them off as
demand slows.
Second, work done outside the firm may yield economies of scale or indivisibilities that would make
within-firm services more expensive than those that can be obtained in the marketplace. Examples
include specialized information technology services, complex accounting services, specialty
intermittent support services, or workers͛ compensation or health care claims administration.
Third, firms may simply choose to externalize work from the central firm in order to reduce
employment costs by reducing wages, benefits and other employment costs. In economic theory,
workers would be paid wages and benefits equal to their marginal product. In practice, there are many
reasons why this will not be the case. In some cases, the rents (that is, excess profits above the
minimum needed to keep the firm in operation) that some firms enjoy may end up shared with its
workers. This may happen because a union bargains for a share of the firm͛ s rents/ Or firms may want
to pay higher-than-market wages to workers who have gained firm-specific skills because this is more
cost-effective than hiring and training workers from the outside . There is also evidence that firms that
pay high wages do so throughout the skill spectrum. This evidence comes both from studies of the firm
contribution to wage heterogeneity [Barth, et al. 2014, Gruetter and Lalive 2009] and from studies of
changes in the wages of less-skilled workers when jobs are outsourced [Dube and Kaplan 2010]. On
the other hand, there is less reason for a firm to pay high wages to relatively unskilled workers,
particularly if they do not need firm-specific skills. Having lower-skilled work done by non-employees
allows the lead firm to capture some of the difference between the wages paid to less-skilled
employees within the firm and outside the firm.
Fourth, firms may seek to reduce regulatory and social insurance costs, some of which may also be
employment costs. If jobs are moved to firms that evade U.S. labor and environmental laws and
regulations or to countries with more permissive laws, then those firms͛ costs may be lower—thus
allowing the contracting firm to buy goods or services at a lower cost. Similarly, if jobs are moved to
small contractors that are not experience-rated for workers͛ compensation, then these contractors will
have injury costs that are unresponsive to injury rates. Lower workers͛ compensation costs may also
reflect misclassification of workers by staffing agencies to categories that reflect less overall risk, and
thus lower insurance rates.
Finally, staffing agencies may be used to employ potentially permanent hires. Going through a staffing
agency may make it easier to quickly replace workers who don͛ t meet the company͛ s needs/This may
be particularly true in unionized firms.
Weil [2014] also argues that institutional factors can lead firms to shed employment of low -skill or non-
essential workers. These include greater pressure to increase profits from capital markets, executive
compensation tied to firm profits, and management theories that encourage firms to focus on their
core competencies.
There is evidence that the fraction of employment that lies outside the umbrella of the consolidated
͚ standard͛ firm model has been growing for decades. This growth has become the focus of
106
considerable policy debate in recent years, fueled most recently by the publication of David Weil͛ s
research on fissured employment.
Evidence of this growth is strongest in the professional and business services sector, in which services
are provided by firms in this sector to other firms. In contrast, the administrative and support services
subsector of this sector, probably the most directly relevant to this paper, employed over eight million
workers in 2014, almost double its 1990 employment. This subsector includes both professional
services such as accounting, legal, and information technology, and less-skilled services including
janitorial and security services where OSH risks may be high. Firms in this sector provide general
staffing assistance (ranging from professional employer organizations that provide administrative
services to temporary help firms that employ unskilled workers) or specialized services such as payroll,
benefits administration, or workers͛ compensation administration.
Evidence of growth of non-standard employment arrangements also comes from studies of specific
occupations. For example, Dube and Kaplan [2010] examined outsourcing of janitors and guards from
1983-2000 using the Current Population Survey (CPS). They found a 31 percent increase in the
proportion of janitors with outsourced jobs and a 24 percent increase for guards .
Notably, growth in specific areas of outsourced employment has varied among specific types and over
time. Tables 1A and 1B compare the overall change in employment for the U.S. economy with
employment changes in specific industries within the administrative and support services sector for
1990-2000 and for 2000-2014. During the earlier period, overall employment grew by 21%, as
compared with only 5% in the later period, which includes the Great Recession. Employment in the
administrative and support services sector grew by 80% in 1990-2000 (at almost four times the overall
growth in employment) but only 6% in 2000-2014, or one percentage point more than the overall
employment growth rate. Employment services, the largest industry within administrative and support
services, showed an even greater fluctuation between the two periods, plummeting from growth of
154% in the earlier period to a decline of 9% in the later period (Figures 1a and 1b). Some of the other
industries in this sector showed growth that was slower than overall employment growth in the later
period, but some showed faster growth.
It is not surprising that the employment services industry saw a large downturn during the Great
Recession. A major function of this industry is to provide temporary employees for firms during times
of increasing demand because releasing temporary employees is easier and cheaper than laying off
longer-term employees. They are often hired for jobs involving relatively little firm-specific skills.
However, we do not know the extent that the change in employment in this sector is related to the
business cycle and to what extent this represents a change in the trend toward using temporary
employees. We suspect that the trend in growth of the employment services industry has slowed
considerably.
Weil [2014] makes a convincing qualitative argument that there is substantial and continuing growth in
franchising, offshoring, and domestic outsourcing of production. Still, there is limited quantitative
evidence of past growth in these activities, in large part because of data availability. We see no strong
reasons for assuming that there will be continued growth in these sectors, although we cannot rule
this out.
107
The downward pressure on wages and working conditions that may be created by the forms of many
of these models has been well-described previously. (See [Weil 2014] and [Handwerker and Spletzer
2015].) If the motivation to go outside the lead firm is to capture firm-specific rents and the firm
supplying the labor, services, or products is in a more competitive market than the lead firm, then we
may expect to see a reduction in wages for people performing those tasks. This is what has been
observed in some research studies [Berlinski 2008, Dube and Kaplan 2010, Kalleberg, et al. 2000].
Research has shown that franchised locations may violate wage and hour laws more often than
locations operated by the lead firm [Ji and Weil 2015]. The factors that produce lower wages and wage
and hour violations may also result in cutting corners on providing a safe and healthy workplace. In a
study of 13 U.S. industries, Filer and Golbe [2003] found that serious violations of OSHA standards
were inversely related to firms͛ operating margin/
However, it is also important to note that if a task is outsourced because an outside individual or
organization has superior, highly-valued human capital or enjoys economies of scale, then it would
seem much less likely that outsourcing would reduce pay levels or OSH conditions. There is evidence
that pay levels are high in some types of outsourced jobs [Houseman, et al. 2003, Kunda, et al. 2002].
In this section, we describe the basic, simple forms of market-mediated, or fissured, employment
arrangements, and summarize the research that focuses specifically on OSH effects within these
arrangements. In many cases, hybrid or multi-layered arrangements may occur. For example, a
franchisee may hire workers from a staffing agency and subcontract janitorial services. Still, we think
that a simple taxonomy is useful.
In the staffing (or ͞ temp͟ ) agency model, the lead employer and the host employer are the same. We
use ͞ staffing agency͟ to encompass all types of firms that provide workers to another employer – from
janitors to temporary construction workers to essentially permanent placements of both unskilled and
skilled workers. The staffing agency hires and pays the worker, but does not have direct control over
the worksite. In essence, the agency is supplying workers to the lead/host employer, but the lead/
host has control over the conditions at the worksite.
This creates a triangulated relationship, with the employment relationship running between the
staffing agency and the worker, while the lead/host firm and the staffing agency have a contractual
relationship between themselves. These inter-firm contracts specify a wide range of issues, including
issues of liability and insurance (such as workers͛ compensation). The services provided take place at
the lead firm͛ s site under the lead firm͛ s specifications. Specific services are provided by the
contracted staffing agency that may not have supervisory personnel at the work site. These services
may include, for example, security, janitorial and landscaping services, among others. Not included
here are multi-employer sites, discussed below, at which a variety of subcontractors provide services
under their own supervision, while operating under the primary umbrell a of a general (controlling)
contractor.
108
We have found only a handful of studies that directly address the impacts of new fissured employment
arrangements on occupational safety and health in the United States, and even fewer of staffing
agency workers. We focus on the U.S. because differences among countries, including in employment
laws as well as differences in the employed populations, make it difficult to know the cross -national
transferability of findings. There is a substantial international literature on this, for example the work
of Quinlan, Mayhew, and their colleagues [Gregson, et al. 2015, Mayhew and Quinlan 1997, Quinlan
1999, Quinlan 2015, Underhill and Quinlan 2011]. The international literature on precarious
employment as a social determinant of health has been reviewed recently [Benach, et al. 2014].
Older studies have looked at arrangements that involved these types of triangulated relationships.
About twenty years ago, Rebitzer [1995] studied the impact on occupational safety of subcontracting
of maintenance and turnaround at petrochemical facilities. He found that managers at the faci lities
were instructed to maintain an arms-length relationship to the contractor employees. This was
believed to be necessary in order to limit the facility owners͛ liability for contractor actions and for
workers͛ compensation benefits for work injuries/ In the course of this study, Rebitzer found a chemical
company memo indicating that managers should not instruct contract employees on how to work in
compliance with plant safety procedures (p. 44). A statistical analysis found that contract employees,
especially those who worked less than one year at the facility, had substantially higher injury rates than
did direct employees.
