Hilton, Rodney, English and French Towns in Feudal Society, Cambridge, 1995 P 6-24-Cap1-The Town and Feudalism, Preliminary Definitions
Hilton, Rodney, English and French Towns in Feudal Society, Cambridge, 1995 P 6-24-Cap1-The Town and Feudalism, Preliminary Definitions
A T O W N I S A T O W N W H E R E V E R I T IS?
What was a town? A preliminary definition, however general, may
be useful. The definition need not attempt to cover all towns from
antiquity to the twentieth century, but only those of medieval, feudal
society. One of the problems is that even medieval towns varied
greatly in size and function, from small market towns with even
fewer than 1,000 inhabitants to great cities, like Paris, with more
than 100,000. A useful definition may, then, be rather what was not
a town than what was. In effect, the town has to be distinguished
from its rural hinterland and not, as some historians have tended to
do, to be assimilated into the agrarian economy and society.1
The first point to be made is that the town, great or small, was the
location of permanent market activity, not only at a weekly
chartered market, which the lords of many villages also obtained in
the thirteenth century. Second, and this is crucial, the inhabitants of
the town did not, in contrast to those of the village, produce their
own means of subsistence, even though they might have small
vegetable plots, vineyards or even meadows. Their main activity was
devoted to manufacture and trade, from which the bulk of their
income was derived. The essential feature of towns, large or small,
was occupational heterogeneity in an economy which produced,
bought and sold commodities other than those necessary for
subsistence, that is, mainly agricultural products.
The existence of a permanent market and of occupational
heterogeneity might seem to be sufficient to define the medieval town
very broadly, but many historians would probably wish to add at
1
Already criticised in 'Towns in English Feudal Society’ reprinted in my Class
Conflict and the Crisis of Feudalism.
6
The town and feudalism : preliminary definitions 7
least an institutional dimension. This usually included the possession
by the town’s inhabitants of certain basic liberties, without which
their special function could not be properly fulfilled. They would at
least need freedom of status and tenure, freedom of movement and
freedom of access to the market. Even if it were argued that a
settlement with a market and an occupationally heterogeneous
population should be assumed to be a town, one would expect that
the grant of at least elementary liberties usually followed the
economic development implied by the first two conditions, and
would provide an extra indicator of urban status.
The role of the town in medieval feudal society has been perceived
in many different ways, over the years, both by historians and
sociologists. Some sociologists, in particular, have been tempted to
assimilate the medieval town, like medieval feudal society, into a
generalised pre-industrial or ‘traditional’ era in human history. In
their long term perspective of pre-industrial history, they have
perceived a duality between town and country, from the ancient
world onwards, and conceived ‘the city’ as an unchanged social
essence whose economy, society and ethos were always and
necessarily specific to a model of urbanism, whatever the overall
social formation.
This concept of ‘the city’ as an entity independent of the context
of the wider society is reflected in the views of Louis Wirth in his
famous article, ‘Urbanism as a Way of Life’. 2 Not all sociologists,
of course, ignored the historical context. One has only to remember
Max Weber’s book on The City, a work with many illuminating
perceptions of medieval urbanisation. 3 G. Sjoberg’s The Preindus
trial City emphasises the varying economic, social and political
contexts of pre-industrial cities. Unfortunately, he over-generalises
pre-industrial society. For him, the whole pre-industrial world is
divided into ‘folk’ and ‘feudal’ social formations, defined in a
manner unrecognisable by historians. His elaborate theorising,
however much he preaches to those (especially historians) presumed
to be ignorant, is of little use in dealing with real feudalism.4
On the whole, historians have been less all-embracing in their
perception of the pre-industrial town. Nevertheless, there have been
elements in their work which, to a greater or lesser extent, include
the concept of the unchanging town: country duality. Even Fernand
2
American Journal of Sociology, 44, 1938.
3 4
Trans. D. Martindale and G. Neuworth. New York, 1960.
8 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH T O W N S
W H A T WAS FEUDALISM?
We must, of course, recognise that there are different ideas about
what is ‘feudalism’. The traditional interpretation defines it in terms
of the relationships between different strata of the landowning class.
The determining features are the lord-vassal relationships, con
cretely manifested in the granting from on high of landed fiefs to
clients, retainers and relatives, in return for homage, military service,
aid and counsel. 12 Although this could imply a fairly tightly
organised pyramidal structure, as was found in the Norman
10
M.M. Postan, The Medieval Economy and Society, p. 212.
