0% found this document useful (0 votes)
3 views

Knowledge_Based_Industry_and_Regional_Gr

The document discusses the shift towards a knowledge-based economy in industrialized countries, highlighting the increasing importance of knowledge and technology in driving regional growth. It emphasizes the role of knowledge-intensive industries and the impact of information and communication technology (ICT) on reducing knowledge gaps between regions. The paper also explores the mechanisms of knowledge spillover and the need for regional policies to support knowledge-based industries for sustainable economic development.

Uploaded by

duttashreelagna
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
3 views

Knowledge_Based_Industry_and_Regional_Gr

The document discusses the shift towards a knowledge-based economy in industrialized countries, highlighting the increasing importance of knowledge and technology in driving regional growth. It emphasizes the role of knowledge-intensive industries and the impact of information and communication technology (ICT) on reducing knowledge gaps between regions. The paper also explores the mechanisms of knowledge spillover and the need for regional policies to support knowledge-based industries for sustainable economic development.

Uploaded by

duttashreelagna
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 23

View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.

uk brought to you by CORE


provided by Hochschulschriftenserver - Universität Frankfurt am Main

Forschungsberichte
Working Papers
Institut für Wirtschafts- und Sozialgeographie
Department of Economic and Social Geography
Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität Frankfurt

Herausgeber Harald Bathelt und Eike W. Schamp


ISSN 1439-2399

© Copyright Institut für Wirtschafts- und Sozialgeographie der Johann Wolfgang


Goethe-Universität Frankfurt und die Autoren

Sam Ock Park

Knowledge-based industry and regional


growth

IWSG Working Papers 02-2000


Die Herausgeber bedanken sich bei Johannes Glückler für die Gestaltung des
Layouts und die Unterstützung der Produktion dieser Reihe.

Autorenanschrift Sam Ock Park,


author’s address Department of Geography
Seoul National University,
Seoul 151-742, Korea
Fon (0) 82-2-880-6449; Fax (0) 82-2-886-4556
Email : [email protected];
URL: http://prome.snu.ac.kr/~igucom
1

1 Introduction

One of the most important but less understood phenomena in the beginning of the
21st century has been a shift toward knowledge-based economic activity in the
comparative advantage of modern industrialized countries. Two broad trends has
been observed in the global economy. That is, the output from the world's science
and technology system has been growing rapidly and the nature of investment has
been changed (MILLER, 1996). The relative proportions of physical and intangible
investment have changed considerably with the relative increase of intangible
investments since the 1980s. In addition, there has been increased complementarity
between physical and intangible investments and more important role of high
technology in both kinds of investment (MILLER, 1996). Even in the newly
industrialized countries, the growth of technology intensive industries, the increase of
R&D activities and the growth of the knowledge intensive producer services have
been common feature in recent years. In this change of the structure of productive
assets, the role of knowledge is well recognized as the most fundamental resources
in recent years (OECD, 1996; W ORLD BANK, 1998). The development of information
and communication technology (ICT) and globalisation trend have promoted this shift
toward knowledge-based economy.
The important role of knowledge in the economy and society is not a new idea.
In Western society, a proverb from Francis Bacon saying that "Knowledge is power"
has long history. There are also many proverbs and instructions regarding the
knowledge in the oriental countries. It is recognized that "Adam Smith refers to new
layers of specialists who are men of speculation and who make important
contributions to the production of economically useful knowledge" (FOREY AND
LUNDVALL, 1996: 11). The role of knowledge become more important over time and
this idea has periodically reappeared in the economic history as implied in the long
waves of Kondratiev. If the importance of the knowledge in the economy is not a new
idea and recognized several centuries ago, then why should we emphasize the shift
toward knowledge-based economy in recent years? There are three major reasons of
emphasis on the shift toward knowledge-based economy as follows.

First, it was found that net job creation was predominantly taking place in the
knowledge-intensive economic activities, which include both knowledge industry and
knowledge-based industry. Knowledge industries are those whose output is
knowledge such as patents, inventions, and new products, as well as services that
2

are mainly knowledge, while knowledge-based industries are those whose main
product or service is dependent on technology or knowledge.1 Knowledge industries
and knowledge-based industries are interdependent since knowledge is output from
the former and input to the latter, and they are together making the knowledge-based
economy. Considering that knowledge is also an important input for the knowledge
industry, knowledge industry can be included in the broad meaning of the knowledge-
based industry.

Second, dominant proportion of work forces in the modern industrialized


countries are knowledge workers such as information system designers, managers,
professionals, educators, scientists, skilled manufacturing teams, and the like. It is
expected that the traditional 'job' will fade and knowledge entrepreneurs will replace
traditional service and factory workers in the more flexible workplace of tomorrow
(HALAL, 1996). In the most of industrialized countries the principal contribution to
employment growth has been the advanced service sector which are creating and
using knowledge products in exactly the way that manufacturing transformed raw
materials into physical products (BERRY, CONKLING, AND RAY, 1997). Concurrently,
new technology has been adopted in the manufacturing and, as a result, there has
been a dramatic growth of high technology industrial products with substantial R&D
inputs. Such trends of changes are also witnessed in the newly industrialized
countries in recent years (CLARK AND KIM, 1996). Accordingly, the knowledge
industries and the knowledge-based industries are driving forces of the knowledge-
based economy.
Third, the rapid development of ICT has promoted the shift toward the
knowledge-based economy. Many characteristics of the knowledge-based economy
such as new dynamics of tacit and codified knowledge, the growing importance of
networked knowledge, and the acceleration of process of interactive learning are
related with the increasing use of ICT (FREEMAN AND SOETE, 1993). The rapid
diffusion of ICT to developing countries in recent years has resulted in the decreasing
information gap between industrialized and developing countries and in the growing
importance of the knowledge-based economy in the global society as a whole.