In a related paper [1994], Kochan, and his co-authors provided recommendations to OSHA that are still
relevant today. Three of these are: (1) holding plant managers accountable for the safety of all thos e
working at their sites, including employees of contractors, (2) requiring plant managers to collect site -
specific safety data for direct-hire and contract workers, and (3) establishing minimum training
standards appropriate for the different types of work employees perform in petrochemical plants.
Evidence from high risk industries such as petrochemical, construction and trucking indicate the
negative effects associated with contracting out work may result from a desire by companies to avoid
liability or regulatory oversight [Azari-Rad, et al. 2003, James, et al. 2007, Rebitzer 1995].
Muzaffar et al. [2013] compared data on contract workers and direct employees in all U.S. mines
between 1998 and 2007 to determine if there were notable differences between the two groups in
relation to fatal mining accidents. Their data indicated that the univariate odds of a reported fatal
incident as opposed to a reported non-fatal incident were 2.8 times higher for contract workers than
operators. They also utilized a multivariate model, which associated other factors with fatality. These
included being a contract worker, being more than 8 hours into a working day, and having less overall
experience in that specific mine. They found that contractors had higher reported fatality rates than
direct employees but lower reported non-fatal injury rates. It is not clear whether the non-fatal injury
rate finding is an artifact of differential reporting. Also, if limited mine experience is a mediator
between being a contract worker and experience at a specific mine, this study may have
underestimated the impact of contracting on injury rates.
A 2011 NIOSH study, led by Pappas and Mark [2011] suggested that contractors in underground coal
mines had substantially higher injury rates than direct mine employees, but that the disparity in rates
had almost disappeared by 2009. However, these comparisons did not control for differences in the
109
occupations of contractors and direct employees. Contractors are often employed to do specialized
tasks like trucking and ventilation work that may not otherwise be done by direct employees.
Several studies of staffing agency workers have found elevated injury risk. An early study at a plastic
products manufacturer found that staffing agency workers had well over twice the injury rate as
permanent workers [Morris 1999]. The authors stated that the two groups did similar work and
received the same job training. Injury rates were not adjusted for age, gender, tenure, or other
potential confounders.
Other studies have focused specifically on temporary workers. In a study of needlestick injuries of
hospital nurses, Aiken, Sloane, and Klochinski [1997] found that temporary nurses had an elevated
injury rate/ Using workers͛ compensation data from Minnesota, Park and utler [2001] found
substantially higher claim rates among temporary agency workers. Two studies using Washington State
workers͛ compensation claim data found qualitatively similar effects [Foley, et al. 2014, Smith, et al.
2010]. Smith et al. [2010] found that temporary workers had estimated claims rate ratios double those
of permanent workers in manufacturing and construction.
ProPublica reporters merged Florida 2011 workers͛ compensation data with occupational employment
data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) program
[Pierce, et al. 2013]. They focused on comparing injury rates for occupations in the employment
services industry group (5613) with those not in this industry group, controlling for age group, sex, and
a measure of whether a job was hazardous. Using logistic regression, they found an odds ratio of close
to four for injuries of temporary workers compared with other workers. We reran their analysis using
negative binomial regression to model their count data and obtained an incidence rate ratio of 3.53
(95% confidence limits 2.76 to 4.51). Using either method, it is reasonable to conclude that temporary
jobs are, on average, more hazardous than other jobs in occupations with similar overall injury rates.
Furthermore, in the event of injury or illness from work, there may be inadequate recordkeeping or
reporting by either the host or the employing firm, either because of true confusion as to who is
responsible for recording and reporting or by intent.
Benavides et al. [2006] conducted a study of Spanish temporary workers, including both staffing
agency workers and individual temporary workers. They found rates of fatal and non -fatal occupational
injuries were 2.5 to 3.0 times as high among temporary workers. However, when accounting for
gender, age, occupation, and company-specific length of employment, the rate ratios became
insignificant and close to 1.0. Length of employment appeared to be the most important contributor to
the excess risk of temporary workers. Given the differences, as noted above, among countries͛
underlying systems, it is difficult to know whether this study is applicable to the U.S. environment.
One reason to go outside the firm is to respond to fluctuations in demand, temporarily hiring workers
in times of increasing cyclical demand and laying them off during slack periods. Temporary workers
hired during times of high demand may have similar pay rates during their employment, but their
relatively short tenure at a specific workplace may increase their OSH risks, because of unfamiliarity
with the hazards at a worksite, less OSH training relevant for the specific job supplied by either the
staffing company or the host company, and more distant relationships with longer-term workers who
could help navigate worksite hazards.
110
Temporary and short-term workers, frequently hired through employment agencies, may be
particularly vulnerable to workplace safety risks. As noted in a recent OSHA White Paper [OSHA 2015]:
New workers often lack adequate safety training and are likely to be unfamiliar with the specific
hazards at their new workplace. As a result, new workers are several times more likely to be
injured in the first months on the job than workers employed for longer periods. Con sistent
with these findings, OSHA has investigated numerous incidents in recent months in which
temporary workers were killed on their first days on a job. Temporary workers are also likely to
be newly assigned to unfamiliar workplaces multiple times in any given year and may carry this
increased risk as long as they are in the temporary workforce. For employers, there is less
financial incentive to invest training resources on temporary employees because shorter tenure
will yield a lower return on investment than similar investments for permanent employees.
OSHA has encountered many situations, including some in which temporary workers have been
killed, in which employers have chosen to not provide required safety training to temporary
workers. And the temporary workers themselves, recognizing the precarious nature of their
employment, are less likely to complain to their employers, or to OSHA, about the existence of
even serious hazards [Foley, et al. 2014, Grabell 2013].
Protections from hazards may be diminished and their vulnerability to a broad range of adverse effects
may be exacerbated by the nature of their employment relationship. Workers in these relationships,
particularly those who are short-term or seasonal workers, may be more subject to job stress and its
adverse health consequences and less likely to benefit from the workplace factors that may mitigate
these effects [Cummings and Kreiss 2008]. Job stress can result in both physical and psychological
disruption. Prolonged job strain is thought to lead to increased cardiovascular disease,
musculoskeletal disorders, sleep disruption, and psychological disorders. According to a recent analysis
of General Social Survey data, exposure to harmful workplace practices such as job insecurity, low job
control, high job demands, and low social support at work may explain a significant proportion of
observed inequality in life spans in different demographic groups in the US [Goh, et al. 2015]. The
growth in non-standard employment relationships that result in increased exposure of less educated
and ethnic minorities to harmful workplace practices may thus ultimately result in diminished life
expectancy. These findings are consistent with a longitudinal mortality study of temporary workers in
Finland that found workers moving from temporary employment to permanent employment had lower
death rates than those who remained as temporary workers [Kivimäki, et al. 2003].
111
Finally, these workers may have less access to health insurance and workers͛ compensation benefits
[Asfaw 2014, Mehta and Theodore 2006], causing greater financial strain and interfering with recovery
from injury or illness.
In the franchised relationship, the lead – the power firm in the relationship – is the franchisor. The
franchisee is the direct and the host employer, with day-to-day direct control of the worksite, although
this control is tempered by the terms of the franchise agreement which will often set out specific
requirements for the worksite. This includes many fast-food chains, but also janitorial firms, security
firms, and others. In contrast to the staffing agency model, this looks diagrammatically linear, rather
than triangulated: the lead firm contracts with the site firm which contracts with the employees; but
the lead employer and the site employer are not both at the worksite.
The franchisee is governed by explicit contractual terms and delivers a product or services to an
outside buyer based upon the requirements of the franchisor. The franchisee often looks like a small
business, but the franchisor exercises significant control. The regulator can easily reach the franchisee,
as it is the site employer, but would have more leverage if it can reach the franchisor and either
persuade the franchisor to require OSH measures in the franchise contracts or persuade the franchisor
to change other contractual terms that may impact OSH. For regulatory purposes, the nature of the
franchise agreement and the extent to which the franchisor and the franchisee are sharing in the local
enterprise will matter.
Franchising may offer significant opportunities for regulatory and public health agencies to improve
worker safety by focusing on the lead employer (the franchisor) and promoting changes that result in
improvement in safety in all franchised establishments. This may mean that, in some cases, a business
that would have been a ͞ small business͟ – with all the economic, policy and regulatory challenges this
entails – may in fact be sufficiently connected to a lead employer to provide opportunities for effective
OSH interventions.
Although we found no published quantitative studies of the impact of franchising on worker health and
safety, a recent example successfully employing this strategy is instructive. The Occupational Health
Surveillance Program of the Massachusetts Department of Public Health, through its ongoing
surveillance of workplace burns, identified poorly designed coffee -makers as the source of a number of
serious burns in franchised coffee shops. The burns resulted in the need for eme rgency medical care
and, in some cases, permanent impairment. The franchisor specified the kind of equipment the
franchisees needed to use and sold this equipment to the worksites. The franchisor agreed to design
an equipment retrofit and then contractually to require franchisees to adopt the retrofit. When
ongoing surveillance indicated a continuation of the burn problem, the franchisor ultimately agreed to
require the use of newly designed coffee makers that appear to have greatly diminished the burn risk
at multiple sites.
