Lecture-1
Lecture-1
Department of Economics
In finance, the net present value (NPV) is defined as the sum of the present values (PVs) of the
individual incoming and outgoing cash flows over a period of time. Alternatively, incoming and
outgoing cash flows are described as benefit and cost cash flows, respectively. Benefit or cost
cash flows of nominally equal value over a time series are affected by the discount factor
resulting in different real value cash flows that makes future cash flows less valuable over time.
The concept of time value of money dictates that time has an impact on the value of cash flows.
If for example there exists a time series of identical cash flows, the cash flow in the present is the
most valuable, with each future cash flow becoming less valuable than the previous cash flow.
This decrease occurs because the discount factor represents the expected rate of return of each
cash flow in a different investment with identical risk, with each decreasing period, the present
calculating the present value (PV) of the total benefits and costs which is achieved by
discounting the future value of each cash flow. NPV is a useful tool to determine whether a
project or investment will result in a net profit or a loss because of its simplicity. A positive NPV
1
results in profit, while a negative NPV results in a loss. In a theoretical situation of unlimited
capital budgeting, a company should pursue every investment with a positive NPV. However, in
practical terms a company's capital constraints limit investments to projects with the highest
NPV whose cost cash flows do not exceed the company's capital.
In the case when all future cash flows are incoming (such as coupons and principal of a bond)
and the only outflow of cash is the purchase price, the NPV is simply the PV of future cash flows
minus the purchase price (which is its own PV). NPV is a central tool in discounted cash flow
(DCF) analysis and is a standard method for using the time value of money to appraise long-term
projects. Used for capital budgeting and widely used throughout economics, finance, and
accounting, it measures the excess or shortfall of cash flows, in present value terms, above the
cost of funds.
NPV can be described as the “difference amount” between the sums of discounted: cash inflows
and cash outflows. It compares the present value of money today to the present value of money in
The NPV of a sequence of cash flows takes as input the cash flows and a discount rate or
discount curve and outputs a price; the converse process in DCF analysis — taking a sequence of
cash flows and a price as input and inferring as output a discount rate (the discount rate which
would yield the given price as NPV) — is called the yield and is more widely used in bond
trading.
2
Formula
Each cash inflow/outflow is discounted back to its present value (PV). Then they are summed.
where
– the discount rate (the rate of return that could be earned on an investment in the financial
– the net cash flow i.e. cash inflow – cash outflow, at time t. For educational purposes, is
commonly placed to the left of the sum to emphasize its role as (minus) the investment.
Any cash flow within 12 months will not be discounted for NPV purpose, nevertheless the usual
initial investments during the first year R0 are summed up a negative cash flow.
Given the (period, cash flow) pairs ( , ) where is the total number of periods, the net
Discount Rate
3
The rate used to discount future cash flows to the present value is a key variable of this process.
A firm's weighted average cost of capital (WACC) (after tax) is often used, but many people
believe that it is appropriate to use higher discount rates to adjust for risk, opportunity cost, or
other factors. A variable discount rate with higher rates applied to cash flows occurring further
along the time span might be used to reflect the yield curve premium for long-term debt.
Another approach to choosing the discount rate factor is to decide the rate which the capital
needed for the project could return if invested in an alternative venture. If, for example, the
capital required for Project A can earn 5% elsewhere, use this discount rate in the NPV
calculation to allow a direct comparison to be made between Project A and the alternative.
Related to this concept is to use the firm's reinvestment rate. Reinvestment rate can be defined as
the rate of return for the firm's investments on average. When analyzing projects in a capital
constrained environment, it may be appropriate to use the reinvestment rate rather than the firm's
weighted average cost of capital as the discount factor. It reflects opportunity cost of investment,
An NPV calculated using variable discount rates (if they are known for the duration of the
investment) may better reflect the situation than one calculated from a constant discount rate for
For some professional investors, their investment funds are committed to target a specified rate
of return. In such cases, that rate of return should be selected as the discount rate for the NPV
4
calculation. In this way, a direct comparison can be made between the profitability of the project
To some extent, the selection of the discount rate is dependent on the use to which it will be put.
If the intent is simply to determine whether a project will add value to the company, using the
firm's weighted average cost of capital may be appropriate. If trying to decide between alternative
investments in order to maximize the value of the firm, the corporate reinvestment rate would
Using variable rates over time, or discounting "guaranteed" cash flows differently from "at risk"
cash flows, may be a superior methodology but is seldom used in practice. Using the discount
rate to adjust for risk is often difficult to do in practice (especially internationally) and is difficult
to do well.
