0% found this document useful (0 votes)
2 views

Lecture2Slides

The document discusses monetary policy, focusing on interest rate policy in a cashless economy and the ineffectiveness of old macroeconomic models. It outlines the relationship between interest rates, inflation expectations, and aggregate output, emphasizing the limitations of traditional models in capturing the effects of policy changes. The lecture also introduces the Taylor rule and critiques the effectiveness of monetary policy through the lens of rational expectations and the Lucas Critique.

Uploaded by

theodore
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
2 views

Lecture2Slides

The document discusses monetary policy, focusing on interest rate policy in a cashless economy and the ineffectiveness of old macroeconomic models. It outlines the relationship between interest rates, inflation expectations, and aggregate output, emphasizing the limitations of traditional models in capturing the effects of policy changes. The lecture also introduces the Taylor rule and critiques the effectiveness of monetary policy through the lens of rational expectations and the Lucas Critique.

Uploaded by

theodore
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 25

Lecture 2 Monetary policy, a little bit

Introduction

Two topics:
▶ Interest rate policy in a cashless economy
⋆ a modern version of the classical dichotomy
⋆ one can talk about policy without the quantity theory
⋆ policy goal: not real effect but stabilize price
▶ An old style macro model
⋆ money is in the model
⋆ policy cannot be systematically stimulative as old style models purport
Interest rate policy in a cashless economy

Outline
▶ real economy in the Arrow-Debreu setup
▶ translate the Arrow-Debreu prices into nominal terms without the
quantity theory
▶ interest rate policy that leads to determinacy
Real economy
The agent’s optimal choice problem

max ∑ β t u(ct )
t≥0

subject to
∑ pt ct = ∑ pt ωt ,
t≥0 t≥0

where pt is the date-t good’s price in the date-0 good’s unit (i.e., the
date-0 good is numeraire andp0 = 1), and ct is the agent’s
consumption of the date-t good
An equilibrium is a sequence of the prices {pt }t≥0 such that the
optimal choice of the agent of the consumption the date-t good is
equal to ωt , all t
We shall have more formal treatment of an infinite-lived agent
decision problem in the future course
Real economy

Here, we know in equilibrium, the consumption of date-t good must


be ωt . But the prices must be right to ensure that the agent does not
choose something different. The condition for price to be right is the
familiar first order condition
pt+1 β u ′ (ωt+1 )
= ; (1)
pt u ′ (ωt )

▶ if the agent cuts the consumption of the date-t good by εt , then he


has unspent wealth pt εt in the date-0 good unit
▶ with this unspent wealth, he can increase his consumption of the
date-t + 1 good by pt εt /pt +1
▶ in order for the agent to not cut the consumption of the date-t good, it
must be that
εt u ′ (ωt ) = (pt εt /pt +1 )β u ′ (ωt +1 ),
which is (1)
Real economy

Let u(c) = lnc. Then (1) becomes

β ωt
pt+1 = pt . (2)
ωt+1

Further let ωt = ω all t. Then the equilibrium is


{pt }t≥0 = {1, β , β 2 , ...}
Translation

There is a central bank


▶ its liability is called money; the unit of money is dollar
▶ if you hold one dollar in whatever forms, then you can claim one dollar
from CB in the form you like (e.g., cash)
▶ central bank issues bonds
⋆ one unit of bonds issued t takes one dollar from you but becomes
(1 + it ) dollars at t + 1
⋆ it is set by the central bank
Translation
Now instead of the date-0 good, money is the numeraire
Moreover, instead of the Arrow-Debru style of trade, the agent trades
sequentially, i.e., each t he sells and buys the date-t good on the
date-t market
The agent’s optimal choice problem
max ∑ β t u(ct )
t≥0

subject to
Mt+1 + Bt+1 + Pt ct = Pt ωt + Mt + (1 + it−1 )Bt all t
where Pt is the nominal price date-t good in the date-t market,
good’s unit, Mt is the amount of money the agent holds at the start of t,
Bt is the amount of bonds the agent holds at the start of t, and
M0 = B0 = 0.
An equilibrium is a sequence of the prices {Pt }t≥0 such that the
optimal choice of the agent of the consumption the date-t good is
equal to ωt , all t
Translation
Again, we know in equilibrium, the consumption of date-t good must
be ωt . But the prices must be right to ensure that the agent does not
choose something different. The condition for price to be right is