There is a wide agreement across all layers of society in the industrialized


countries on the trend of the shift toward the knowledge-based economy and on the

1) These definitions are based on personal communication with Edward Malecki, Grahm Humphrys,
and Richard Le Heron, and OECD (1996).
3

crucial role of knowledge in the economic activities. This wide agreement implies a
challenge for regional development theory and for regional and industrial policy with
dynamics of economic space in the 21st century. The emergence of the region and
the locality as the main arenas for growth in a globalizing world has been well noted
during the last two decades. Much growth at the regional and local level results from
the growth of new industries, which include cultural, health, high technology and
knowledge industries. Basically, these new types of industries are mostly knowledge-
based activities. The new motors of growth behind this emergence of new growth
region have received less attention in economic geography. The purposes of this
paper are dealing with the pressing issues related to understanding the role of the
knowledge-based industries in promoting regional growth and to derive some
directions of regional and industrial policy for regional growth.

2 Knowledge, Development, and Information Communication


Technology

Knowledge is a crucial factor for advancing economic and social development. It has
been well recognized that knowledge is power and well-being in long history of both
Western and Eastern societies. The difference between poor countries and rich ones
can be ascribed not only to less capital but also less knowledge in the poor ones
(THE W ORLD BANK, 1998). The results of empirical studies of OECD reveal that the
overall economic performance of the OECD countries increasingly and more directly
based upon their knowledge stock and their learning capabilities (OECD, 1996).
Developing countries have less knowledge about technology than industrialized
countries, resulting knowledge gaps across counties. Even within countries,
knowledge gaps in acquiring, absorbing, and communicating knowledge exist among
regions. In the capacity to create knowledge, the knowledge gaps are even greater
between developing countries and modern industrialized countries because
knowledge is often much costly to create.
The model of knowledge production function, formalized by Griliches (1979),
at the unit of observation of countries or industries also supports the positive
relationship between knowledge and development. In the knowledge production
function model, firm exists exogenously and then engaged in the pursuit of new
economic knowledge as an input into the process of generating innovative activity.
Considerable empirical evidences suggest that there is strong relationship between
4

R&D and innovative output, measured in terms of either patents or new product
innovation (AUDRETSCH, 1999). Some empirical analysis also shows that investment
in knowledge is characterized by increasing returns (OECD, 1996). However, the
model of knowledge production function becomes particularly weak when small firms
are included in the sample for the unit of observation of the firm. This result at the
firm level is consistent with the results of some empirical studies which suggest that
formal R&D is concentrated among the largest corporations and small firms account
for a disproportional share of new product innovation given their low R&D
expenditures (ACS AND AUDRETSCH, 1990).

In the industrial engineering and industrial production, knowledge and


technology are closely correlated since knowledge on technology in emphasized. In
the knowledge-based economy, however, not only knowledge on technology but also
knowledge on advanced services such as management, marketing, financing, etc.
are also important. In the knowledge-based economy product innovation is not limited
to the tangible manufacturing products, but it also includes the intangible new
products such as new financial product and new management system which are
mainly based on new knowledge and idea. Accordingly, there are not only consistent
sectors or activities which have close correlation between knowledge and technology
in the industrial production sector, but also inconsistent sectors between knowledge
and technology dimensions. That is, some high technology sectors require high level
of knowledge, but others may require relatively low level of new knowledge on the
one hand. On the other hand, some low technology sectors or activities require the
high level of knowledge, while others require low level of knowledge as expected.
Due to the inconsistency between knowledge and technology in the knowledge-
based economy, there is a possibility that the low technology industry can move
toward knowledge-based industry with applying new knowledge. These two
dimensions of knowledge and technology will be more elaborated in the following
section with regard to Figure 1.

Revolution of ICT has contributed to lessen the gaps of knowledge and


technology among countries and regions as well as among firms in the global
economy. The development of ICT accelerates radical changes in the way
knowledge is produced, stored, and diffused. With communication costs plummeting,
especially in the optical fiber transmission cost, during the last two decades, the cost
of sending information and knowledge is cheaper than ever (THE W ORLD BANK, 1998).
Because of the radical reduction of communication costs, rapid narrowing knowledge
gaps and then a surge in economic growth and well-being in developing economies
may be expected. The development of ICT and the accelerated use of ICT in the
5

long-term can contribute to the evolution of the following three paths. 1) the
increasing speed and decreasing cost of developing tools and instruments for basic
research and R&D; 2) the increasing ability to generate technological options; and 3)
the extending power of electronic networks as research tools (OECD, 1996). In this
respect, the realization of a new potential of productivity gains in the process of
generation, distribution and exploitation of knowledge and in the knowledge-based
industries is the major concern of the long-term effects of ICT.

