Principles of Economics_shared
Principles of Economics_shared
C.Unemployment rises.
Scarcity
Economic Goods
Choices
Opportunity Cost
Is there any such thing as free Lunch?
The expression “there’s no such thing as a free lunch”
clarifies the relationship between scarcity and
opportunity cost.
Application: The Cost of Military Spending
The war in Iraq cost the United States an estimated $1
trillion. Each $100 billion could:
Enroll 13 million preschool children in the Head Start program
for one year.
Hire 1.8 million additional teachers for one year.
Immunize all the children in less-developed countries for the
next 33 years.
The true cost of the war was its opportunity cost: what the United
States sacrificed for it.
Marginal Thinking
Individual decisions are rarely straight-forward and usually involve
weighing of costs and benefits to achieve maximum results.
Economist emphasize marginal thinking when the focus is on
additional or marginal choices.
Marginal choices involve the effects of adding or subtracting from
the current situation.
Marginal Change: describe small incremental adjustments to an
existing plan of action.
Thinking at the margin can be seen as the basic rule of rational
behaviour.
Incentives Matter
Individuals always wish to be better off today than they
were yesterday.
As such they respond to changes in incentives.
Economics can therefore be reduced to incentive Marginal
Benefit vs. Marginal Cost.
Both consumers and producers are driven by incentives that
affects their expected cost or benefits.
Economic System
Because of scarcity, certain economic questions must
be answered regardless of the level of affluence of
the society or its political structure.
The way resources are allocated has a lot to do with
the economic system being operated
Economic System
Limited Resources Unlimited Wants and Needs
Scarcity
Higher Investment,
Greater Economic Lower Investment, less
Growth Economic Growth
Kg
0 Cg
It is important to remember that increases in a
Cocoa society's output do not make scarcity disappear.
A’
B’
15 A
B C’
14
12 C
D
D ’
9
Q E E’
5
F F’
0 1 2 3 4 5 Rice
Application 1: Don’t Forget the Costs of Time and Invested
Suppose you go into the
application development
business. It takes you 1,000
hours to develop the
application and requires
using a GH¢30,000 computer
setup for half a year.
What is the true cost of
developing the app?
Application 1: Don’t Forget the Costs of Time and Invested Funds
Value the 1,000 hours at your
hourly wage; perhaps GH¢84 per
hour, hence GH¢84,000.
For the computer setup, you must
devote GH¢30,000 in funds for six
months; at 6 percent interest per
year, this costs GHS¢1,800.
Technological Change & Growth
Technological advance does not have to impact all
sectors of the economy equally.
There is a technological advance in food production but
not in housing production.
The technological advance in agriculture causes the
production possibilities curve to extend out further on
the horizontal axis which measures food production
Cocoa
A
15
B’
14
B
C’
12 C
D D’
9
Q E E’
5
F F’
Rice
0 1 2 3 4 5
Growth, Scarcity, Efficiency and Equity.
Does economic growth imply the absence of
scarcity?
What is meant by equity?
What is meant by efficiency?
Q.Which of the ff would shift the PPF outwards?
A. An increase in the population of
working age
B. A reduction in unemployment
C. A reduction in VAT
D. An increase in the general level of
prices
E. A reduction in expenditure on
education
Economics in Practice
Trade-Offs among the Rich and Poor
In all societies, for all people, resources are
limited relative to people’s demands.
In 1990, the World Bank defined the extremely
poor people of the world as those earning less
than $1 a day.
Even for the poorest consumers, biological need
is not all determining. So even in extremely poor
societies, household choice plays a role.
CRITICAL THINKING
1. Why might we see a greater demand for festivals in poor countries than in rich ones?
How might this be affected by choices available?
Economics and Global Issues
Economics and global issues
COVID-19 and the global health emergency
effects on individuals
changes in buying patterns
the issue of choice of whether to be vaccinated and effects
on other people
effects on firms
costs, revenues and profit: many made a loss
move to online
Economics and global issues
COVID-19 and the global health emergency
effects on employment and wages
some were laid-off; others working online
effects on economic growth: a fall in GDP
support by government and effects on borrowing
support by central banks: creating money
Economics and global issues
The environment and the global climate
emergency
people’s actions affect others: spillover effects
many firms emit CO2 in production
consumers emit CO2 when they use fossil fuels
importance of prices and incentives
use of green taxes and subsidies
carbon trading
Economics and global issues
The environment and the global climate emergency
the issue of fairness: winners and losers
fairness between individuals, generations and nations
international action to curb emissions and destruction
of carbon sinks
getting international agreements: problem of ‘game playing’
does free trade benefit the environment?
Theory of Demand and Supply
What is Demand?
Demand is the amount of a good/service that
individuals/consumers are willing and able to
purchase at each possible price during a given period of
time.
The quantity demanded is the amount of a product that
people are willing and able to purchase at one specific
price.