NPV is an indicator of how much value an investment or project adds to the firm. With a
particular project, if is a positive value, the project is in the status of positive cash inflow in
the time of t. If is a negative value, the project is in the status of discounted cash outflow in
the time of t. Appropriately risked projects with a positive NPV could be accepted. This does not
necessarily mean that they should be undertaken since NPV at the cost of capital may not account
for opportunity cost, i.e., comparison with other available investments. In financial theory, if
5
there is a choice between two mutually exclusive alternatives, the one yielding the higher NPV
should be selected.
where
r(t) is the rate of flowing cash given in money per time, and r(t) = 0 when the investment is over.
Net present value can be regarded as Laplace, respectively, Z-transformed cash flow with the
integral operator including the complex numbers which resembles the interest rate i from the real
6
From this follow simplifications known from cybernetics, control theory and system dynamics.
Imaginary parts of the complex number s describe the oscillating behaviour whereas real parts
Motivation
C0 C1 C2 C3
Initial Clean-up
Investment Costs
Introduction
maximizing the wealth of shareholders. We had a simple model, but you can show that in much
more complex environments the same rule still holds. The NPV rule always works.
In addition to the NPV rule, we also had the rate of return rule. In that case they were
equivalent, but in general which should we use? Why go to the bother of calculating NPV when
we could find out whether to invest or not by comparing rate of return with opportunity cost? As
7
the motivation example illustrates it's not always easy to get the correct answer with the rate of
return rule.
In this Lecture we are going to argue for the superiority of the NPV rule over the rate of
return rule or, in its more general form, the internal rate of return (IRR) rule and also over various
We will start with why it is better than the IRR. We shall argue that they are equivalent
provided the IRR rule is properly applied, but it is much more difficult to apply the IRR rule, and
In the one period case we considered before, the one period rate of return R was given by
In the more general case with more than one period it is not entirely clear what is meant by the
What is the IRR? The IRR extends the last form given above for the rate of return. It is
the rate you discount at such that the discounted cash flow (DCF) is zero. The DCF is a function
C1 C2 CT
DCF(i) C 0 ...
1 i (1 i) 2
(1 i) T
C1 C2 CT
DCF( IRR ) C 0 ... 0
1 IRR (1 IRR ) 2
(1 IRR ) T
8
Finding the IRR
The easiest way to find IRR is a calculator. One question that may occur to you is how is
the calculator finding it? To see this, it is helpful to consider what is going on graphically. We
can calculate the DCF at a number of values of the discount rate, join them up and then read off
the value of the discount rate at which DCF = 0. This is the IRR. For example, suppose we have
Example 1
C0 C1
-1 +1.1
In this case we have the following values of DCF for various values of i:
i DCF(i)
0 -1 + 1.1 = 0.1
0.1 -1 + (1.1/1.1) = 0
9
Hence the IRR in this case is 10% since this is the value of i at which DCF is 0.
When you use a calculator what it is effectively doing is the same thing. It is finding
IRR Rules Now that we know how to extend the definition of rate of return to many periods
how do we extend our simple rate of return rule from Lecture 2? An obvious extension would be:
In some cases this rule is perfectly correct, but we have to be extremely careful because in
other cases it has to be adapted in order to lead to the same decisions as the NPV rule.
Cases where IRR Rule (1) is the same as the NPV Rule
Let's consider a case like our example where the DCF is a downward sloping function of i,
10
When does the IRR rule (1) say that we should accept projects? It says we should accept when
the IRR is above the opportunity cost of capital. For example, if the IRR is 10% and the
opportunity cost of capital is 5% we should accept the project. In other words, we should accept
at points to the left of the IRR. We should reject when the IRR is below the opportunity cost of
capital. For example, if the IRR is 10% and the opportunity cost of capital is 15% we should
reject the project. In terms of the diagram we should reject to the right of the IRR.
When does the NPV rule say that we should accept projects? The NPV of a project is just
the DCF where the rate used to discount is the opportunity cost of capital. Keeping with the
same example, when the opportunity cost of capital is 5% it can be seen from the diagram that
the NPV is positive. Hence we should accept. Similarly, we should accept whenever the
opportunity cost of capital is such that NPV is positive. When the opportunity cost of capital is
15% the NPV is negative and we should reject the project. Similarly, we should reject whenever
NPV is negative.
