CM2A_Sept2024_9642771 - Copy
CM2A_Sept2024_9642771 - Copy
Solution:
(i) The assumption implies that the claims occurred in the past does not affect the probability
of the future claims. Each time interval has an independent chance of claims which is only
determined by the Poisson distribution.
(ii) Whether this assumption is reasonable for the insurer depends on the nature of the
insurance which is offered and the risk factors involved.
For some types of insurance such as auto insurance or property insurance, where the
occurrence of 1 claim might not significantly increase the likelihood of another claim in the
near future, Therefore this assumption might be reasonable to some extent.
In cases where there is strong dependence between the future and the past claims, this
assumption might not be reasonable. If the insurer’s actions in the response to the previous
claims affects or influences the future claim behaviour of the insurer, then this assumption
might not be valid. For example: If the insurer rises the premiums highly after the claim, it
may discourage the policyholders from making future claims even though they are legitimate
(iii)
Since N(5) follows a poisson distribution with parameters lambda(5) = 0.25 = 1, we get:
E p =x A × E A + x B × EB
Substituting x_B = 1 – x_A and E_B=4E_A into the var and exp returns equations:
2 2 2
V p=x A × V A + 4 V A −8 x A × V A + 4 x A ×V A + 4 x A ×V A × ρ−4 × x A ×V A × ρ
E p =4 E A−3 x A × E A
E p =4 E A−3 × ( 25 ) × E ¿ 4 E − 65 × E E = 145 × E
A A A p A
(b) ρ=1
2 2 2
V p=5 x A ×V A−4 x A ×V A + 4 V A + 4 × x A × V A −4 × x A × V A¿ x A ×V A + 4 V A
Differentiating with respect to x_A and setting it equal to 0:
dV p
=2 x A ×V A =0 x A=0
d xA
Hence x_B = 1
Substituting these values in expected returns equation:
E p =4 E A−3 × 0 × E A E p =4 E A
(i)
Absolution Risk Aversion:
''
' '' −U ( w ) −2 c
U ( w ) =b+2 cwU ( w )=2 c ARA= ' =
U ( w) b+2 cw
Relative risk aversion:
RRA=−w ×U (w)/U'(w)=-2cw/(b+2cw)
(ii) This implies that they are risk averse. Since the investor requires a higher
probability of winning (p>0.5) in order to accept gamble, it indicates they are
willing to forego some potential gains to avoid the risk of losses.
At p = 0.54167, the investor is indifferent between taking and not taking the
gamble.
0.54167 × U (175 )+ ( 1−0.54167 ) × E (125 )=U ( 150 )Substituting the utility
functions and the values:
0.541675 ( 175 b+30625 c ) +0.45833 × ( 125 b+15625 c )=6750
94.79225 b+ 16572.96875 c+57.29125 b+ 7160.15625 c=6750
152.0835 b+23733.125 c =67500.304167 b+ 0.4746625 c=0.135−−−(2)
Expressing b in c terms from equation (1)
b 3 3
= − c b=30−150 c
100 10 2
Substituting this value in equation (2):
0.304167 × ( 30−150 c ) +0.4746625 c=0.135
9.12501−45.62505 c +0.4746625 c=0.13545.1503875 c=−8.99001c=0.199114
Substituting this value back into the equation for b:
b=30−150 × 0.199114b=0.1335
'
(iv) U ( w ) =b+2 cw> 0
Substituting values of b and c:
0.133+2 × 0.199114× w> 00.3928228 × w>−0.133w >−0.3339
Since wealth cannot be negative, the maximum wealth for which the function
U(w) satisfies the principle of non satiation is infinity.
(v) After winning the gamble , the wealth of the investor increases to 175
(vi) We can expect that the minimum value of p at which the investor will accept the
gamble will now be more than 0.54167. This is mainly because the investor is risk
averse as established earlier . Also wih the increase in wealth they have more to
lose. Also a risk averse investor becomes even more cautious when they have
more to lose.
Hence, they would require a higher probability of winning to compensate for the
increased potential losses
8. Solution:
(i) Bond Price=( 1−PD ) × PV of Nominal at risk free rate+ PD × PV of recovery amount
For zero coupon bond, the recovery amount in case of default = (1-LGD) × Nominal value
(a) Let PD_1 be the prob of default for the 1 year bond
Nominal Value = 100
Recovery amount = (1-0.5)×100 = 50
PV of Nominal at risk free rate = 100×e^(-0.05×1)
PV of recovery amount = 50×e^(-0.05×1)
× [ 100−50 × P D2 ]
−0.05 ×2 −0.05 ×2 −0.1
76.91=( 1−P D2 ) × 100× e + P D2 × 50× e 76.91=e
76.91
−0.1
=100−50 × P D 285=100−50 × P D250 × P D2=15P D2=0.3
e
(b)
(iii) The yields in part (ii) are consistent with the default probabilities in part (i) because:
The 2 year bond has a higher probability of default i.e 30% compared to 1 year bond i.e 20%.