In reality, however, while ICT is pervasive in all sectors of industry and


economic life, it does not seem to have produced the expected rise in productivity in
all the sector of economy, resulting productivity paradox. The productivity paradox,
which refer to the apparent contradiction between the investment on ICT and
industrial productivity, can be easily found in the less developed regions because of
the relatively lower capacity to absorb the investment on ICT for productivity growth,
compared to advanced regions. Furthermore, the investment on ICT may not directly
linked to the improvement of regional productivity in some regions because the ICT
can not be easily applied to region's specialized traditional industries at first to
improve productivity. In addition, the application of ICT stuck to a certain sector such
as high tech and information industries which are not well developed in that region.
In addition, even though the knowledge gaps are decreased with the
development of ICT, developing countries would still be at a disadvantage in the
respect of knowledge about attributes (THE W ORLD BANK, 1998). There are
information problems resulting from the difficulties posed by incomplete knowledge of
attributes such as the quality of product, the creditworthiness of a firm, etc. in addition
to the knowledge gaps in poor countries. For example, financial crises of the East
Asian countries in 1997 were surely related to the incomplete knowledge of attributes
in those countries. Moreover, tacit knowledge is usually sticky in a certain place and
can not be easily transferred across the space, even though the development of ICT
has contributed to the diffusion of information or codified knowledge across the
countries (HIPPEL, 1998; MALMBERG, SOLVELL AND ZANDER, 1996). However, in the
long-term perspectives, the investment and spread of ICT will improve the
productivity even in the traditional sector of industry and in peripheral areas.
Because of the uneven distribution of knowledge in the space and uneven
increase of productivity by sectors and regions, appropriate regional policy with
regard to knowledge-based economy is urgently needed, especially in the less
favored regions. Considering the complexity in creating, acquiring, and using
6

knowledge, more detail examination of the knowledge-based industries and regions


is necessary to understand the process of promoting regional growth.

3 Knowledge, Knowledge-Based Industry and Region

3.1 Knowledge Production Function and Knowledge Spillover

Based on empirical studies, the most important source of new economic knowledge
is considered to be R&D. High degree of human capital, a skilled labor force, and a
high presence of scientists and engineers are included to additional important factors
generating new knowledge. Because of this close link between knowledge inputs and
innovative output, empirical evidence supports more strongly the model of knowledge
production function as the unit of observation becomes increasingly aggregated
(AUDRETSCH, 1999). However, knowledge can be generated by the diverse learning
modes. In some activities, knowledge is accumulated by informal mechanisms, such
as learning-by-doing and learning by interacting with customers and suppliers. While
in others, it is generated by more formalized activities of R&D. Knowledge is
generated not only from firm's internal R&D activities but also from university
research and scientific advances. Because of this diversity of learning modes, if the
model of the knowledge production function is examined at the unit of observation of
the firm, the link between knowledge inputs and innovative outputs become weak or
non-existent (AUDRETSCH, 1999). This weak relationship or no relationship is resulting
from the fact that many firms, especially the small firms, have considerable innovative
outputs in spite of low level of or even no R&D expenditures.

Then where do the innovative small firms or new firms with little or no R&D
expenditure get the knowledge inputs? Recent studies suggest that knowledge
spillover from other firms conducting the R&D or research institutions such as
universities is the major source of the knowledge inputs for those innovative small
firms (AUDRETSCH, 1995; BAPTISTA, 1997; COHEN AND LEVINTHAL, 1989). There are
three major mechanisms for knowledge spillover. First, firms can develop the
capacity to adapt new technology and innovation developed in other firms. Then the
firms can appropriate some of the returns accruing to investments in innovative
outputs made by other firms or research institutions (COHEN AND LEVINTHAL, 1989).
Most of leading large firms in the newly industrializing countries may belong to this
category. Most of the NIEs had considerable benefits from this mechanism of
knowledge-spillover during the rapid industrialization stage
7

Second, inter-firm networks, collaboration with public institutions and


universities can provide synergy effects for participating firms with greater innovative
outputs than expected from the given knowledge inputs. Firms can develop new
ideas and knowledge through interactions with customers and suppliers, workshops
or forums provided by public institutions or universities and can appropriate some of
the returns accruing to the new ideas or knowledge made externally.
Third, knowledge worker may leave the firm or university where the knowledge
was created in order to establish a new firm. If the knowledge worker can pursue the
new idea within the organizational structure of the firm developing the knowledge and
appropriate the expected value of that knowledge, he can continue to work at the
firm. However, if the scientist or engineer places a greater value on his ideas than the
decision-making bureaucracy of the incumbent firm, he may decide to start a new
firm to appropriate the value of his idea (AUDRETSCH, 1999). In this mechanism of
knowledge spillover the knowledge production function is reversed and the
knowledge is exogenous and embodied in a knowledge worker.

There is, in general, spatial limitation in these knowledge spillovers. According


to MALMBERG, SOLVELL AND ZANDER (1996), three elements are involved in the local
creation and accumulation of knowledge and in the sustainability of competitiveness
in the space as follows. First, locally confined innovation processes are favored
because of the trial and error process of problem solving, the repeated interaction
between related firms, and the need to exchange knowledge through face-to-face
contacts. Second, there are barriers to diffusion of locally embedded knowledge to
other areas. The ability to gain access to local informal and formal networks of
knowledge exchange and accumulation is mostly limited to insiders of milieu. Third,
both knowledge resources brought in by outsiders and initiatives taken by
incumbents to tap knowledge resources from outside can enhance the process of
knowledge accumulation within the local milieu. Because of these elements, the
knowledge spillover effects have spatial dimension.