Pt (1 + it ) ′
u ′ (ωt ) = β Et u (ωt+1 ); (3)
Pt+1

▶ the expectation term Et appears because Pt +1 may not be determinate


(but the agent knows its objective distribution and so can form the
expectation based on the information available in date t)
▶ if the agent cuts the consumption of the date-t good by εt , then he
has Pt εt more dollars in date t
▶ he can buy bonds this amount of dollar and increase his consumption
of the date-t + 1 good by (1 + it )Pt εt /pt +1
▶ in order for the agent to not cut the consumption of the date-t good, it
must be that

εt u ′ (ωt ) = Et ((1 + it )Pt εt /Pt +1 )β u ′ (ωt +1 )


Translation

Let u(c) = lnc and ωt = ω all t. Then (3) becomes

1 1
1 + it = [Et ]−1 , (4)
β 1 + πt+1

where 1 + πt+1 = Pt+1 /Pt is the gross inflation rate.


If inflation is fixed at zero, then
1
1 + it = . (5)
β
Translation

But fixing the nominal interest rate by (5) can only fix

1
Et
1 + πt+1

at unity but cannot fixed πt+1 at 0


▶ there are many objective random variables xt +1 satisfying
1
Et =1 (6)
1 + xt +1
▶ when the agent picks such a random variable xt +1 at t and expects
that the realization of xt +1 is the inflation at t + 1, his expectation is
rational
The Taylor rule
Now suppose that when the agent picks a random xt+1 to form his
inflation expectation, all realizations of xt+1 are around zero so (3)
can be approximated by the familiar Fisher equation

it = r + Et πt+1 , (7)

where r = 1/β − 1
The Taylor rule
it = φ πt + ρ. (8)
▶ The Taylor principle: coefficient φ > 1
▶ ρ a parameter
It follows from the Fisher equation and the Taylor rule that

πt = φ −1 [Et πt+1 + (r − ρ)] (9)

so
πt = ∑ φ −(s+1) (r − ρ) (10)
s≥0
Policy ineffectiveness in an old style model

Efforts have been made to build models in which


▶ policy in general and monetary policy in specific are effective in the
short run
Those models were popular and influential
But they have been abandoned
▶ Reasons? To be discussed here
Three equations
y : log aggregate output
y : log price level
m: log money stock
i: one-period nominal rate of interest
IS equation

yt = a0 + a1 (it − πte |t−1 ) + v1t , a1 < 0, (11)

LM equation

mt − pt = c0 + c1 yt + c2 it + v2t , c2 < 0 < c1 , (12)

Friedman-Phelps natural-rate aggregate supply function (AS)

yt = γ0 + γ1 (pt − pte |t−1 ) + γ2 yt−1 + ut , γ1 > 0, 1 > γ2 ≥ 0. (13)


Three equations

πte |t−1 : date-t-1 expectation of private agents regarding inflation


between t and t+1
pte |t−1 : date-t-1 expectation regarding the date-t price level
v1t , v2t , and ut are i.i.d. random variables
▶ unsystematic and unpredictable factors in economy
AS: output supply affected by price only when price differs from its
expected value
Rational expectations

Rational expectations:
e
xt+j |t−1 = Et−1 xt+j

for j ≥ 0,
▶ Et−1 xt +j is mathematical expectation of xt +j computed according to
⋆ equations of the model
⋆ values of all variables in the model realized in periods t-1 and earlier
RE

With RE, (11) becomes

yt = a0 + a1 [it − Et−1 (pt+1 − pt )] + v1t , a1 < 0, (14)