In this case the IRR rule (1) is the same as the NPV rule. In fact it can be seen from the
diagram that whenever the DCF of a project is a downward sloping function of i, the NPV and
11
the IRR rule (1) give the same result.
When Must IRR Rule (1) Be Adapted to Correspond to the NPV Rule
Now that we have seen that the two rules are the same when DCF is a downward sloping
function of i, when do you think they will differ? Suppose DCF is an upward sloping function of
The IRR rule (1) again says we should accept the project to the left of the IRR. However,
you can see that in this case the NPV is negative so that the NPV rule would say that we should
reject the project. To the right of IRR the IRR rule (1) would say that we should reject but NPV
is positive so that the NPV rule would say we should accept. We know from Lecture 2 that the
12
NPV rule is always right so in this case IRR rule (1) must be wrong. What is happening
intuitively here? To see this, let's look at a very simple example where DCF is upward sloping.
Example 2
C0 C1
+1 -1.1
Notice that this is the same as our original example except that the signs are reversed. Hence the
numerical values of DCF at various values of i will be the same but the signs will be reversed.
i DCF
0 +1 - 1.10 = -0.1
0.10 +1 - (1.1/1.1) = 0
In this case we have the type of relationship depicted above. What is happening? You receive 1
now and pay back 1.1 next period; in other words, you are "borrowing" and the IRR is like a
borrowing rate. Should you try to borrow at a high rate or at a low rate? At a low rate. If you
can borrow at less than the opportunity cost of capital then clearly you can make a profit (i.e.
NPV > 0) and this is what you should do--but this is what the NPV rule is saying.
13
C0 C1
-1 +1.1
In this case you are laying out $1 now in return for a payment of $1.5 next period. It is
like "lending" and the IRR is like the lending rate. You want to lend at as high a rate of interest
as possible. If the rate you can lend at is greater than the opportunity cost of capital, you can
make a profit so that NPV > 0. Again you can see that the NPV rule is intuitively right.
IRR rule (1) needs to be adapted to take account of whether you are "lending" or
(i) If DCF is a downward sloping function of i, accept the project provided the opportunity cost
(ii) If DCF is an upward sloping function of i, the project should be accepted if the IRR is less
The IRR rule (2) will then be equivalent to the NPV rule. In order to use IRR rule (2) we
have to know whether a project is a "lending" or "borrowing" project. In what types of situation
is it likely to be the case that NPV is a declining function of the discount rate i?
C1 C2 CT
DCF C 0 ...
1 i (1 i) 2
(1 i) T
14
There is one obvious case where this is downward sloping (which is what we need for the
two rules to be equivalent). This is where the first cash flow is an outlay on the investment
project so C0 < 0 and the cash flows in all the subsequent periods are positive so C1, C2, ... CT >0.
As i goes up, the positive terms in the DCF expression get smaller since they are divided by
(1+i)t term whereas the negative C0 term stays the same. Hence DCF gets smaller as i gets bigger
and the expression is downward sloping. In this case the project is guaranteed to be a lending
project. However, if C1 or C2 or any Ct up to CT < 0, then the possibility arises that DCF is
upward sloping and the project is a borrowing one. The reason is that there are now negative
terms that become smaller in magnitude as i rises so DCF may go up. Thus it is not always that
easy to discover which case you are dealing with. For example, consider the following situation
C0 C1 C2 C3
Initial Clean-up
Investment Costs
Such a profile of cash flows may arise, for example, with strip mining. What is the relationship
15
We then know it's a borrowing situation, and we should apply part (ii) of rule (2).
To summarize, if the first cash flow is negative and all the subsequent ones are positive
then you can use IRR rule (1). However, if there are any negative cash flows after time 0 you
have to use rule (2) and check whether it's a lending or borrowing project. This takes a fairly
With the NPV rule we don't have to determine the situation we are in--we just calculate
NPV. What NPV is measuring in terms of money today is the amount you are better off if you
use the 925 to do the project compared to just putting the 925 in the bank. Consider this way of
thinking for our motivation example. Let’s start by considering what you end up with at date 3
first for just putting the money in the bank and second putting it in the project and taking the cash
t= 0 1 2 3
16
(i) Put the 925 in the bank 9251.13 = 1231
The great advantage of NPV is it does this calculation automatically for you. It tells you
Multiple roots
not the only one. There is also the problem of multiple roots that we come to next.
17
In this case there are two values of i which are such that DCF = 0. Which is the internal
rate of return? We can devise a rule to deal with this type of case, but it is complicated.