There are some empirical evidences of spatial links in exploiting knowledge


spillover. Some recent studies (AUDRETSCH AND FELDMAN, 1996; FELDMAN, 1994;
JAFFE, 1989) modified the model of knowledge production function to include explicit
specification for the spatial and product dimensions2. The empirical evidences

2
) The model is as follows: I ri = PRD a1 ⋅ (URri ) a 2 ⋅ URri ⋅ (GCri ) a 3 ⋅ eri
where I is innovative output, PRD is private corporate expenditure on R&D, UR is the research
expenditures undertaken at Universities, and GC measures the geographic coincidence between
8

consistently support the notion that knowledge spills over for the use of third party
from university research laboratories as well as firm's R&D laboratories. The
empirical results suggest that proximity to university research labs or industry R&D
labs is important in exploiting knowledge spillover. Especially, the propensity of
innovative activity to cluster geographically tends to be greater in industries where
new economic knowledge plays a more important role such as bio-technology
industry (AUDRETSCH AND FELDMAN, 1996). This finding suggests that industry life
cycle of knowledge-based industry have relationship with spatial location.

3.2 Knowledge-Based Industry and Region

The models of product life cycle and global commodity chains suggest that key
location factors are different by the stage of product life cycle and by the degree of
the importance of new knowledge inputs. The concept of life cycle at the product
level can also be applied to the level of industry. Industries in the early stage of
industry life cycle in which new knowledge inputs are critical factor for the
development of the industries tend to cluster geographically in a few locations. On
the other hand, old industries in which new knowledge is less important than the
earlier stage may tend to disperse with mass production and standardization. For
example, firms in bio-technology, which is an industry based mainly on new
knowledge, tend to cluster in just a handful of locations (PREVENZER, 1997). In the
Newly Industrialized Economies (NIEs), relatively new and knowledge intensive
industries such as computer and medicines are mostly concentrated in a few clusters
(PARK, 1995; PARK AND NAHM, 1998).
Location patterns are also different by the stage of commodity chains of same
industry (GEREFFI AND KORZENIEWIEZ, 1994). Even the old industries like textile and
apparel, early stage of commodity chains may require considerable knowledge
resources and tend to cluster in some areas. For example, development of design or
new materials in these industries is knowledge intensive process and usually
concentrate in major metropolitan areas. Producer services in the commodity chains,
which are mainly regarded as knowledge intensive activities, also tend to concentrate
to major metropolitan areas.

university and corporate research. The unit of observation for estimation is at the spatial level, r, a
state, and industry level, i.
9

Such differences in industrial location by product cycle and commodity chains


reveal that the importance of knowledge as input resources is a critical factor for
patterning industrial location instead of by just sectoral type of industries. That is,
industries or a certain stage of industrial production in the commodity chains in which
the knowledge input is a critical factor are in general clustering in a specific region
rather than decentralizing throughout the space.
Those industries or a certain stage of commodity chain which require
considerable knowledge inputs can be identified as "knowledge-based industry" in
this study. In the knowledge-based industry "new knowledge" is more important
production factor than the traditional production factors of labor, capital and land
inputs. The products of the knowledge-based industries are strongly based on new
techno-scientific knowledge. The knowledge-based industry represents
comparatively high degree of knowledge intensity, measured in terms of the variables
of R&D expenditure, scientists and engineers, and high skilled labor. The locational
pattern of the knowledge-based industry shows, in general, a regional clustering
trend, but may reveal a quite complex pattern by degree of technology intensity or
industry life cycle.

Considering knowledge and technology are important dimension for


development as reviewed in section II, industries/activities can be classified based on
the degree of knowledge and technology as Figure 1. In (Figure 1), knowledge
intensive industries can be identified in two cells. Industries in cell 1 of the (Figure 1)
are highly knowledge-intensive and high technology-based ones, and belong to
typical knowledge-based industry. Innovative activities are very active in this type of
industries. Innovative new industries such as biotechnology and new ICT are the
examples of this type of the knowledge-based industry.

The creation and accumulation of new knowledge is critical for the innovation
activities in these industries. As reviewed in the previous section, the new knowledge
needed for these industry are generated by the strong local networks among firms,
research institutions, and university research labs. Tacit knowledge and codification
of the knowledge are very important for the process of innovation. The innovative
ideas and knowledge are, in general, sticky in local milieu and clustering of this type
of the knowledge-based industries are natural. In order to develop such type of
industries or activities, well development of social capital, learning mechanism and
external economies of scale through networking are required. Advanced high
technology regions such as Silicon Valley are a typical example of the cell 1.
10

(Figure 1) Intensity of knowledge and level of technology in industries

Intensity of knowledge inputs

High Low

(1) Innovative (3) Scale-based


Level of Technology

High

new products products

(2) Product design (4) Scale-based


Low

and low skill products

advanced services

Industries in cell 2 of (Figure 1) are low technology but require intensive


knowledge inputs. High value added craft industries and advanced producer services
such as product design, finance, market research, firm management, coordination,
etc. are belong to this category. Even low technology or traditional sector like textile
or apparel, designing part of the industry belongs to this type. Product design is very
important because new products can be developed continuously. Knowledge is an
important input for product design, firm management, coordination, market research,
finance and other advanced services, and accordingly the industries in this cell can
be regarded as the knowledge-based industry. In some aspect, the activities of firm
management such as functions of headquarter and regional headquarter, market
research, finance, and design are more knowledge intensive than the R&D activities
(ENLIGHT, 2000). This type of the knowledge-based industry can be clustered in
certain part of the large metropolitan areas or in industrial districts. Face-to-face
contacts for exchange of information and tacit knowledge, division of labor, skill
formation in local area, and collaboration and cooperation among firms are important
factors for regional clustering of this type of knowledge-based industry. In the large
metropolitan areas, some clusters of this type of industries/activities can be emerged
in the era of globalization and knowledge-based economy even in the newly
industrializing countries. Along with the globalization, Hong Kong has been
specialized with knowledge intensive activities even though R&D activities are not
strong compared to other newly industrialized economies (ENLIGHT, 2000). Hong
Kong can be regarded as a typical example of cell 2.
11