This model involves multiple employers operating at a single site. Subcontractors direct the work of
their own employees, but the ultimate responsibility for the worksite (and work product) is shared with
112
the controlling host employer. This model is most common in construction, where the lead employer
is sometimes termed the ͞ controlling͟ contractor/ In construction, subcontracting is common, and
subcontract workers are faced not only with the hazards of their own jobs but hazards emanating from
other activities at the site/! n example of this is in a study of electrical subcontractors͛ exposure to
hazardous noise levels emanating from other contractors at the worksite, even though their own
activities are relatively quiet [Seixas, et al. 2001]. Notably, while there is an extensive literature
regarding construction hazards generally, there is a dearth of studies that specifically focus on the
effects of subcontracting on OSH outcomes in multi-employer sites.
In this model, a central firm develops individual contracts with individual workers. This is an arena of
considerable current dispute regarding the classification of these workers as independent contractors.
Within the OSH field, the problem is further exacerbated by the fact that these workers work in
disseminated sites, often not under the control of the lead firm, but not necessarily under the control
of the worker. In the Uber model, for example, the place of work – the vehicle itself – is arguably
within the sole control of the worker, with specifications set by the firm. The roads are, of course, not
within the control of any of the firm, though this does not differ from the on-the-road hazards of other
workers. In the home health aide model, on the other hand, the place of work is under the control of
the customer/client, and the aide may confront considerable risks from both the physical workplace
and the difficulty in caring for patients who may pose both physical and emotional risks for the
caregiver. In all of these models, OSH interventions – beyond requirements for training and
communication – would be difficult.
We did not identify any published evidence about the OSH impact of this form of market-mediated
employment.
When one firm contracts with another to complete portions of the work, a supply chain is formed.
While often discussed within the context of globalization, this also occurs within the U.S. In this
situation, the lead employer contracts with another employer for the delivery of particular goods that
meet specifications. It is up to the contracted employer to figure out how to do this, including making
decisions regarding further contracting, either for workers or with another firm that will provide part
or all of the product. The lead firm may have potential contractual authority over a range of
production issues that could govern conditions at the site of the direct employer, but this authority is
exercised infrequently.
Supply chain competition domestically or from abroad can increase economic pressures on domestic
firms competing internationally. In principle, subcontracted (outsourced or offshored) work can be
done by profitable well-established firms or by marginal firms that are under substantial economic
pressure. There is some evidence that OSH risks are greater among marginal subcontractors.
McManus and Schaur [McManus and Schaur 2014] estimated that increased Chinese import
competition in the period 2001-2007 led to substantially higher injury rates in affected U.S. industries
and that small plants were particularly affected. Supply-chain policies and practices have significant
113
impact on safety conditions worldwide as exemplified by the Rana Plaza di saster [Manik and Najar
2015].
B. Underlying changes in the nature of work and the health and safety consequences
Underlying changes in the nature of work, including technological changes, and changes in the labor
market both independently change OSH risks and also interact with changing contractual
arrangements. Detailed discussion of these other trends is not the primary focus of this paper, but it is
important to note that these other changes may, in fact, be as significant in the evolution of OSH
challenges as those discussed in the prior section.
First, new technologies are disrupting existing patterns of work and are likely to continue to do so in
the future. For example, improved accuracy of analytic models of consumer demand has enabled
employers to fine-tune work schedules to meet production needs [Greenhouse 2015]. Last-minute
schedules make working hours less predictable for the worker and have negative impact on necessary
non-work arrangements, including childcare and other family responsibilities. Wireless tracking
technologies combined with delivery route adjustment based on real-time traffic conditions, such as
those implemented by UPS, improve the efficiency of parcel delivery and reduce fuel costs but also
change the balance of worker control of job pace versus demand/Warehouse ͞ fulfillment centers͟ are
adopting voice recognition ͞ picking͟ technologies with computer generated voices pacing and directing
workers that may (at least initially) improve worker efficiency and reduce error, but also result in closer
monitoring of worker performance, reductions in worker control over job pace, speed-up and
attendant mental and physical risks. An example of this is Dematic Pick-to-Voice, described on their
website [Dematic]. It is these technological changes that enable the ͞ gig͟ economies such as Uber and
Taskmaster, but they also dramatically affect work within more standard employment relationships. In
fact, these new unforgiving technologies allow a return to an extreme form of Taylorism. They have
the potential to increase psychosocial stressors and increase work-family conflicts, particularly for
workers with dependent children.
Second, sectoral shifts mean that important job growth is in isolated environments often subject to
contracting arrangements. The growing need for in-home health care is a critical example where OSH
hazards are high and work is dispersed. Increased dispersion of work is further enabled by
technological interventions. On the other hand, employment in some dangerous industries, such as
underground coal mining, is declining.
Third, workers have decreasing ability to voice concerns about health and safety, as well as other
issues. Union membership has been declining in the U.S. for many years (Figure 2), and unions have
played a substantial role not only in protecting their own members but supporting laws and institutions
that attempt to protect all workers. Protections for raising concerns exist only on paper for many. We
discuss this more fully in the next section.
Fourth, the workforce itself is changing in ways that create new OSH challenges. There is, for example,
a higher labor force participation of older workers and of women; the number of immigrants in the
workforce is high, with challenges of both language and, for those who are not documented, increased
vulnerability to retaliation.
114
Fifth, there are new exposures – such as nanoparticles – that pose risks that are still being assessed.
These underlying, and in some cases non-cyclical, changes may be at least as important as changes in
labor market structures in affecting OSH and therefore in developing a strategic approach to reducing
OSH risks.
The overall goal is clear: to protect all workers, to the extent feasible, from illness, injury or death from
hazards at work. While regulation of health and safety in single firms is challenging, the regulation of
fissured environments is undoubtedly more complex. Nevertheless, all workers need to be fully aware
of the hazards they face; effective communication and education is just as critical for employees hired
through staffing agencies, as is the need for appropriate personal protective equipment, training, and
careful attention to exposure histories irrespective of length of employment with an individual host
firm. All workers must be able to raise concerns about safety without fear of retaliation from a direct
or an indirect employer/ Regulatory interventions should, to the extent possible, cross employers͛
contracting boundaries in order to reach the entity that has the most potential to control hazards for
the largest number of workers – generally the lead firm. Assistance should be provided to employers,
particularly small and medium-sized employers, to educate them in how to meet their health and
safety obligations. Similarly, irrespective of contracting relationships, it is critical to ensure accurate
reporting and effective surveillance. And there should be alignment of liability to hold responsible
parties accountable for exposures that lead to illness or injury.
Health and safety regulatory policy is only partly a matter of enforcement of the OSH ! ct͛ s standards
and general duty clause. Instead, we must think about all of the available regulatory levers as well as
the tools available to workers who seek to improve their health and well -being.
The problem of preventing injury and disease from work differs in some fundamental ways from the
problem of wage violations. In wage collection, the goals are to find an entity that will pay wages that
are due and to counter misclassifications that remove workers from the protections of the wage and
hour laws and social safety net. To accomplish this in fissured workplaces, it may be necessary to
identify the lead firm that may be setting wage requirements or establishing policies that misclassify
workers. In contrast, responsibilities for health and safety are tied to place – the place where workers
work and the policies that govern the work environment.
There are several intersecting areas of policy that must be addressed, and they intersect in various
ways with the types of employment arrangements that we have described in the prior section. We
115
address three of the critical areas below. A fourth – potential legal and policy approaches in the states
– is an important part of the puzzle, but is generally not addressed in this paper.
The ability of workers to raise concerns about health and safety risks is cri tical to successful OSH policy.
It goes without saying that the regulatory reach of OSHA (and state plans) is limited, given the
inflexibility of standards, the difficulty of mounting general duty cases, and the inadequacy of
administrative resources. As noted above, union membership has declined overall, so that only about
7% of the private sector workforce is now covered by collective bargaining agreements, most of which
guarantee job security to workers through ͚ just cause͛ and progressive discipline p rovisions. With this
decline, the strength of health and safety efforts has also diminished within the union movement. In
addition, although a few state statutes require joint health and safety committees, these committees
function more effectively in unionized than in non-union workplaces [Weil 1999]. Moreover, these
state-created committees exist in a gray area of legality as a result of the preemption of state law by
the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA) and the reach of §8(a)(2) of that Act, 29 U.S.C. §158(a)(2)
which prohibits employer domination of workplace organizations that function as labor organizations
within the meaning of Section 2(5), 29 U.S.C. §152(5). See Electromation, Inc., 309 N.L.R.B. No. 163
(Dec. 16, 1992). Joint labor-management safety committees established outside of union-organized
workplaces are therefore viewed as suspect by the NLRB, even when established pursuan t to a state
law that mandates that the committees be created. See NLRB Office of the General Counsel Advice
Memo, Goody͛ s Family lothing, Inc/, ase No/ 10-CA-26718 (Sept. 21, 1993). Non-union private
sector workers are almost universally ͞ at-will,͟ with no job protection other than that offered by
specific employment laws that provide very limited rights that are difficult and often expensive to
enforce. Thus, there is no easily accessible route for most workers to raise OSH concerns, and workers
must take significant risks to come forward.