(b) Given two IRR: IRR1, and IRR2, there are two possible situations.
(i) If at IRR1, DCF is upward sloping and at IRR2 DCF is downward sloping (i.e. the curve is
n-shaped), then we should accept the project if IRR1 < Opportunity cost of capital < IRR2.
18
(ii) If at IRR1, DCF is downward sloping and at IRR2, DCF is upward sloping (i.e. the curve
is u-shaped), we should accept if the opportunity cost of capital < IRR1 or > IRR2.
DCF
This is obviously an immensely complicated rule to apply. In fact, the problem is even more
serious than this example indicates since in general we may have many more than two values at
which DCF = 0, especially if the project is long-lived and there are many alterations between +ve
and -ve cash flows. For each of these possibilities we will have to develop a version of our IRR
19
rule.
Our problems with IRR are not at an end yet. Investment decisions are often concerned
with mutually exclusive projects, that is, ones in which you are choosing among different ways of
doing the same thing. In other words, in some circumstances you can only do one project, you
can't do all of them. An example would be replacing a machine on a production line; there may
be several alternative machines you could potentially use but you can only use one of them to
replace the old one. It would seem that the appropriate rule in this type of situation is:
In this case there is no problem--B is clearly superior to A. It always has a higher NPV and its
20
IRR is higher so that the naive rule works. When will the naive rule fail to work? Consider the
following situation:
In terms of the naive IRR rule, however, B would appear to be superior regardless of i.
Example
A -1,000 +1,200 20 91 0
21
If you graph A and B for NPV against i for this example you get the type of situation shown
What is happening is a question of relative versus absolute returns. A has a low relative
return but a high absolute return; B has a high relative return but a low absolute return. Given
they're mutually exclusive, you can't do both. What's important is which gives you the highest
absolute return since that's the amount that your budget constraint is pushed out or in other words
the money that actually goes in your pocket. You may be better off investing a large amount at a
It is possible to fix up the IRR rule by looking at the IRR on incremental cash flows. This
is rather painful and so we will not go through it here. It is much simpler just to use NPV.
One important point to note is that the analysis above assumes perfect capital markets.
This implies that it is possible for the firm to borrow as much as it would like to. If capital
markets are imperfect and the firm is limited in the amount it can borrow there is said to be
“capital rationing.” The way that capital budgeting decisions should be made in this case is
So far we have been assuming that there is just one opportunity cost of capital which is the
same for every period. However, as we discussed in Lecture 3 this may not be the case. The
22
In this case the opportunity cost of capital for different periods differs, and we must
C1 C2
NPV C 0 ...
1 r1 (1 r2 ) 2
We discount C1 at the opportunity cost of capital for 1 year, C2 at the opportunity cost of capital
Now if we use the IRR method, which opportunity cost of capital do we compare it to?
In a situation where the yield curve is not approximately flat we have to compare the project IRR
This is obviously a difficult task. Again the NPV rule is much simpler. Next we
23
consider the advantages and disadvantages of a number of other investment criteria that are used
by firms.
Profitability Index
It can be seen that only projects with a positive NPV are accepted, so it is again like the
NPV rule. However, as with the IRR, the profitability index ranks mutually exclusive projects
in a different way from NPV. The problem, as with IRR, is that they are both relative measures
of profitability, whereas NPV is an absolute measure, and it is the latter which is relevant here
since this determines the amount the budget constraint of shareholders can be shifted outward.
Consider the example we used with IRR and mutually exclusive projects again.
Here we should choose A since this pushes out the budget constraints of shareholders the
farthest. A naive profitability rule which chose the project with the highest PI would give an
incorrect answer; it would say choose B. However, we can again adapt the PI method to deal
with this by looking at the PI of the incremental investment similarly to IRR. Again,
appropriately adapted, PI, like IRR, is not incorrect but NPV is easier to use.
24
Payback
The payback rule requires that the initial outlay on any project should be recoverable
within some specified cutoff period. The payback period is calculated by counting the number of
years it takes before forecasted cash flows equal the initial investment.
Example
With the payback method we will accept A if the cutoff period is 1 year or over and B if it
is 3 years or over. With NPV, however, we would reject A and accept B. Thus payback can give
incorrect answers to the capital budgeting problem, unlike IRR and PI which were just more
difficult to use.
Why doesn't payback give the same results as NPV? There are three main problems with it.
(i) The first difference is clearly that with payback no account is taken of the difference in the
value of $'s at different dates. To try and deal with this we could use the discounted payback
method which takes into account the time value of money but this still suffers from the other two
defects.