Industries in cell 3 of (Figure 1) are high technology sector, but belong to


mature stage of industry life cycle and are oriented toward mass production.
Generally these industries decentralized to peripheral areas of industrialized
countries or to newly industrialized countries. Production of electrical appliances such
as TV, refrigerator, air conditions, and so on are the good example of this type of
industries. In the initial stage of the industry life cycle, these industries were mainly
located in industrialized countries. These industries are now matured and
decentralized to the newly industrialized or developing countries because priority is
given to reduction of production costs with severe competition and product
standardization. Development of ICT and globalization of MNE’s production have
contributed to the decentralization of the industries. Even though modern new
technologies are applied for the production in these industries, the production is
relatively standardized with mass production and less required new knowledge.
Accordingly, these industries can not be regarded as the knowledge-based industry.
However, in recent years, application of new knowledge to these mature
industries makes different story. Application of new ICT and new knowledge to these
mature industries provide possibilities of product innovation or improvement and
process innovation. Product improvement and new product development in this
sector in recent years have contributed to growth of certain regions with
agglomeration of the industries, especially in the newly industrialized countries.
Technology catch-up and leapfrogging in these high technology mature industrial
sectors has been successfully performed in some of the newly industrialized
countries such as Korea (LEE AND LIM, 1998). New industrial districts based on the
application of new technology are emerging in the newly industrialized countries
(PARK AND MARKUSEN, 1995; FROMHOLD-ELISEBETH, 1998; W ANG, 1999). In the
process of industrial restructuring of these industries in recent years, there are some
possibility of local creation and accumulation of knowledge in those new industrial
districts. Traditional agglomerated region of these industries has been undergoing
creative destruction and regaining competitive advantages (FLORIDA, 1996). The
changes of these industries in recent years reflect that these scale-based high
technology sectors tend to become the knowledge-based industry in some region
with the application of new knowledge. High tech parks in NIEs such as Kumi in
Korea and Silicon Glen in UK can be regarded as good examples of cell 3.
Industries in cell 4 of (Figure 1) are low technology and scale-based
standardized products. These industries can be regarded as typical traditional mature
industries in which production technology is stabilized and new knowledge input is
not important. Mass production of textile, apparel and shoes in the low cost location
12

are some examples of these industries. However, high value-added products of


textile and apparel, in which new knowledge of design and products are important,
can not be regarded as this type because knowledge input is very important in these
activities. Since priority is given to lowering production cost, the industries
decentralize to areas of low labor cost. In recent years these industries tend to
disperse even to the peripheral areas of developing countries without any specific
agglomeration. This type of industries is no more clustered in the advanced
economies.
In sum, four types of industries or activities examined above are clearly related
with region. It should be noted that two major aspects be found in recent years.
Firstly, types of industries in cell 2 and 3 shows more the tendency to cluster than
before with more emphasis on new knowledge creation and accumulation.
Knowledge spillover effects in local milieu are becoming more important than before
in these industries even though they are weaker than the case of innovative products
in cell 1. Accordingly, those industries of cell 2 and 3 are more shifting toward the
knowledge-based industries along with the development of ICT. Secondly, regions
are dynamically changing with industrial restructuring and industry life cycle.
Industrial clustering can be reemerged in some of the traditional industrial regions
with application and creation of new knowledge on the one hand. Because of the
dynamics, in some large metropolitan areas all the four types of industries or
activities can be found with reemergence of new high tech sector and knowledge
intensive activities along with the traditional specialized industries. Especially in some
of the large metropolitan areas like Chicago, all the four types can coexist (See
chapter of Felsenstein), even though a dominant type of activities/industries will be
advanced over time. On the other hand, new innovation centers can emerge in new
place with a congestion effect of maturing industry in the traditional innovation
centers. The maturing industry in the traditional innovation center may lock-in with
respect to new ideas in the region (AUDRETSCH, 1999). In this maturing industry of the
old innovation center, the congestion refers to intellectual lock-in, contrasting to the
traditional congestion factors with regard to rents, commuting, and pollution.

3.3 Knowledge-Based Economy and New Industry

The evolution of the knowledge-based economy in recent years contributed to the


emergence of new industries and progress of new industrialization. Along with this
new industrialization, new regional motors of growth seem to appear in the modern
industrialized countries. Two major directions of the emergence of new industries and
13

new motors of growth can be identified: one is the expansion and new emergence of
knowledge intensive industries; the other is knowledge intensive service-oriented
industry.