11
Cambridge, Mass., 1985, pp. 2, 19.
12
F.M. Stenton, The First Century of English Feudalism, 1066 to 1166, very well
describes the feudo- vassalic aspect for England. For France, see F.L. Ganshof,
Feudalism, trans. P. Grierson. Marc Bloch, Feudal Society, trans. L.A. Manyon,
presents a more wide-ranging view.
10 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH TOWNS
14
See my Bond Men Made Free.
12 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH T O W N S
19
See his contribution to The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism, intro. R.H.
Hilton.
20
Suggested by H.P.R. Finberg in his edition of The Agrarian History of England and
Wales, I, Part 2, p. 392; and by Fournier, Le peuplement, pp. 127-200.
21
The Feudal Monarchy in France and England, trans. E.D. Hunt.
The town and feudalism : preliminary definitions 15
22
Les trois ordres ou F imag inaire du féodalisme.
16 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH T O W N S
URBAN C L A S S E S - A P R E L I M I N A R Y VIEW
Much of the conflict in feudal society, and that which is best known,
resulted from competition for land and power within the upper
23
For Antoigné, see Bond Men Made Free, p. 66; for Rosny-sur-Bois, see the English
translation of Bloch’s article in S.L. Thrupp, ed., Change in Medieval Society.
24
R.H. Hilton, ‘Lord and Peasant in Staffordshire in the Middle Ages’, in Hilton,
The English Peasantry in the later Middle Ages, p. 23; Hilton, ‘A Thirteenth
Century Poem on Disputed Villein Services’, in Hilton, Class Conflict and the
Crisis of Feudalism, p. 110.
The town and feudalism : preliminary definitions 17
ranks of society. But if we accept that the main division, and
therefore area of conflict, was between two classes, namely the ruling
landowning aristocracy, lay and ecclesiastical, and the peasantry, a
re-evaluation of the idea that the towns were the leading element in
anti-feudal movements will need to be made. If towns were not, by
their very nature, anti-feudal entities, were the divisions within
feudal society reflected in them? How different from those of the
countryside were urban classes and class relationships?
One fundamental difference, of course, was that the urban
artisans did not, like the peasants, produce their own means of
subsistence, although many urban artisans did in fact have small
plots and gardens within or just out of town. 25 Nevertheless the
artisan workshop, like the peasant holding, was an enterprise based
on a family labour force with only two or three additional persons
- an apprentice, one or two journeymen - just as many peasant
households had one or two servants. Below the artisans, whether
masters, apprentices or journeymen, there were many unskilled
workers, as well as beggars, prostitutes and other marginals. A
constant flow of rural immigrants sustained the numbers of the
artisans and retail traders, as well as of the unskilled workers and
marginals. It was an influx almost impossible to measure. It was
partly due to the higher mortality of the urban population, as well
as to the attractions of urban life. But even though rural immigration
cannot be reliably quantified, there are indications from the number
of people with surnames indicating a rural origin that in some of the
expanding urban centres in the late thirteenth and early fourteenth
centuries, at least a third of the tax-paying inhabitants were recent
immigrants, and probably an even higher proportion further down
the social scale. 26 We can only guess what was their influence on
town life.
If we move above the mass of artisans, small shopkeepers and
other petty traders, do we then find a class which is clearly separate
from, and antagonistic to, the main structures of feudal society?
Studies of medieval towns have clearly designated the nature of their
ruling class. Wealthy leading masters of craft gilds occasionally
obtained a minor voice in town government. In some areas, the
lesser nobility and officials with legal training might have a greater
share (increasingly in the case of the latter), and there was always
25
A. Higounet-Nadal, ‘Les jardins urbains dans la France médiévale’.
26
A survey of some of the evidence is in P. McClure, ‘ Patterns of Migration in the
Later Middle Ages: the Evidence of English Place-name Surnames’.
18 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH T O W N S
30
Duby, The Rural Economy, Book 3, chapter 2.
31
Hilton, The Decline of Serfdom in Medieval England.