The existing protective laws do not make up for fear of retaliation and lack of on-the-ground
protections. There are two primary sets of relevant, though limited, laws. The whistleblower laws,
enforced by OSHA, vary in their level of protection. In particular, the protection offered to workers in
general industry for raising health and safety issues (or related activities, such as reporting injuries)
under Section 11(c) of OSHA is notoriously weak [Spieler 2014]. Nevertheless, it is important that
Section 11(c) says, ͞ No person shall discharge or in any manner discriminate against any employee0 ͟
On its face, this language does not require a claim be made against the direct employer. To our
knowledge the interpretation of these laws has not yet been used to include complaints against host or
lead employers. If the non-direct employer is complicit in the discriminatory or retaliatory acts,
however, there is no reason why this could not be done. In fact, a similar argument was recently
sustained in a case involving a temporary worker under Title VII, where the statutory language is less
broad: In the case of Faush v. Tuesday Morning, Inc., 808 F.3d 208 (3d Cir. 2015), the site employer was
held responsible for discriminatory conduct involving a worker employed through a staffing agency,
where the site employer itself engaged in discriminatory conduct including job assignments.
The second arm of protection, under the NLRA, extends protection to workers who collectively raise
concerns about working conditions, irrespective of their union status. The National Labor Relations
Board [NLRB] has moved ahead to reach both franchisors – in a case involving McDonald͛ s US! – and
116
host employers that use workers through staffing agencies. The question is whether the direct
employer and the host or lead employer are ͞ joint employers͟ under the NLR! / In the case involving
McDonald͛ s, the NLRB General Counsel issued complaints against both the franchisees and the
franchisor, alleging that actions were taken against the workers in the franchises for engaging in
protected activities and that the franchisor, McDonald͛ s, was sufficiently involved to constitute a joint
employer under the statute/ ! ccording to the General ounsel, ͞ Our investigation found that
McDonald͛ s, US! , LL, through its franchise relationship and its use of tools, resources and technology,
engages in sufficient control over its franchisees͛ operations, beyond protection of the brand, to make
it a putative joint employer with its franchisees, sharing liability for violations of our ! ct/͟
In Browning-Ferris Indus. of California, Inc., 362 NLRB No. 186 (Aug. 27, 2015), addressing the issue of
staffing agencies, the Board broadened the definition of joint employers – returning to an earlier
accepted definition – and determined that a host/lead employer was a joint employer responsible for
collective bargaining with the employees of a staffing agency as long as the host employer was able to
exert at least indirect control over wages, hours and other terms of employment:
In this case, for instance, BFI communicated precise directives regarding employee work
performance through Leadpoint͛ s supervisors/ We see no reason why this obvious control of
employees by BFI should be discounted merely because it was exercised via the supplier rather
than directly.
The Board may find that two or more entities are joint employers of a single work force if they
are both employers within the meaning of the common law, and if they share or codetermine
those matters governing the essential terms and conditions of employment.
These cases are notable when considering health and safety issues for three reasons. First, they
indicate that workers who collectively raise health and safety concerns may have recourse, under the
NLRA, against lead and host employers – taking both negotiations and protection for concerted activity
͚ up the food chain͛ to the potentially most influential entity. Second, they will allow workers employed
by staffing agencies and franchises to organize unions that reach across the firms͛ contracting lines – a
unionizing effort will involve both the direct and the host, both the franchisee and the franchisor.
Third, these legal analyses have relevance to interpretations of the OSH Act, discussed in the next
section.
Despite these potential areas of protection for workers in non-standard employment relationships, the
laws and the level of job security are weak for all at-will workers. The number of complaints brought
under these laws – and related laws where retaliatory or discriminatory conduct involving health and
safety or work injuries is alleged – is overall quite small. This may mean that retaliation is infrequent,
and that workers bring forward their concerns without facing retaliation. Alternatively, based on
persuasive data regarding under-reporting of both hazards and injuries [Azaroff, et al. 2002, Spieler
and Wagner 2014], it is likely that the problem is, in fact, that retaliation is often not reported, and that
non-union workers are particularly reluctant to voice concerns about safety – or even to report
injuries. These rights are further attenuated for workers who work alone as home health aides or in
117
other similar positions, as they face additional barriers to raising a collective voice. Individuals
employed through staffing agencies – particularly if they are made more vulnerable by their
immigration status – also face special barriers, particularly if they are assigned to worksites for brief
periods of time, or they are immigrants without adequate documentation. This means that the
protection of worker voice, a critical foundation for improved health and safety, is extremely weak.
Aggressive enforcement of the available laws is critical, but may not be adequate to address the level
of vulnerability faced by most workers.
The goal for an OSH strategy should be to focus where interventions will have the broadest and most
lasting impact. This is particularly true in situations involving complex relationships among employers
and resulting confusion for workers. OSHA practice has historically recognized this need, and this
recognition predates the current discussion regarding non-standard employment arrangements.
Recent developments in enforcement suggest that OSHA is pursuing a more strategic and aggressive
approach.
First, OSHA has engaged in various strategies for targeting hazards and hazardous industries for some
time. Now, with the OSHA Information System (OIS), OSHA can better evaluate its own enforcement
targeting, and continually improve its targeting efforts. As data sources improve, so will the possibility
for relying on this feedback loop to improve targeting efforts that can affect behaviors across an
industry. The recent revision of the emphasis program on amputations and the development of
regional emphasis programs on the poultry industry are examples of newly designed targeting efforts.
OSH! has also invited interested parties to advocate for new targeting/ hanges in OSH! ͛ s
programmed inspection policies and practices and development of emphasis programs in the industry
sectors with both target populations of particularly vulnerable workers and significant regulated
hazards will allow OSHA to be a more efficient and effective enforcement agency in the areas of
growing concern that are exacerbated by changes in work structure.
Second, OSHA has engaged more effectively in the use of corporate-wide enforcement and settlement
agreements. See https://www.osha.gov/pls/oshaweb/owasrch.search_form?p_doc_type=CWSA for a
list of the settlement agreements currently in place. The authority to seek corporate-wide
enforcement – without a voluntary agreement – was preliminarily upheld by the Occupational Safety
and Health Review Commission (OSHRC) in a recent case in which OSHA sought the entry of a
corporate-wide abatement order involving non-compliance with safety standards for powered
industrial trucks in the employer͛ s 170 shipping terminals and service centers distributed across the
U.S. Secretary of Labor v. Central Labor Transport, LLC, OSHRC Docket Nos. 14-1452, 14-1612, 14-1934
(2015). The expansion of the use of similar agreements and enforcement to cover contracting
arrangements among employing entities – including franchise agreements – should be explored
further. The example given above of effective intervention in franchised coffee shops highlights the
possibilities for effective health and safety interventions when reaching up through contracting
relationships.
Third, a recent Memorandum of Understanding between OSHA and the Department of Justice (DOJ),
announced December 17, 2015, establishes the Worker Endangerment Initiative within DOJ and
118
expands the possibilities for criminal enforcement, including in areas where contracting among firms
exacerbates workplace health and safety challenges. The previous prosecution in United States v. Xcel,
Criminal Case No. 09-cr-00389-WYD (D. Col. 2010), despite the fact that it ended with an acquittal, is
an example of expanding the prosecutorial net beyond the direct employer-employee relationship.
The prosecution of Don Blankenship in a case arising out of the Upper Big Branch mine disaster also
suggests that federal prosecutions regarding workplace health and safety can be pursued successfully.
In what other ways can OSHA use its direct regulatory authority to address the problems created by
fissured contracting relationships among employers?
Although the OSH Act clearly envisioned what we have called standard employment relationsh ips, in
fact OSHA has broader authority to reach non-direct-employers than exists for other federal agencies
under the NLRA, FLSA and other laws. Although the specific language and degree of proof required
under the other statutes may vary somewhat, they all require proof of a direct employment
relationship in order to assert rights on behalf of the workers/ OSH! ͛ s hortatory language is much
broader: Section 2 of the OSH ! ct includes ongressional findings that urge OSH! to assure ͞ so far as
possible every working man and woman in the National safe and healthful working conditions͟ - Section
4 says, ͞ This ! ct shall apply with respect to employment performed in a workplace/͟ Here, the focus
seems to be more on place and control of the environment, and less on the exact nature of the
employment relationship. In fact, OSHA can sometimes impose regulatory duties based on an
employer͛ s relationship to the hazards at work without also proving that the cited employer is the
direct employer of the workers who are at risk.
This is particularly true in the enforcement of specific standards. Section 5(a)(2) of the Act requires
͞ each employer͟ to ͞ comply with occupational safety and health standards/͟ Thus, enforcement of the
standards does not require proof of a direct employment relationship, though the cited entity must be
an ͞ employer/͟ 1 This statutory framework means that OSHA need not focus on the existence of a direct
employment relationship when enforcing standards, in contrast to legal interventions under other
federal employment and labor statutes.