As discussed in the previous section, knowledge input becomes more


important even in the mature industries. This trend of growing the knowledge-based
industries is not limited to the modern industrialized countries. Knowledge-based
industries are expanding even in the newly industrialized and industrializing countries
with the trend of globalization of MNE's activities. The development of ICT has
promoted the globalization and expansion of the knowledge-based industries
(DUNNING, 1998; SOLVELL AND ZANDER, 1998). In the process of expansion of the
knowledge-based industries, the trend of localization or local clustering of the new
industries has been conspicuous. In Europe, this clustering of the knowledge-based
industries are identified as "Islands of Innovation" and about 90% of the Islands of
Innovation are in the old or traditional industrial regions (HILPERT, 1992; 1996). These
clusters of the existing or newly emerged knowledge intensive industries contributed
to the regional growth. In the newly industrialized countries the local clusters of the
industries can be identified as new industrial districts (MARKUSEN, ET. AL, 1999; PARK
AND MARKUSEN, 1995). The new industrial districts are developed by clustering of the
new industries, which are not actually new for the industrialized countries but newly
introduced to the newly industrialized countries. These new industrial districts have
taken a role of regional growth in these countries.

Knowledge inputs are also important in, what we call, the new industries such
as health, tourism/leisure, and culture industries. With the increase of per capita
income, people become more interested in health products and good health services
which are mostly high value added and knowledge-based. Location of health service
centers in good environment contributes to the regional development on the one
hand, development of new health products and production of the products
contributes to the local development on the other hand. Culture and image industries
are also rapidly growing with regional clustering, like agglomeration of Los Angeles
(SCOTT, 1996). Local clustering of these knowledge intensive activities are also
appearing in the newly industrialized and even in the developing countries. The
growth of new industries in recent years is related with the growing importance of
knowledge as input resources. For example, recent growth of health industries is
related with the new scientific knowledge. Recent growth of the culture and image
industries is also mainly based on the integration of ideas, historical knowledge and
modern information technology. Even modern tourism and leisure industry are
changing toward intensive use of knowledge with the development of new tourism
14

goods such as theme tour and ecological tour, which are different from the traditional
sightseeing. The notable evolution of the new industry in the modern industrialized
countries are, therefore, based on the intensive use of new knowledge and expected
to be the next motor of regional growth in some regions in the knowledge-based
economy of this 21st century.

Knowledge is also being more important for service sector in the knowledge-
based economy. Knowledge is a critical factor for producer services such as firm
management and coordination, market research, product design, engineering,
computer software and finance. In recent years many new products are developed
based on new knowledge even in finance sector. The rapid growth of the producer
services in the industrialized countries has been obvious during the last two decades.
Rapid employment growth in the R&D activities, engineering service and computer
software industries are well recognized in the newly industrialized countries as well
as in the modern industrialized countries (MEYER-KRAHMER, 1996; FROMHOLD-
EISEBITH, 1998; WANG, 1998). These activities are mostly clustering in a few regions
and promoting regional economic growth and change (MALECKI AND OINAS, 1998).

4 Policy Directions for Promoting Regional Growth

In the knowledge-based economy, linkage between research and industry is one of


the key elements. It is argued that learning firms in the knowledge-based economy
intends to build non-price competitive advantages from creative use of information
whose cost is rapidly decreasing with the ongoing ICT revolution, contrasting with
"neo-classical" firms which are obsessed by scale and cost and produce
standardized and homogeneous goods (GUINET, 1996). Competitive advantages of
the firms in the knowledge-based economy is not in the low-cost production based on
low-wage employment, but in the production of non-standardized, non-routinized
tradeable goods with generation of high-wage employment. In this context, the
learning firm can be the source of employment and growth in the knowledge-based
economy (GUINET, 1996). The knowledge-based economy, however, does not mean
that all the employment in the society are from the learning firms of the knowledge-
based industries. Employment of low-wages from the "neo-classical" firms is coexist,
but their significance in the economy is reducing and high-wage employment
generated by learning firms become major source of employment and economic
growth in the knowledge-based economy. Such changes require new policy or
strategy for promoting growth in the knowledge-based economy. In this paper,
15

human resources and institution are regarded as the most important factors for the
shift toward the knowledge-based economy and these factors will be more
emphasized in the policy issues.

Key economic activities in the knowledge-based economy are the knowledge


industries and the knowledge-based industries. It is non-disputable that the role of
knowledge and learning firms in these industries are critical. Successful creation,
acquisition, absorption, and accumulation of the knowledge are important for these
industries. Then, ultimately, human resources are the most critical factor for
benefiting from creation, acquisition, absorption, and accumulation of the knowledge.
Accordingly, the government policy in the knowledge-based economy should be
focused on the development of the human resources. R&D activities, inter-firm
networks of customer-supplier relationships, innovative manufacturing and
knowledge-intensive advanced services are constantly increasing the stock of
knowledge that is required for the success of enterprises and promoting regional
growth in the knowledge-based economy.