And (13) becomes

yt = γ0 + γ1 (pt − Et−1 pt ) + γ2 yt−1 + ut , γ1 > 0, 1 > γ2 ≥ 0. (15)


Policy

Monetary authority follows a rule


▶ relates target value of m or i to past values of variables in the model
(e.g., yt−1 , pt−2 )
A money-supply rule targets m; suppose the rule is

mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + µ2 yt−1 + et , (16)

▶ et is i.i.d., mean zero, constant variance: policy error


▶ et independent of structural disturbances v1t , v2t , and ut .
Aggregate Demand Function

Eliminate it from IS (14) and LM(12) to get aggregate demand


function

yt = β0 + β1 (mt − pt ) + β2 Et−1 (pt+1 − pt ) + vt , (17)

where

β0 = (a0 c2 − a1 c0 )/(a1 c1 + c2 ),
β1 = a1 /(a1 c1 + c2 ) > 0,
β2 = −a1 c2 /(a1 c1 + c2 ) > 0,
vt = (c2 v2t − a1 v1t )/(a1 c1 + c2 ).
Equilibrium

Let yt in (17) be equated to yt in (15);

1
pt = [(β0 − γ0 ) + β1 mt + γ1 Et−1 pt − γ2 yt−1 (18)
γ1 + β1
+β2 Et−1 (pt+1 − pt ) + vt − ut ]

▶ this determines “equilibrium” price


Policy ineffectiveness
Applying Et−1 (.) to (18),

1
Et−1 pt = [(β0 − γ0 ) + β1 Et−1 mt + γ1 Et−1 Et−1 pt − γ2 yt−1
γ1 + β1
+β2 Et−1 Et−1 (pt+1 − pt ) + Et−1 (vt − ut )];

simplifying,
1
Et−1 pt = [(β0 − γ0 ) + β1 Et−1 mt + γ1 Et−1 pt − γ2 yt−1
γ1 + β1
+β2 Et−1 (pt+1 − pt )];

and subtracting,
1
pt − Et−1 pt = [β1 (mt − Et−1 mt ) + (vt − ut )]. (19)
γ1 + β1
Policy ineffectiveness
Applying Et−1 (.) to (16),

Et−1 mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + µ2 yt−1 + Et−1 et ;

simplifying,
Et−1 mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + µ2 yt−1 ;
and subtracting,
mt − Et−1 mt = e t . (20)
Substituting (20) into (19),

1
pt − Et−1 pt = [β1 (mt − Et−1 mt ) + vt − ut ] (21)
γ1 + β1
1
= [β1 et + vt − ut ].
γ1 + β1
Policy ineffectiveness

Substituting (21) into AS (15),

γ1 vt + β1 ut + γ1 β1 et
yt = γ0 + γ2 yt−1 + . (22)
γ1 + β1

In (22), equilibrium yt influenced only by


▶ disturbances vt , ut , et and
▶ non-policy parameters γ0 , γ1 , γ2 , β1 = a1 /(a1 c1 + c2 )
▶ NOT by µs in policy rule (16)
The Lucas Critique
Combining policy rule (16) and equilibrium output function (22) (to
eliminate et ),

yt = φ0 + φ1 yt−1 + φ2 mt + φ3 mt−1 + ξt , (23)

where

φ = γ1 β1 (γ1 + β1 ),
φ0 = γ0 − µ0 φ , φ1 = γ1 − µ1 φ , φ2 = φ , φ3 = −µ1 φ ,
ξt = φ [(ut /γ1 ) + (vt /β1 )].

Suppose monetary authority follows policy rule (16) in history.


Econometricians can estimate φ0 , φ1 , φ2 , and φ3 accurately
▶ φ2 > 0
▶ So increasing µs in policy rule (16) can increase output?
The Lucas Critique

The φ parameters in (23) are estimated when µs are fixed


When µs change, φ will change

You might also like