Components of the Definition
1. Price/quantity relationship-price is the most important
determinant of quantity
2. Ready, Willing and Able-this defines the market
Ready-in the market; Willing-desires the good; Able-has the wherewithal/ability
3. Per unit of time-Time must be specified as it reflects diminishing
marginal utility
4. Other things Constant-A number of things aside from price
effect
5. Downward-Sloping due to diminishing MU (fullness)-This is the
reason why there is an inverse relationship between price and
quantity.
Demand Schedule
Demand curve:
a curve showing the relation
between the price of a good
and quantity demanded
during a given period, other
things constant.
Suppose we are making pizza.
Law of Demand
States that a quantity of a good demanded during a
given period relates inversely to its price, other things
constant.
Price increases ➔ Quantity Demanded decreases
Price decreases ➔ Quantity demanded increases
Creates a downward sloping demand curve
Why the Law of Demand?
Substitution Effect
Unlimited wants/scarce resources
When the price of a good falls, consumers substitute that good
for other goods, which become relatively more expensive.
Reverse also holds true
Income Effect
Money income: is simply the amount of Cedis received per
period
Real income: your income measured in terms of what it can buy.
A fall in the price of a good increases consumers’ real income
making consumers more able to purchase goods; for a normal
good, the quantity demanded increases.
Application 1: Young Smokers and the Law of Demand
As price decreases, the quantity
of cigarettes demanded
increases for two reasons:
People who already smoke, choose
to smoke more; and
Some (mostly young) people
start smoking.
Keeping cigarette prices high,
or increasing them with taxes, is
one way that governments try to
discourage young people from
starting smoking.
Demand Curve
P
GH₵12
A curve showing the relation
GH₵10
between the price of a good
GH₵7 and the quantity demanded.
GH₵4
GH₵2
0 Q
45 100 130 180 200
Shifts in Demand versus Movements Along a Demand Curve
Demand refers to a schedule of quantities of a good that
will be bought per unit of time at various prices, other
things constant.
Graphically, it refers to the entire demand curve.
Quantity demanded refers to a specific amount that will
be demand per unit of time at a specific price.
Graphically, it refers to a specific point on the demand
curve.
Shifts in Demand versus Movements Along a Demand Curve
A movement along a demand curve is the graphical
representation of the effect of a change in price on the
quantity demanded.
A shift in demand is the graphical representation of the
effect of anything other than price on demand.
Movement along the Demand Curve
Price
B
GH₵6
GH₵5 A
Demand
0
75 100 Quantity
A shift (change) in the demand curve
A graphical representation of the effect of changes in other
determinants of demand rather than changes in a commodity’s
own price. And these factors are
Consumer’s income
Price of other related commodities
Taste and preference of the consumer
Consumers’ expectation of future prices
Season and weather
Types of Goods Demanded
Complementary goods: Two goods are known as complements
when they are jointly consumed or demanded. With complementary
goods as quantity demand for one increases, quantity demanded for
the other increases as well. A change in the price of one good
affect not only the quantity demanded of that good but also the
quantity demanded of its complement. For example, Car and petrol
are jointly demanded. Also tennis and racket are jointly demanded.
Usually in a demand equation, the coefficient of the prices of
complementary goods carry the same signs.
Types of Goods Demanded
Substitute goods: Two goods are known as substitute goods if the
two goods satisfy the same or similar needs or desires. With
substitutes goods, as the quantity demanded for one increases,
demand for the other decreases. A rise in the price of one goods
increases quantity demanded of the other because it becomes
relatively cheaper to buy than the other. These goods could be close
substitutes or perfect substitutes. Example, Coca Cola and Pepsi
are substitute goods.
Usually in a demand equation, the coefficient of the prices of
substitutes goods carry different signs.
Types of Goods Demanded
Normal good refers to any good whose quantity demanded changes
in the same direction with a given change in income. That is, as
income rises, quantity demanded rises and vice versa. Example of a
normal good is ‘good food’. Usually in a demand equation, the
coefficient of the income variable is positive.
Inferior goods refers to goods for which less is demanded as
income rises. They are inversely related to income. Usually in a
demand equation, the coefficient of the income variable is negative
Types of Goods Demanded
Neutral goods refers to goods whose demand do not change as
income change. Example salt.
Giffen goods refer to goods whose quantity demanded increases as
price increases and vice-versa. Giffen goods have an upward
sloping demand curve.
Number of Price of Related
Buyers Goods
Determinants of Quality
Income Demand
Price
GH₵1
D2
D1
Quantity
75 100
Market vs Individual Demand
It is the sum of the individual demand for a product from
buyers in the market.
If more buyers enter the market and they have the ability to pay
for items on sale, then market demand at each price level will
rise
15 15 15
10
+ 10
= 10
D2
D1 DM
4 5 2 8 6 13
Demand Function
The function describes how much of a good will be purchased
at different prices taking into consideration other
determinants of demand.