Government policies in the knowledge-based economy can not replace the


firm as a learning organization, but can create a climate or soft infrastructure that is
favorable for knowledge-based development (HILPERT, 1996). The distribution of
technology and knowledge is uneven over space even though the ICT is prevalent.
Government policy should be more focus on the less favored regions with regard to
knowledge and technology with promoting the diffusion and application of the new
knowledge to the less favored regions. Development of qualified and flexible labor
forces is important and required for the knowledge-based industries. Educational
systems and vocational training systems should be come into meeting these new
demands of the knowledge-based economy, especially in the less favored regions.
Lifelong process of learning should be developed and promoted to practice for both
individuals and enterprises. Training the workforce in technology-related fields
becomes more important for industrial and labor policy in the knowledge-based
economy.
Policy directions regarding the development of human resources, however,
should be different by countries or regions. In the modern industrialized countries,
speeding up change with emphasis on the product innovation and development of
new promising technologies is important for profit gaining. Strategies of strong
networking among firms, universities, and research institutions for collaborative R&D
activities will be important for the regional clustering like cell 1 in the (Figure 1) in the
highly innovative regions. In the old industrial regions or newly industrialized
16

countries, however, application of new technology to mature industries, diffusion of


knowledge, and knowledge spillover are more important for regional development.
Accordingly, skill formation and development of incremental knowledge is more
important for these countries. Strategies for labor training with collaboration of
universities, firms, and trade unions, and local governments are more promising for
the newly industrializing countries. In addition, training system and provision of
infrastructure of ICT in order to reduce the proportion of workers excluded from the
labor market should be emphasized in the newly industrializing countries.
Recent studies have emphasized the importance of institutional factors for the
formation of industrial clustering and innovation in the knowledge-based economy
(GUINET, 1996; STORPER, 1996; 1999; STORPER AND SALAIS, 1997). Institutions are
"persistent and connected sets of rules, formal and informal, that prescribe
behavioral roles, constrain activity. and shape expectations" and overlap with
conventions (Storper, 1996: 265). In order to promote regional growth, in the
knowledge-based economy, institutional reform is required. GUINET (1996: 210)
summarized the main objectives of institutional reform as follows.
 improving the coordination between training and research institutions, or between
training and research functions within any given institutions;
 reinforcing the institutional mechanisms for labor and firm competency
assessment, as a means to increase workers' incentives to learn as well as
financial institutions' propensity to invest in innovation;

 promoting the development of those networks which enable producer/user and


basic research/development interactions;

 improving physical (e.g. information infrastructure) and legal conditions of access


to existing stocks of knowledge;

 stimulating demand for innovative services and products, through the removal of
trade and regulatory obstacles to market access and development; and
 removing structural impediment to technological entrepreneurship.

The directions of the institutional reforms identified above emphasize the


production system-oriented policy rather than the firm-oriented one. Based on these
objectives some of policy directions can be identified, especially for the newly
industrialized or industrializing countries. First, networking between large and small
firms, among large firms and among small firms should be encouraged and
supported (PARK, 1996). Second, industry specific or region-specific labor training
should be provided by public institutions in order to help workers to secure jobs in the
17

face of flexibility in specific, regionally-concentrated sectors (STORPER, 1996). Third,


in order to promote knowledge spillover effects, support for venture business,
technology incubator function, and spin-offs are needed. Fourth, technopoles or
science parks in the newly industrialized countries should be promoted with
emphasis of relations between research and industry, collaborative R&D activities,
and skill formation in order to encourage clusters and regional growth. Lastly, service
centers for providing producer services such as design, software industry, legal,
managerial and marketing services should be developed for successful progress of
the knowledge-based industries.

This paper has not intended to deal with all the policy directions to promote
regional growth in the knowledge-based economy. Rather, the focus is given to the
human resource and institution factors which are regarded as promising factor for
regional growth in the knowledge-based economy. The above directions of
institutional reforms and policy are not independent, but interrelated with each other.
Even though there are some differences in the emphasis of the policy ingredients by
the regions and countries, the basic directions can be commonly applied to the
knowledge-based economy or toward the knowledge-based economy.

5 References

ACS, Z. AND AUDRETSCH, D. (1990): Innovation and Small firms, Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
AUDRETSCH, D. (1995): Innovation and Industry Evolution, Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
AUDRETSCH, D. (1999 (forthcoming)): Knowledge, globalization and regions, in
DUNNING, J. H., ed., Regions, Globalization and the Knowledge-Based
Economy, Oxford University Press.

AUDRETSCH, D. AND FELDMAN, M. (1996): R&D spillovers and the geography of


innovation and production, American Economic Review, 86(4): 253-273.

BAPTISTA, R. (1997): An Empirical Study of Innovation, Entry and Diffusion in


Industrial Clusters, Ph. D. Dissertation, London Business School, University
of London.
BERRY, B. J. R., CONKLING, E. C., AND RAY, D. M. (1997): The Global Economy in
Transition, Second edition, Upper Saddle River, NJ, Prentice Hall.
18

CASTELLS, M. (1996): The Rise of Network Society. The Information Age: Economy,
Society and Culture, Volume 1, Cambridge, Blackwell.
COHEN, W. AND LEVINTHAL, D. (1989): Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D,
Economic Journal, 99(3): 569-596.
DUNNING, J. D. (1998): Globalization, technological change and the spatial
organization of economic activity, in CHANDLER, A. D., HAGSTROM, P. AND
SOLVELL, O., eds., The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy,
Organization, and Regions, Oxford and New York, Oxford University Press:
289-314.

ENLIGHT, M. J. (2000): Globalization, Regionalization, and the Knowledge-based


Economy in Hong Kong, in JOHN DUNNING, ed., Regions, Globalization and
the Knowledge-based Economy, London, Oxford University Press
(forthcoming).

FELSENSTEIN, D. (2000): Promoting Local Growth, London, Ashigate (forthcoming)


FLORIDA, R. (1996): Regional creative destruction: production organization,
globalization, and the economic transformation of the Midwest, Economic
Geography, 72: 314-334.

FREEMAN, C. AND SOETE, L. (1993): Information Technology and Employment,


Universitaire Pers Maastricht.