Note that this not true with regard to enforcement of the ͞ general duty͟ clause/ The language of
Section 5(a)(1) suggests that proof of a direct employment relationship is necessary for enforcement of
the general duty clause. ͞ Each employer shall furnish to each of his employees employment and a
place of employment which are free from recognized hazards that are causing or are likely to cause
death or serious physical harm to his employees/͟ (Emphasis added)
Relying on the statutory language relating to enforcement of standards, the Multi -Employer Citation
Policy, first developed in the 1970s and last revised in 1999, recognizes that joint responsibility among
multiple employers is critical where coordination affects workplace hazards; the policy notes that
͞ more than one employer may be citable for a hazardous condition that violates an OSH! standard/͟
The test under this policy is whether the cited employer is a ͞ creating, exposing, correcting or
1
The definition of ͞ employer͟ is not particularly helpful. OSH! ct Section (3) (5)says, ͞ The term "employer" means a person
engaged in a business affecting commerce who has employees0͟
119
controlling employer͟ and whether the employer͛ s actions were sufficient to meet its obligations
[OSHA 1999]/ The citation policy explicitly applies ͞ in all industry sectors,͟ and most appeals courts
have endorsed this approach. Under this directive, the controlling employer is ͞ [a]n employer who has
general supervisory authority over the worksite, including the power to correct safety and health
violations itself or require others to correct them. Control can be established by the con tract, or in the
absence of explicit contractual provisions, by the exercise of control in practice/͟
Rabinowitz [2015] persuasively argues that this policy may be applied to other non-standard
employment arrangements where the non-direct employer has significant control over the work
environment, though this argument has not yet been tested. As noted above, this argument only has
relevance when enforcing specific standards, because the general duty clause requires a direct
employment relationship. For example, Rabinowitz suggests that franchisors often have sufficient
control – through contracting/ franchise agreements or inspection policies or specific worksite
requirements – to be cited under this policy. Similarly, supply chain organizational structures, where
the lead employer specifies conditions or work organization, may arguably also be vulnerable to this
approach. Rabinowitz appropriately concedes, however, that the hazard must be one that the
franchisor or lead employer has the ability to control: any franchise agreement requirements for use of
protective equipment or hazardous site equipment or hazardous workplace practices would qualify;
site-specific hazards that could not be anticipated, such as exits blocked by boxes, would not.
The Washington State Supreme Court imposed liability, for example, on the lead jobsite employer,
SeaTac, after a worker, who was employed by a contractor that provided ground services for the
airlines, was injured. The court held that the lead employer retained control over the manner in which
the contractors completed their work, and was therefore potentially liable in tort.2 The court relied in
part on Washington͛ s multi-employer site doctrine, noting that OSH liability might hold ͞ irrespective of
any employer-employee relationship͟ as long as the jobsite owners ͞ retain control over the manner in
which contractors complete their work/͟ See Afoa v. Port of Seattle, 296 P.3d 800 (WA en banc).
Rabinowitz argues that the use of the multi-employer citation policy in non-standard work
relationships would be strengthened by several steps that DOL could take, including revision of the
existing policy so that it explicitly and clearly covers both traditional and non-standard work
organization and developing a written legal justification for broad application of the policy. OSHA
could also strengthen its legal position on these issues by issuing a regulation, as was done in 1997 in
California, explicitly referring to multi-employer worksites in ͞ both construction and non-
construction/͟ See Title 8 of the alifornia ode of Regulations, Section 336/10 – Determination of
Citable Employer (available at https://www.dir.ca.gov/title8/336_10.html).
OSH! can also make use of the more traditional ͞ joint employer͟ doctrine in multi -employer
situations: Use of this doctrine would be necessary for enforcement of the ͚ general duty͛ clause and
may be necessary in some cases involving the enforcement of standards. This can be done advancing
the same type of legal argument as that used by the NLRB in the Browning Ferris and McDonald͛ s
cases, discussed above. The specific legal issues that confront the NLRB in re -interpreting the joint
2
The tort liabilityissue is one that is very specific to the state.
120
employer doctrine may also confront OSHA; the outcome of the NLRB cases, as they continue to be
litigated, will help to define the boundaries for developing this doctrine under the OSH Act.
Not surprisingly, broadening OSHA enforcement to include contracted and franchised facilities and
firms has already attracted attention from employers͛ representatives who focus on health and safety/
For example, Baruch Fellner, an attorney with Gibson Dunn & Crutcher LLP, told Bloomberg BNA in
August 2014, "If you've got a blocked exit at a McDonald's down the corner and they get a citation –
ho-hum. But if you've got hundreds of McDonald's receiving the same kinds of citations, with
ratcheted-up penalties going to the attention of the CEO of McDonald's writ large, then OSHA gets its
shaming mechanism and its deterrence mechanism." [Lee 2014].
Notably, state law – particularly the law governing workers͛ compensation – generally acknowledges
the relationship among contracting employers/ While direct employers usually provide workers͛
compensation coverage and, therefore, benefits, host and lead employers are, in many jurisdictions,
shielded from tort liability as a result of their contractual relationships with the direct employers. This
protection is sometimes extended by statute (Tennessee is one example), but it can also be extended
through the contracting arrangements between staffing agencies and host employers (as was recently
held by the Massachusetts Appeals Court in Molina v. State Garden, 88 Mass. App. Ct. 173 (Mass. App.
Ct. 2014). Obviously, this is not the universal rule, as can be seen by the Washington State case
described above.
There are other alternative strategies to allow for regulation of health and safety violations, but none
are available under current federal OSH law/ The ͚ hot cargo͛ provisions of the wage and hour laws –
which allow intervention in the supply chain when violations are found – are not now part of the OSH
regulatory landscape. Regulation of contracting terms – between franchisor and franchisee, or
between lead and supplier – might require inclusion of specific terms regarding OSH issues. Federal
contracting requirements might be expanded to include requirements and responsibilities within
franchising and staffing arrangements.
Two examples of non-OSH Act regulatory intervention in health and safety involving the mining
industry are also instructive. First, the Dodd Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act,
Pub. L. 111-103, was enacted shortly after the Upper Big Branch mining disaster. It requires publicly -
traded companies that operate mines to report a variety of safety-related information including
significant mine safety violations and the dollar value of assessed fines in their quarterly SEC filings that
go to shareholders. There is some belief that this heightened visibility of safety conditions to investors
will create an effective incentive to correct hazardous conditions and prevent them from occurring.
Second, the Mine Safety and Health Administration [MSHA] requirement for pre -shift inspections to
identify and mitigate hazardous conditions provides another example of efforts to prevent hazardous
conditions for all workers at a worksite no matter what their employment status. OSHA has
encouraged employers to develop and implement Injury and Illness Prevention Programs in an effort
to achieve similar goals.
Private rights to bring actions against employers that create or tolerate safety and health hazards –
including employers in contracting relationships – are generally viewed as state law issues, and may
sometimes be barred under the web of state laws governing the workplace . This is not, however,
121
universally true, as is also illustrated by the Washington State case discussed above. Notably, the
Washington State statute has an arguably broader definition of employers than the OSH Act, making
the reach of the statute in non-standard employment situations more likely. 3
State litigation that does not overlap with standards is likely to be going on ͚ below the radar͛ of much
of the national debate on these issues. A full discussion of the potential of state legal action in the
health and safety area is beyond the scope of this paper, although there is certainly additional state-
based litigation that is worthy of note/ For example, in a case involving severe burns in a Hardee͛ s
restaurant, where the plaintiff alleged a variety of state causes of action, a federal district court in
West Virginia denied the franchisor-defendant͛ s motion to dismiss/ The franchisor argued that it was
not the injured worker͛ s employer- the judge concluded ͞ that the Franchisor Defendants had actual
knowledge of alleged unsafe working conditions which were of long standing and much complained
about at the Hardee͛ s franchise in question,͟ where the plaintiff had alleged that the franchisor
provided training, supervision, inspections, equipment, cooking supplies, and procedures in
furtherance of the operation of that restaurant. ͞ It is reasonable to infer from these allegations that
the Franchisor Defendants had control over the equipment and procedures which contributed to
Hamrick͛ s injury and that their conduct created a risk of physical harm to Hamrick. Defendants owed
Hamrick a common-law duty to exercise reasonable care, and his alleged injury as a result of using
equipment and safety procedures in place at that restaurant makes him a foreseeable plaintiff.͟ See
Hamrick v. Restaurant Management Group LLC, Memorandum Opinion and Order, Civil Action No.
2:14-cv-02762 (S.D. W.Va., Sept. 19, 2014). The liability of franchisors and contracting firms will
undoubtedly be pressed by plaintiffs͛ lawyers in state claims like this one, where state law varies
regarding the extent to which employers have civil liability for workplace injuries; this is a worthy area
for additional exploration in thinking about the full set of potential legal actions that may help t o
improve health and safety in fissured workplaces around the country.
#3: Education, training, communication, medical surveillance, and personal protective equipment
Who is responsible for ensuring that individual workers receive the necessary informati on and training
to perform jobs in a safe manner? This is an easy question to answer in the standard employment
relationship. But in non-standard arrangements, where authority may be retained by a lead employer
that exerts indirect control of day-to-day work (e.g. franchising, supply chains) or in triangulated
contracting situations (e.g. staffing agencies or off-site subcontractors), the apparent diffusion of
responsibility may threaten the ability of workers to obtain critical information, be fitted wit h essential
personal protective equipment, or be assured that exposure time -limits are met when they move from
job to job. These problems may be exacerbated by language barriers and the legally vulnerable status
of undocumented immigrant workers. Workers may be understandably confused in triangulated work
relationships where employers are choosing to meet their responsibilities by contracting among
themselves, using contracts that are not available or transparent to workers or regulatory agencies.