22 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH T O W N S
landlord class - as was the case in France. There were earls, heads of
wealthy aristocratic families, and other lay landlords of lesser
wealth, down to the thegns who were lords of villages (or even less)
- antecedents of many of those who in the twelfth and thirteenth
centuries would be known as knights. In addition, there were
wealthy landowning bishops and abbots who controlled great
estates, freed from undue lay influence since the reforms of the tenth
century. As in post-Carolingian France, it was the lay and
ecclesiastical aristocracy which provided the ruling cadres at the
level of the shire (county in France), and - especially the ecclesiastics
- had private jurisdiction over their estates. One should also
probably not exaggerate the difference between Anglo-Saxon
military mobilisation and that regarded as properly ‘feudal’. The
word ‘feudum’ (fief) may not have been used, but the vassals of the
king and lords did in fact do military service for lands received, as
E. John pointed out many years ago.32
England after 1066 had its earls, barons, bishops and abbots with
vast estates, but these estates tended to be scattered. Coherent
duchies and counties, as in France, did not exist, except (marginally)
on the frontiers of Scotland and Wales. The wide scattering of the
aristocratic estates is shown in Domesday Book. One of the
wealthiest of the Norman expropriators of the English landowners
was the count of Meulan, whose considerable estates (793 manors)
were distributed over Cornwall, Buckinghamshire, Devon, Dorset,
Northamptonshire, Somerset, Sussex and Yorkshire. Earl Roger of
Montgomery, nearly as wealthy (544 manors), held his lands mainly
in Shropshire, but also in eleven other counties, down as far as
Sussex. The earl of Chester (Ranulf III), at the beginning of the
thirteenth century, was also earl of Lincoln and lord of the Honours
of Leicester and Lancaster. His contemporary, the famous William
Marshal, had a fief as far north as Cartmel (Lancashire) and family
holdings in two midland and four southern counties, not to speak of
his scattered acquisitions resulting from his marriage to the daughter
of the earl of Pembroke. In the late thirteenth century, the Clare
earls of Gloucester, one of the richest landed families, not only had
the lands of their family honours of Gloucester, Clare (Suffolk) and
Tonbridge (Kent), but also various other acquisitions. Their manors
were scattered throughout some twenty counties, from the midlands
32
E. John, Land Tenure in Early England; see also his contribution to Campbell, ed..
The Anglo-Saxons.
The town and feudalism : preliminary definitions 23
to the south-east. This scattered distribution of feudal estates
continued throughout the middle ages.
In the tenth, eleventh and twelfth centuries, the Capetian
monarchy, although claiming suzerainty over France west of the
Rhone (and of Alsace and Lorraine), still only had control over its
domain in the He de France, with a wider indirect influence over a
number of bishoprics and abbeys beyond. The great dukes and
counts had, in effect, what were independent principalities, of which
the duchies of Aquitaine, Brittany, Normandy and Burgundy, and
the counties of Toulouse, Flanders and Champagne were the most
important. After the marriage, in 1152, of Eleanor of Aquitaine to
Henry Plantagenet, count of Anjou, later to become king of England
(1154), the whole of western France, except for Brittany, from
Normandy to Gascony, came under the control of the English
monarchy.
Within the royal, ducal and comital domains, as well as those of
the great ecclesiastics, there was, as in England, a hierarchy of feudal
landowners, barons, castellans, knights and lords of villages, though
in France, the castellany was a more important intermediate element
in the feudal hierarchy than in England. 33 All acquired powers of
jurisdiction, not only over their tenants but over all inhabitants of
their lordship (seigneurie banale). Haute justice, that is, jurisdiction
over cases for which there was death penalty for the guilty, was not
enjoyed by petty lords, but nevertheless was found much lower down
the social scale than in England, for, in spite of the considerable
jurisdictional powers that lords of manors in England had over their
unfree tenants, the king monopolised haute justice.
The centrally-controlled law courts in England were matched by
relatively sophisticated royal financial and administrative appara
tuses, with effective locally-based officials. By the thirteenth century,
the Capetian monarchy was developing similar institutions, though
primarily on the royal domain rather than throughout the kingdom.
Because the English lay and ecclesiastical nobility was not able to
develop regional powers to the extent found in France, it pursued its
political interests at the centre. However much elements among the
baronage might oppose royal policies, they had to do so at the
national level. Their aim was to control the king, his court and his
administration, not to set up rival states of their own. However
33
Duby, The Chivalrous Society, trans. C. Postan.
24 ENGLISH A N D FRENCH T O W N S