FROMHOLD-EISEBITH, M. (1999): Bangalore: A network model for innovation-oriented


regional development in NICs, In MALECKI, E. J. AND OINAS, P., eds. (1999):
Making Connections - Technological learning and regional economic change,
Aldershot, Ashgate: 231-260.

GEREFFI, G. AND KORZENIEWIEZ, M. (1994): Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism,


Westport, Connecticut and London, Praeger.

GUINET, J. (1996): Institutional framework conditions for the development of the


knowledge-based economy, In OECD (1996): Employment and Growth in the
Knowledge-based Economy, Paris, OECD: 207-211.

HALAL, W ILLIAM E. (1996): The rise of the knowledge entrepreneur, The Futurist,
November-December 1996: 13-16.

HILPERT, U. (1992): Archipilago Europe -- Islands of Innovation, Brussels, FAST,


Commission of European Communities.
19

HILPERT, U. (1996): The role of the social partners in designing learning


organizations, in OECD, Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-based
Economy, Paris, OECD: 143-156.

HIPPEL, E. (1998): "Sticky information" and the locus of problem solving: implications
for innovation, In CHANDLER, A. D., HAGSTROM, P. AND SOLVELL, O., eds., The
Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, Organization, and
Regions, Oxford and New York, Oxford University Press: 60-77.

JAFFE, A. (1989): Real effects of academic research, American Economic Review,


79: 957-970.

LEE, KEUN AND LIM, CHAISUNG (1998): Technological regimes, catch-yp and
leapfrogging: findings from Korean industries, A paper presented at the 1998
Annual Convention of the Korean Economic Association, Seoul, Korea
MALECKI, E. J. AND OINAS, P., eds. (1999): Making Connections - Technological
learning and regional economic change, Aldershot, Ashigate.
MALMBERG, A., SOLVELL, O. AND ZANDER, I. (1996): Spatial clustering, local
accumulation of knowledge and firm competitiveness, Geografiska Annaler,
78 B (2): 85-97.

MARKUSEN, ET.AL. (1999 (in press)): Second Tier Cities, University of Minnesota
Press.

MEYER-KRAHMER, F. (1996): Dynamics of R&D-intensive sectors and science and


technology policy, In: OECD - Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-
based Economy, Paris, OECD: 213-236.
MILLER, R. (1996): towards the knowledge economy: New institution for human
capital accounting, In OECD - Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-
based Economy, Paris, OECD: 69-80.

OECD (1996): Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-based Economy, Paris,


OECD
PARK, SAM OCK (1995): Seoul, Korea: city and suburb, In: G. L. CLARK AND W. B. KIM,
eds., Asian NIEs and Global Economy, the Johns Hopkins University Press:
147-167.

PARK, SAM OCK (1996): Networks and embeddedness in the dynamic types of new
industrial districts, Progress in Human Geography, 20(4): 476-493.
20

PARK, SAM OCK AND MARKUSEN, ANN (1995): Generalizing new industrial districts: a
theoretical agenda and an application from a non-Western economy,
Environment and Planning A, 27: 81-104.

PARK, SAM OCK AND NAHM, KEE-BOM (1998): Spatial structure and inter-firm networks
of technical and information producer services in Seoul, Korea, Asia Pacific
Viewpoints, 39(2): 209-219.
PREVENZER, M. (1997): The dynamics of industrial clustering in biotechnology, Small
Business Economics, 9(3): 255-271.
SCOTT, A. J. AND SOJA, E. W., eds. (1996): The City, Los Angeles and Urban Theory
at the End of the Twentieth Century, Berkeley, Los Angeles, and London,
University of Californai Press.

SOLVELL, O. AND BIRKINSHAW , J. (1999 (forthcoming)): Multinational enterprises in the


knowledge economy: leveraging global practices, In: DUNNING, J. H., ed.,
Regions, Globalization and the Knowledge-Based Economy, Oxford
University Press.

SOLVELL, O. AND ZANDER, I (1998): International diffusion of knowledge: Isoating


mechanisms and the role of MNE, In: CHANDLER, A. D., HAGSTROM, P. AND
SOLVELL, O., eds., The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy,
Organization, and Regions, Oxford and New York, Oxford University Press:
402-416.
STORPER, M. (1996): Institution of the knowledge-based economy, In: OECD -
Employment and Growth in the Knowledge-based Economy, Paris, OECD:
255- 283.

STORPER, M. (1999 (forthcoming)): Rethinking the economic of globalization: the role


of ideas and conventions, in DUNNING, J. H., ed., Regions, Globalization and
the Knowledge-Based Economy, Oxford University Press.
STORPER, M. AND SALAIS, R. (1997): Worlds of Production: the Action Frameworks of
the Economy, Cambridge, MA., Harvard University Press.

THE W ORLD BANK (1998): Knowledge for Development, World Development Report,
1998/1999, The World Bank.

WANG, JICI (1999): In search of innovativeness: the case of Zhong'guancun, In


MALECKI, E. J. AND OINAS, P., eds. (1999, Making Connections -
Technological learning and regional economic change, Aldershot, Ashigate:
205-230.
21

IWSG Working Papers

10-1999 Harald Bathelt: Technological change and regional restructuring in


Boston’s Route 128 area
12-1999 Johannes Glückler: Management consulting – structure and growth of
a knowledge intensive business service market in Europe
02-2000 Sam Ock Park: Knowledge-based industry and regional growth

You might also like