3
The WISHA defines employer as follows: ͞ any person, firm, corporation, partnership, business trust, legal representative,
or other business entitywhich engages inanybusiness, industry, profession, or activity inthis state and employs one or
more employees or who contracts withone or more persons, the essence of which is the personal labor of suchpersonor
persons0/͟ RW 49.17.020(4) [emphasis added]-the OSH ! ct defines employers as follows. ͞ The term ͚ employer͛ means a
person engagedin a business affecting commerce who has employees0͟ 29 U/S//§ 652(5)/
122
The problems posed are clearly more challenging, both from a practical and regulatory point of view , in
triangulated work relationships than in hierarchical contracting relationships.
First, although not directly analogous, some standards extend responsibility for protections to non -
direct employers: manufacturers and distributors must create and transmit information under the
hazard communication standard regarding toxic chemical hazards; property owners must inform
contractors regarding asbestos hazards; multi-employer sites require employer to employer
communication. The confined space standard for general industry specifically requires host employers
to work with contractors, 29 C.F.R. § 1910.146(c)(8); failure to do so has resulted in at least one
criminal prosecution in which the trial judge allowed the case to go to trial after five workers died.
United States v. Xcel Energy, Inc., Criminal Case No. 09-cr-00389-WYD, Order denying defendant͛ s
motion to dismiss (D. Col. March 29, 2010). Thus, in situations involving standards, in which the non-
direct-employer holds critical information, OSHA has the ability to require transmittal of information
from one employer to another. This is in keeping with the broad language of the statute regarding
application of standards, discussed above. The breadth of this regulatory authority needs further
exploration.
Second, OSHA has launched the Temporary Worker Initiative (TWI), based upon data showing that
temporary workers are at increased risk of work-related injury and illness, and has also issued guidance
regarding treatment of workers employed through third party staffing agencies. The guidance states
explicitly that host and staffing agencies may be joint employers for purposes of OSHA enforcement:
While the extent of responsibility under the law of staffing agencies and host employers is
dependent on the specific facts of each case, staffing agencies and host employers are jointly
responsible for maintaining a safe work environment for temporary workers - including, for
example, ensuring that OSHA's training, hazard communication, and recordkeeping
requirements are fulfilled.
This is reiterated in instructions from Deputy Assistant Secretary Dougherty to Regional Administrators,
issued July 15, 2014. The guidance also recommends – but, because it is not a standard, does not
require – that temporary staffing agencies and host employers ͞ set out their respective responsibilities
for compliance with applicable OSH! standards in their contract,͟ and that ͞ [h\ost employers must
treat temporary workers like any other workers in terms of training and safety and health protections/͟
(emphasis in original) [OSHA 2014c]. The Dougherty memo specifically notes as well:
If the staffing agency has a long-term, continuing relationship with the temporary worker, it
may be best positioned to comply with requirements such as audiometric testing or medical
surveillance. The host employer, in turn, would be the primary party responsible for complying
with work-place-specific standards relating to machine guarding, exposure to noise or toxic
substances, and other workplace-specific safety and health requirements.
The OSHA TWI also specifically addresses responsibilities in these situations for providing personal
protective equipment, concluding:
123
As joint employers of temporary workers, both the host employer and the staffing agency are
responsible for ensuring that adequate PPE and associated training is provided. The host
employer will usually have the primary responsibility for selecting, providing and ensuring the
use of adequate PPE0 The staffing agency shares responsibility for its workers͛ safety and must
take reasonable steps to ensure that the host employer conducts the appropriate hazard
assessment and provides adequate PPP0 ͟ [OSHA 2014b]
Similar problems arise regarding injury record-keeping and medical surveillance. The staffing agency
may be most familiar with the consecutive work placements of its employees, and therefore must be
legally responsible for adherence to medical surveillance requirements – although, of course,
temporary workers in non-staffing agency relationships do not have this potential tracking mechanism.
OSHA, in its TWI Bulletin No. 1 [OSHA 2014a],addresses this problem by again noting the joint
employer status of the staffing and host employer. Here, OSHA concludes that the record -keeping
responsibility follows the path of direct supervision: if the host employer maintains day -to-day
supervision over the worker, the host employer is responsible for recording injuries and illnesses, but
the staffing agency ͞ shares responsibility͟ and therefore ͞ should maintain frequent communication
with its workers and the host employer to ensure that any injuries and illnesses are properly repor ted
and recorded/͟ It would also be helpful to require that all workers be given portable exposure and
medical surveillance information, given the mobility of the workforce in general. This would be
particularly useful for workers who are employed by staffing agencies at multiple worksites with the
same hazards.
Third, in November 2015, OSHA issued a draft of proposed Safety and Health Program Management
Guidelines (https://www.osha.gov/shpmguidelines/). These guidelines include a section on
communication and collaboration at sites where employees of more than one employer are present.
They also provide guidance to employers in triangulated work settings, although they do not create
new legal obligations. Needless to say, despite OSH! ͛ s recent and innovative efforts to give clear
guidance, all of this entails regular communication between and among employers, and clear and
comprehensible communication with workers – and a genuine commitment to the health and safety of
the contracted workers. In situations in which employers do not demonstrate this level of
commitment, OSHA is called upon to use its full enforcement powers. And, indeed, citations for
violations involving temporary workers͛ injuries have been issued by OSH! / In one current example,
OSHA issued citations against both the host employer, Moore Co Inc., and the staffing agency,
Manpower Group US Inc., after temporary workers were injured when inadequately guarded
machines pulled them in [U.S. Department of Labor Nov. 13, 2015]; citations in these situations have
also been sustained by the Review Commission, as in the case of Perez v. Matsu Alabama, Inc., d/b/a/
A Division of Matcor Automotive Inc., OSHRC Docket No. 13-1713 (Sept. 29, 2015). The legality of this
approach may ultimately not be in question – though it will certainly be litigated. The real problem is
that the vulnerability of workers, combined with the complexity of the relationships among the
employing firms, makes both worker voice and regulatory intervention difficult.
Moreover, none of these approaches acknowledges the problem that some workers are off -site
entirely, creating a separate challenge in the area of communication and monitoring. Nor doe s OSHA
124
address the problem of workers who come onto dangerous sites in order to make deliveries or who are
otherwise only transiently present.
RESEARCH
The diversity and frequency of changes in employment relationships have outpaced our understanding
of their consequences for the health, safety, and well -being of workers in non-standard employment
and of the best strategies for controlling or mitigating the risks. While some of these changes
undoubtedly benefit workers, providing new opportunities and, for some, increased flexibility and
autonomy, others confer additional risk.
In 1996 the National Occupational Research Agenda, developed through a NIOSH-led stakeholder
engaged process, identified changing employment relationships and organization of work as a high
priority for new research and surveillance. The recommendations for future research and improved
prevention are still relevant. These recommendations included: (1) improved surveillance to better
track how the organization of work is changing, (2) accelerated research on safety and health
implications of the changing organization of work, (3) increased research focus on organizational
interventions to protect safety and health, and (4) steps to formalize and nurture organization of work
as a distinctive field in occupational safety and health [CDC/NIOSH 2002].
Two types of investigations would be helpful in better understanding the health consequences of non -
standard employment and the effectiveness of policies intended to address them. A population -based
prospective investigation of the health consequences of non-standard employment could be designed
to account for a range of issues found in the current literature, most notably selection bias. This would
be useful in both understanding how workers in standard and non-standard employment differ, if at
all, and the impact of non-standard work on health and wellbeing. The study population would need
to be large in order to explore a wide range of these diverse employment arrangements and to be able
to evaluate whether any health effects observed vary with the intensity and duration of worker
exposure to non-standard work. But these investigations would need to be based on good information
concerning the basic demographics of workers in non-standard employment.
It would also be particularly useful to investigate the effectiveness of a range of policy approaches,
including both voluntary programs such as guidance and consultations as well as direct regulatory
interventions, that are intended to protect workers in non-standard employment. This kind of
intervention effectiveness research, while challenging to conduct, could be instrumental in providing
flexible, effective approaches to dealing with the diversity of employment arrangements faced by the
current workforce. Interventions that are narrowly workplace-focused are unlikely to be sufficient to
address the range of health consequences of non-standard employment. Policy interventions and their
evaluation must also look more broadly at the overall context of work beyond the traditional arena of
enforcement of health and safety regulations.
Notably, there continues to be a dearth of available information relevant to understanding the extent
to which workers are employed in fissured work arrangements, with estimates varying widely [Dey, et
125
al. 2012]. Definitions of the range of non-standard employment lack standardization. Health and
safety surveillance—the ongoing collection, analysis, and reporting of data for purposes of
prevention—has been unable to provide insight into the extent of non-standard employment, the
degree to which these relationships confer added risk, and the effectiveness of interventions intended
to address this risk.