(ii) The second defect is that the cutoff date is fairly arbitrary. If you use the same cutoff,
regardless of the project, then you reject too many long lived projects and accept too many short
lived ones.
There are certain special cases where we can calculate a formula for the optimal cut off
25
period which corresponds to maximizing NPV, e.g., if flows are spread evenly across the life of
(iii) The third defect is that it ignores all flows after the cutoff date so there is a bias against long
lived projects.
Does payback have any advantages? One advantage of payback is its ease of calculation
compared to NPV. With short time horizons where things are constantly being replaced and the
projects are small (e.g., office supplies and equipment) it may be worthwhile to use the payback
method because of its ease of computation. In the majority of cases we shouldn't use it though
There are various other criteria which are used for investment decisions. Many are
accounting based such as the book rate of return. These other methods are either difficult to use
or do not correspond to creating wealth for shareholders. I won't go through the deficiencies here
but you can read about them. NPV is best because it is relatively easy to use and directly
measures what we are interested in namely how much wealth is created for shareholders.
Capital Rationing
We have argued above that one of the problems with IRR and PI is that they are relative
measures rather than absolute measures. We suggested it is the absolute amount of money
received that shareholders are interested in so it can be better to take a large investment with a
low rate of return than a small investment with a high rate of return. Implicit in this argument is
the assumption that the firm can invest as much as it wants to. Capital rationing occurs when the
firm has limitations on the capital it can invest which prevent it from undertaking all investment
26
opportunities with positive net present value that are available to it. We next consider how
There are a number of reasons why firms may operate with capital rationing.
Management may believe a rapid expansion will overtax the organization and use a capital
constraint as a proxy in restricting this growth. This is an example of soft rationing, where the
Because of problems of fraud, people may be reluctant to give any particular firm too
much money. This is an example of hard rationing, which is externally imposed by the market.
In these types of situations, how should the firm make its investment decisions? It is first
necessary to check that the assumption of perfect capital markets for shareholders is not violated.
Unless this is true, maximizing NPV will not remain a valid objective for the firm. Assuming
there are perfect capital markets for shareholders, the firm should choose its investment, I, to
maximize its NPV subject to the constraint that I is not more than I* where I* is the maximum
We want to maximize the NPV of the I* we are allowed to invest and get the "biggest bang
for our buck". We need to select the projects that will maximize NPV per dollar. One natural
intuition is that we should rank by some relative measure such as PI or IRR and accept projects
until we have exhausted the capital constraint. As we shall see, this method sometimes works
Consider what happens if you have two projects, A and B, which require equal investments
IA and IB, respectively, and which have 1+PI's as follows. Plot 1+Profitability Index (1+PI)
27
against Investment (I). Note that
NPV ( PV I) PV
1 PI 1 1
I I I
1+PI NPV
NPV
A B
I I
A B
I
*
I
In interpreting this diagram it is helpful to remember that each bar represents a project:
= (PV/I) * I
= PV
=I
= NPV
Hence the objective of firms is to choose the projects which maximize the total shaded area.
28
In the diagram above, if the firm is constrained to I*, in this situation it should clearly do A.
Ranking by PI and accepting until the constraint is satisfied works in this case.
If there are three projects A, B and C as below which all require the same investment what
1+PI
A B C
I I IC I
A B
I *
Clearly it should do A and B. Again the rule of ranking by PI and accepting until the
constraint is exhausted works. Is it always the case that the rule works? No! If the projects
1+PI
A B C
29
I I I I
A B C
*
I
It's not even clear that it will always be best to do the most profitable project.
1+PI
A C B
I I I I
A C B
I *
C produces more NPV than A. You can't do both A and C, so you do C. You can still do B
Thus ranking by PI and choosing the projects with the highest return until you exhaust the
capital constraint can often give incorrect solutions. It is only if all investments are the same that
it definitely works. Essentially what we should do if investments are unequal is try all possible
combinations of projects that satisfy the capital constraint and choose the combination with the
highest NPV.
With 3 projects this is not too difficult, but as the number increases, the number of possible
technique that does this is integer programming. This is more sophisticated than simple trial and
error: it chooses its combinations in a systematic way to increase NPV on each new combination.
30
When it gets to a point where no more combinations increase NPV, it stops. In situations where
it is not worth applying such sophisticated techniques because of the time involved ranking by PI
or IRR and taking the best projects until you exhaust I* may on occasions be the best technique.
31