To compensate for this additional risk, 2 year bond offers a higher yield i.e. 13.5% than the
year bond i.e. 15.4% .
This shows that the risk is associated with the higher expected returns. Investors demand a
higher yield for taking on the increased risk of the 2 year bond.
9. Solution:
(i) the insurer may use a utility function with a discontinuity at w = x to represent a minimum
acceptable level of wealth.
(ii)
(iii)
w_0=100
x=90
Claim prob=0.25
Claim amt=50
( )
0.5
100
U ( w )= =10
100
0.75 ×U ¿
0.75((110+p)/100)^0.5 >1
((100+P)/100)^0.5>4/3
(100+P)/100>16/9
100+P>177.78
P>77.78
100+P-50<90
P<40
0.75×((w_0+P)/100)^0.5+0.25×((w_0+P-50)/100)^0.5>1
0.75×(1(100+P)/100)^0.5+0.25×((50+P)/100)^0.5>1
P>39.95
Also:
100+P-50>= 90
P>=40
A high premium can trigger the issue of adverse selction, as only individuals who perceive a
very high risk of claim will be willing to pay such high premium
1. Solution:
R−μ
(i) Let Z= Z N (0 , 1)
σ
t−μ
=−1.64485t−μ=−1.64485 σt=μ−1.64485 σ
σ
Since 95% VaR = -t
95% VaR = 1.64485σ −μ
(ii) 95 % Tail VaR=E [−R|R ←VaR ] Subbstituting the value of VaR in the terms of
the standard normal variable Z:
95 % Tail VaR=E [ −( μ +σZ )|Z ←1.64485 ] =−μ−σE [ Z|Z ←1.64485 ]
−1.64485
E [ Z|Z ←1.64485 ] =
1
(
P ( Z ←1.64485 ) ) ∫
∞
z × f 0 , 1 ( z ) dz
−1.64485
¿ ( ) ∫ −ddz f ( z ) dz
1
0.05 −∞
0 ,1
¿ ( )
−1
0.05
[
−1.64485
f 0 , 1 ( z ) ]−∞ ( 0.05 )
−1
[ f ( −1.64485
0 ,1 ) −0 ] ¿−
f 0 ,1 (−1.64485 )
0.05
Substiting this in tail Var expression:
f 0 ,1 (−1.64485 ) σ
95 % Tail VaR=−μ−σ ×− = × f (−1.64485 )−μ
0.05 0.05 0 ,1
(iii) (a)
95% Var = 1.64485σ −μ
95% VaR=1.64485×0.07746-0.04
95% VaR=0.0851
(b)
σ
95% Tail VaR = × f (−1.64485−μ ) f 0 ,1=0.1031
0.05 0 , 1
95% Tail Var = 0.07746/0.05 ×0.1031 – 0.04
95% Tail Var = 0.1199
(iv) Benefits:
VaR provides a single number that represents the potential loss at a given
confidence level. Hence, it makes easy to understand and communicate
Tail VaR provides information about the expected loss in the worst case
scenarios which is crucial for risk management
Limitations:
VaR only focuses on the threshold loss and do not provide information about
severity of losses beyond point
Tail Var is highly dependent on the assumed distribution of returns,
particularly in the tails, inaccurate assumptions might lead to results which are
very misleading
2. Solution:
PD = N(-d_2)
2
σ
d_2 = (ln(V/F) + (r- ¿ T ¿ /(σ √ T )
2
(i) Company A:
d_2 = (ln(60/50)+(0.03-0.25^2/2)2)/(0.25√ 2 ¿
d_2 = 0.5543
PD_A=N(-0.5543) i.e. approx. 0.29
Company B:
d_2 = (ln(80/50)+(0.03-0.25^2/2)3)/(0.25/√ 3)
d_2 = 1.531
PD_B=N(-1.531) i.e. approx. 0.063
D=V-E
=60000000-12457650
=47542350
Debt value per 100 nominal = (D/F)/100
=(47542350/50000000)*100
=95.08
(iv) The change in share price is significantly larger than the change in debt value
per 100 nominal. This is mainly because the equity holders have a residual
claim on the company’s assets. When the value of the company increases trhe
equity share holders gets benefitted more as they capture the upside potential
after debt holders are paid
4. Solution:
u = 1+0.15=1.15
d=1-0.1=0.9
−r
S0 =e × [ p × S0 ×u+ ( 1−p ) × S 0 × d ]
12
−0.06
× [ 115 p+ 90−90 p ]100=0.995012× [ 25 p+ 90 ]25 p=10.4987
−0.005
100=e 12
× ¿100=e
p=0.41995
T=1:
At t=2:
Up-up=115*1.15=132.25
Up down=115×0.9=103.5
Down down=90×0.9
=81
At t=1
Up-node
r
C u=∆ × S u +B × e 12 115 ∆+1.005012 B=2.99−−−(1)
Down node:
90 ∆+1.005012 B=0−−−(2)
Solving both the equations we get:
B = -10.71
At t=2
(iv)The value of the replicating portfolio at t=0 is approximately 1.23, which is same as the
option value calculated in part (ii)