To determine the risks faced by workers in fissured employment arrangements, we need two types of
data: (1) on injuries and illnesses categorized by relevant characteristics, including employment
category (e.g. staffing agency, franchisee, etc.) industry, occupation, age, gender, and race) and (2) on
employment and hours categorized by the same characteristics.
There are several national sources of information on employment and hours by industry. These sources
can most directly provide estimates of the employment in the employment services sector and in its
subsectors temporary help services and professional employer organizations (PEOs). They are less
helpful in providing estimates of non-standard work involving franchising, on-site contracting, and
supply-chain relationships. Bernhardt [2014] has recently written a good description of some of the
data challenges in identifying and measuring the extent of non-standard employment arrangements in
the U.S. economy.
The national data sources include Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) data and Quarterly Census
of Employment and Wages (QCEW) data, and Current Employment Stati stics (CES) data, all collected by
the U/S/ Department of Labor͛ s ureau of Labor Statistics (LS)/They also include the urrent
Population Survey (CPS) and the Contingent Worker Survey (CWS) Supplement to the CPS. These
sources have been used to estimate fissured employment numbers, but numbers derived from them
differ substantially. A major reason is differences in how the data are collected. For example, the
QCEW is designed as a complete census of employers, while the OES and CES are based on a sample of
employers. The CES and CWS Supplement are population-based surveys and rely on workers͛
responses. Surveys may not use the same classifications, causing comparability problems. These issues
are well-described by Dey, Housman, and Polivka [2010], and we will not dwell on them here.
A yet more difficult problem is matching current national injury data to fissured employment data.
There are two national occupational injury and illness datasets collected annually by the BLS: the
Census of Fatal Occupational Injuries (CFOI) and the Survey of Occupational Injuries and Illnesses (SOII).
Since 2011, the CFOI has been collecting information on both the firm employing the fatally injured
worker and the host employer [Pegula 2014]. However, contractor definitions are not identical in the
CFOI and the Census datasets, so linking the CFOI with employment and hours data may be
problematic. The SOII does not collect information identifying either contractors or staffing/PEO
workers, so it cannot be used to compare injury rates between fissured and standard employment.
Workers͛ compensation data has been used to compare the experience of staffing agency workers with
direct employees [Fan, et al. 2006, Foley, et al. 2014, Park and Butler 2001, Pierce, et al. 2013, Smith, et
al. 2010]. However, only a few states collect injury data that can be linked to occupation. This,
combined with the substantial differences in workers͛ compensation laws among states, limits t he
usefulness of this data source.
126
A potential solution to this data problem for the staffing agency arrangements in the administrative
and support services sector would be to add to the current required OSHA Form 301 the name, Federal
Employer Identification Number (EIN), and address of both the host and the employing firm for injured
workers, as well as the workers͛ occupation (perhaps the checklist now in the SOII) 4 and to fill out a
separate OSHA Form 300A for the lead firm and for each staffing or PEO firm paying wages or salaries
to people working at the host firm. Franchisees could be required to provide a single form (unless
they used staffing agency or PEO workers), but that form would also include the name, EIN, and
address of the franchisor firm. Requiring both EINs should mitigate the potential for double -counting
injuries.
We understand that such a change would require OMB approval and would need to go through
rulemaking. In addition, we recognize that there is substantial underreporting on OSHA forms and to
the SOII. Still, the proposed changes would potentially provide valuable surveillance data on the risks
of two important categories of fissured employment. It would also provide data that could be used in
the SOII to compare the risks of standard and fissured jobs nationally.
Gathering similar data for surveillance and research for same-site construction subcontractors,
franchises, and supply chains would involve more substantial changes in data collection. We can
imagine an OSHA initiative focusing on franchises that would require franchisor companies to obtain
OSHA Forms 300A and 301 from its franchisees. This information, together with equivalent information
from non-franchised locations, could then be made available to BLS or OSHA for statistical or
surveillance purposes. A parallel data collection could, in principle, be done where construction
contractors would collate this information for subcontractors working on their projects.
Conclusion
We reach several conclusions based upon this review of the occupational safety and health
implications of changes in work, the regulatory and policy environment, and the current state of data
collection and research.
First, the context in which these employment relationships appear is criti cal. Vulnerable workers can
be found in standard and fissured arrangements; not all workers in fissured arrangements are
necessarily more vulnerable; highly vulnerable workers are likely to be more vulnerable as a result of
some fissured work arrangements.
Second, one area is quite clear: There is ample evidence that temporary workers, and particularly
temporary workers employed through triangulated contracting arrangements, are particularly
vulnerable to OSH hazards when compared to workers with more stable work arrangements/ OSH! ͛ s
current focus on temporary workers is therefore warranted.
4
The SOII occupational categories are: office, professional, business; healthcare or management staff; delivery or driving;
sales; food service; product assembly, product manufacture; cleaning, maintenance of building, grounds; repair, installation
or service of machines, equipment; material handling (stocking, loading/unloading, moving, etc.); construction; and
farming.
127
Third, non-standard employment includes a broad range of specific arrangements and exposures.
There is a need for further research and data in a number of areas in order to assess fully the effects of
these heterogeneous contracting arrangements on occupational health and safety risk. There is much
that we do not know. Moreover, we cannot assume that the current nature of contracting
arrangements among firms will remain static. It will be important to understand the level of
penetration and the persistence of these contracting forms in different industries over time to assess
fully their effect on occupational safety and health. It would be useful to know when arrangements are
embraced because workers prefer them and which are accepted because of limitations in the labor
market that limit worker power or choice. Although the downward pressure on wages may be clear
when looking at staffing agency hiring and supply chain economics, we nevertheless need to better
understand the nature of contracting among firms, and the extent to which these contracts create
additional pressures that result in changes in occupational safety and health risk. We do not know, for
example, whether franchising – with clear directives from central firms – increases or decreases the
level of risk when compared with equivalent independent small businesses – and whether the answer
to this question would be industry-specific.
Finally, there are risks that are growing irrespective of these contracting arrangements that should not
be ignored. In this area, as in many others, the multiplicity of risks makes OSH a more difficult area to
assess than wage and hour violations. Disruptive technological changes, for example, may increase
psycho-social risk, irrespective of the specific nature of the employment contracting arrangement.
Other changes, including changes in labor market participation, particularly of aging workers, and new
hazards, such as those created by nanotechnology, may be as significant to OSH as changes in the work
relationships that are created by inter-firm contracting.
In sum, occupational safety and health – and the control of risks to workers – is a multidimensional and
highly contextual challenge. The changes in work relationships through fissuring are a piece of the
puzzle – but a piece that creates specific prevention challenges for employers and enforcement
challenges (and opportunities) for OSHA and its sister enforcement agencies.
128
REFERENCES
Abraham KG, Taylor SK. 1996. Firms' Use of Outside Contractors: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Labor
Economics: 394-424.
Aiken LH, Sloane DM, Klocinski JL. 1997. Hospital nurses' occupational exposure to blood: prospective,
retrospective, and institutional reports. Am J Public Health 87: 103-107.
Appelbaum E, Batt R, Bernhardt A, Houseman S. 2016. Domestic Outsourcing in the U.S.: A Research Agenda to
Assess Trends and Effects on Job Quality.
Asfaw ! / 2014/ Disparities in ! ccess to Health Insurance and Workers͛ ompensation enefit between Non-
Contingent and Contingent Farm Workers in US Agriculture. Journal of Health Disparities Research and Practice
7: 6.
Azari-Rad H, Philips P, Thompson-Dawson W. 2003. Subcontracting and injury rates in construction. Proceedings
of the Annual Meeting-Industrial Relations Research Association: Citeseer. p 240-247.
Azaroff LS, Levenstein C, Wegman DH. 2002. Occupational injury and illness surveillance: Conceptual filters
explain underreporting. Am J Public Health 92: 1421-1429.
Barth E, Bryson A, Davis JC, Freeman R. 2014. It's where you work: Increases in earnings dispersion across
establishments and individuals in the US: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Benach J, Vives A, Amable M, Vanroelen C, Tarafa G, Muntaner C. 2014. Precarious employment: understanding
an emerging social determinant of health. Annu Rev Publ Health 35: 229-253.
Benavides FG, Benach J, Muntaner C, Delclos GL, Catot N, Amable M. 2006. Associations between temporary
employment and occupational injury: what are the mechanisms? Occupational and environmental medicine 63:
416-421.
Berlingieri G. 2014. Outsourcing and the shift from manufacturing to services: Centre for Economic Performanc e,
LSE.
Berlinski S. 2008. Wages and contracting out: does the Law of one price hold? British Journal of Industrial
Relations 46: 59-75.
Bernhardt A. 2014. Labor Standards and the Reorganization of Work: Gaps in Data and Research.
http://escholarshiporg/uc/item/3hc6t3d5.
129
CDC/NIOSH. 2002. The Changing Organization of Work and the Safety and Health of Working People:
Knowledge Gaps and Research Directions. http://wwwcdcgov/niosh/docs/2002-116/pdfs/2002-116pdf DHHS
(NIOSH) Publication 2002-116.
Cummings KJ, Kreiss K. 2008. Contingent workers and contingent health: Risks of a modern economy. JAMA 299:
448-450.
Dey M, Houseman S, Polivka A. 2010. What do we know about contracting out in the United States? Evidence
from household and establishment surveys. Labor in the New Economy: University of Chicago Press. p 267-304.
Dey M, Houseman SN, Polivka ! E/ 2012/ Manufacturers͛ Outsourcing to Staffing Services. ILR Review 65.
Dube A, Kaplan E. 2010. Does outsourcing reduce wages in the low-wage service occupations? Evidence from
janitors and guards. Ind Labor Relat Rev 63: 287-306.
Erickcek GA, Houseman SN, Kalleberg AL. 2002. The effects of temporary services and contracting out on low-
skilled workers: Evidence from auto suppliers, hospitals, and public schools. WE Upjohn Institute Staff Working
Paper.
Fan ZJ, Bonauto DK, Foley MP, Silverstein BA. 2006. Underreporting of work-related injury or illness to workers͛
compensation: individual and industry factors. J Occup Environ Med 48: 914-922.
Filer RK, Golbe DL. 2003. Debt, operating margin, and investment in workplace safety. The Journal of industrial
economics 51: 359-381.
Foley M, Ruser J, Shor G, Shuford H, Sygnatur E. 2014. Contingent workers: Workers' compensation data analysis
strategies and limitations. Am J Ind Med 57: 764-775.
Goh J, Pfeffer J, Zenios S. 2015. Exposure To Harmful Workplace Practices Could Account For Inequality In Life
Spans Across Different Demographic Groups. Health Affairs 34: 1761-1768.
Grabell M. 2013. The Expendables: How the Temps Who Power Corporate Giants Are Getting Crushed.
http://wwwpropublicaorg/article/the-expendables-how-the-temps-who-power-corporate-giants-are-getting-
crushe.
130
Greenhouse S. 2015. In Service Sector, No Rest for the Working.
http://wwwnytimescom/2015/02/22/business/late-to-bed-early-to-rise-and-working-tiredhtml?_r=0%29.
Gregson S, Hampson I, Junor A, Fraser D, Quinlan M, Williamson A. 2015. Supply chains, maintena nce and safety
in the Australian airline industry. Journal of Industrial Relations: 0022185615582234.
Gruetter M, Lalive R. 2009. The importance of firms in wage determination. Labour Econ 16: 149-160.
Handwerker EW, Spletzer JR. 2015. Increased Concentration of Occupations, Outsourcing, and Growing Wage
Inequality in the United States.
Houseman SN, Kalleberg AL, Erickcek GA. 2003. The role of temporary agency employment in tight labor
markets. Ind Labor Relat Rev 57: 105-127.
James P, Johnstone R, Quinlan M, Walters D. 2007. Regulating supply chains to improve health and safety.
Industrial Law Journal 36: 163-187.
Ji M, Weil D. 2015. The Impact of Franchising on Labor Standards Compliance. ILR Review: 0019793915586384.
Kalleberg AL, Reskin BF, Hudson K. 2000. Bad jobs in America: Standard and nonstandard employment relations
and job quality in the United States. American Sociological Review: 256-278.
Kalleberg AL, Reynolds J, Marsden PV. 2003. Externalizing employment: flexible staffing arrangements in US
organizations. Soc Sci Res 32: 525-552.
Kerr C. 1954. The balkanization of labor markets. In: Bakke EWea editor. Labor Mobility and Economic
Opportunity Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Tecnology Press.
Kivimäki M, Vahtera J, Virtanen M, Elovainio M, Pentti J, Ferrie JE. 2003. Temporary employment and risk of
overall and cause-specific mortality. American Journal of Epidemiology 158: 663-668.
Kochan TA, Smith M, Wells JC, Rebitzer JB. 1994. Human resource strategies and contingent workers: The case of
safety and health in the petrochemical industry. Human Resource Management 33: 55-77.
Kunda G, Barley SR, Evans J. 2002. Why do contractors contract? The experience of highly skilled technical
professionals in a contingent labor market. Ind Labor Relat Rev 55: 234-261.
Lee S. 2014. NLRB Joint Employer Stance Could Affect OSHA Position on Franchisers, Franchisee. Bloomberg BNA
Labor Relations Week.
131
Manik JA, Najar N. 2015. Bangladesh Police Charge 41 With Murder Over Rana Plaza Collapse.
http://wwwnytimescom/2015/06/02/world/asia/bangladesh-rana-plaza-murder-chargeshtml.
Mayhew C, Quinlan M. 1997. Subcontracting and occupational health and safety in the residential building
industry. Industrial Relations Journal 28: 192-205.
McManus TC, Schaur G. 2014. The Effects of Import Competition on Worker Health.
http://papersssrncom/sol3/paperscfm?abstract_id=2668392.
Mehta C, Theodore N. 2006. Workplace safety in Atlanta's construction industry: Institutional failure in
temporary staffing arrangements. WorkingUSA 9: 59-77.
Morris JA. 1999. Injury experience of temporary workers in a manufacturing setting: factors that increase
vulnerability. AAOHN Journal 47: 470-478.
Muzaffar S, Cummings K, Hobbs G, Allison P, Kreiss K. 2013. Factors associated with fatal mining injuries among
contractors and operators. J Occup Environ Med 55: 1337-1344.
OSHA. 2014a. TWI Bulletin No. 1. Injury and Illness Recordkeeping Requirements.
https://wwwoshagov/temp_workers/OSHA_TWI_Bulletinpdf.
OSHA. 2015. Adding Inequality to Injury: The Costs of Failing to Protect Workers on The Job.
http://wwwdolgov/osha/report/20150304-inequalitypdf.
Pappas D, Mark C. 2011. A deeper look at contractor injuries in underground coal mines. Mining Engineering 63.
Park Y-S, Butler RJ. 2001. The safety costs of contingent work: Evidence from Minnesota. Journal of Labor
Research 22: 831-849.
132
Pegula SM. 2014. Fatal occupational injuries involving contractors, 2011. Monthly Lab Rev 137: 1.
Pierce O, Larson J, Grabell M. 2013. How We Calculated Injury Rates for Temp and Non-temp Workers.
PROPUBLICA, Dec 18.
Piore M, Doeringer P. 1971. Internal labor markets and manpower analysis. Lexington, Mass, Heath.
Quinlan M. 1999. The implications of labour market restructuring in industrialized societies for occupational
health and safety. Economic and industrial democracy 20: 427-460.
Quinlan M. 2015. The effects of non-standard forms of employment on worker health and safety. Conditions of
Work and Employment Series No 67 Geneva: International Labor Organization.
Rabinowitz R. 2015. Missed Opportunities: How OSHA Should Ensure Worker Safety in the Fissured Workplace.
ABA Section of Labor and Employment Law 9th Annual Labor and Employment Law Conference Philadelphia,
PA: American Bar Association.
Rebitzer JB. 1995. Job safety and contract workers in the petrochemical industry. Industrial Relations: A Journal
of Economy and Society 34: 40-57.
Seixas NS, Ren K, Neitzel R, Camp J, Yost M. 2001. Noise exposure among construction electricians. AIHAJ-
American Industrial Hygiene Association 62: 615-621.
Smith CK, Silverstein BA, Bonauto DK, Adams D, Fan ZJ. 2010. Temporary workers in Washington stat e. Am J Ind
Med 53: 135-145.
Spieler E. 2014. Written Statement Before the Subcommittee on Employment and Workplace Safety U.S. Senate
Committee on Health, Education, Labor and Pensions. http://wwwhelpsenategov/imo/media/doc/Spieler1pdf.
Spieler EA, Wagner GR. 2014. Counting matters: Implications of undercounting in the BLS survey of occupational
injuries and illnesses. Am J Ind Med 57: 1077-1084.
U.S. Department of Labor OoPA. Nov. 13, 2015. Furniture manufacturer, staffing agency expose workers to
hazards twice in 14 months; MooreCo Inc., Manpower Group US Inc. in Temple, Texas, face proposed fines of
$161K https://wwwoshagov/pls/oshaweb/owadispshow_document?p_table=NEWS_RELEASES&p_id=29043
Release Number: 15-2162-DAL.
Underhill E, Quinlan M. 2011. How precarious employment affects health and safety at work: the case of
temporary agency workers. Relations industrielles/Industrial Relations: 397-421.
133
Weil D. 1999. Are mandated health and safety committees substitutes for or supplements to labor unions? Ind
Labor Relat Rev 52: 339-360.
Weil D. 2014. The Fissured Workplace Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
134
Figure 1a. Employment Growth, U.S. 1990-2000
1.80
1.60 154%
1.40
1.20
1.00 94%
0.80
0.60
44%
0.40 35%
21%
0.20 15%
0.00
Total, all industries Facilities support Employment services Business support Security guards and Services to buildings
services services patrol services and dwellings
135
Figure 1b. Employment Growth, U.S. 2000-2014
0.50
0.40
36%
30%
0.30
23%
0.20
15%
0.10
5%
0.00
-9%
-0.10
-0.20
Total, all industries Facilities support Employment services Business support Security guards and Services to buildings
services services patrol services and dwellings
136
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Membership Covered
137