𝐐𝐝𝐱 = 𝐟(𝐏𝐱 , 𝐏𝐲 , 𝐌, 𝐓, 𝐇)
𝐐𝐝𝐱 = 𝛂𝟎 + 𝛂𝟏 𝐏𝐱 , +𝛂𝟐 𝐏𝐲 , +𝛂𝟑 𝐌, +𝛂𝟒 𝐓, +𝛂𝟓 𝐇
Demand Function
Example
An economic consultant for Microsoft Corporation recently
provided the firm’s marketing manager with this estimate of
the demand function for the firm’s product:
𝐐𝐝𝐱 = 𝟏𝟐𝟎𝟎 − 𝟑𝐏𝐱 + 𝟒𝐏𝐲 + 𝐌 + 𝟐𝐀 𝐱
Where 𝐐𝐝𝐱 represents the amount consumed of good X, 𝐏𝐱 is the
price of good X, 𝐏𝐲 is the price of good Y, M is income and 𝐀 𝐱
represents the amount of advertising spent on good X.
Demand Function cont’d
Example cont’d
Suppose good X sells for GH¢20 per unit, good Y sells for GH¢15
per unit, the company utilizes 2,000 units of advertising, and
consumer income is GH¢10,000.
a. How much of good X do consumers purchase?
b. Are goods X and Y substitutes or complements?
c. Is good X a normal or inferior good?
Derived demand Competitive
demand
Types of
Demand
Types of
Demand
CRITICAL THINKING
1. Economists predict that my interest in purchasing a convertible also depends
on how much I think other people like convertibles. How is this prediction
related to the durability of cars?
Supply
GH₵3 50 6
GH₵4 75
GH₵5 100 5
GH₵6 150
GH₵7 200 Quantity
Individual Supply Curve
A curve which shows the Price Supply
various quantities of a
given commodity which an 6
individual producer is
willing to supply at
different prices at given 5
period of time.
Quantity
Market Supply Curve
It is curve which shows the various quantities of a
commodity which all producers are willing to produce
and sell at different prices at a given period of time.
Price Supply Price Price
Supply Supply
6
6 6
5
5 5
16 25 Quantity 36 55 Quantity
20 30 Quantity
Why Is the Market Supply Curve Positively Sloped?
There are two reasons why the market supply curve is positively
sloped. As the market price increases,
1. Individual firms increase output by purchasing more materials
and hiring more workers; and
2. New firms enter the market, encouraged by the higher price.
As with the individual supply curve, the market supply curve shows
the marginal cost of production, this time for the market as a whole.
Change in Quantity Supplied
Movement along the supply Price
Supply
curve is caused by changes in
the price of the commodity
when all other factors are held
constant. GH₵6
B
SUPPLY PRODUCER
COST OF INPUTS DETERMINANTS EXPECTATIONS
NUMBER OF GOVERNMENT
PRODUCERS POLICY
The supply Function
The supply function of a good describes how much of the good
will be produced at alternative prices of the good, alternative
prices of inputs, and alternative values of other variables that
affect supply.
The supply function of a good say X can be written as:
𝐐𝐬𝐱 = 𝐟 𝐏𝐱 , 𝐏𝐫 , 𝐖, 𝐇
Where 𝐏𝐱 is the price of the good, 𝐏𝐫 is the price of
technologically related goods, W is the price of an input and H
is the value of some other variable that affects supply (such as
existing technology, the number of firms in the market, taxes,
or producer expectations).
Market Equilibrium: Bringing Demand and Supply Together
A market is an arrangement that brings buyers and sellers
together. These buyers and sellers jointly determine prices
and quantities traded.
Market equilibrium: A situation in which the quantity
demanded equals the quantity supplied at the prevailing
market price.
When a market is in equilibrium, there is no pressure on
the price to change.
Market Equilibrium
At specific price where:
Quantity demanded = Quantity supplied
Equilibrium price –
market clearing price
Equilibrium quantity –
𝑸𝑫 = 𝑸𝑺
The price in a competitive market is determined by the
interactions of all buyers and sellers in the market.
Market Equilibrium
At specific price where: P
Quantity demanded S
Equals
Quantity Supplied GH₵5 Equilibrium
Q
150
(The Walrasian Price Adjustment)
P
D S
Surplus
PH
Pe
PL
Shortage
S D
Q0 Qe Q2 Q
(The Marshallian Quantity Adjustment)
Under the Marshallian adjustment, a difference between what
consumers are willing to pay and what producers require to cover
at least their cost of production sets up incentives for economic
agents to alter output levels
Since P1 (what the consumer is willing to
pay) exceeds their MC, they are willing to
supply more, hence supply increases
P
D S
P1
PS 1
Q1 Qe Q2 Q
(Is there a Unique Equilibrium)
A unique equilibrium exist when there is just one single
equilibrium position.
Such equilibrium is said to be stable when it can only at one
point.
i.e. when in disequilibrium, forces tend to move price and
quantity back towards equilibrium
Veblen effect – this implies that the high price is the reason for
buying it for the status it confers on the purchaser
W S
D PRICE
We2
P2 D
E2
We1
P1 E1
S
D
D 0
Q1 Q2 QUANTITY
Le2 Le1 L
EFFECTS OF CHANGES IN DEMAND AND SUPPLY ON EQUILIBRIUM
Shift in Demand Curve Shift in Supply Curve
P D1 S
P S1
D S
D
P1
P0
P0
P1
D1
S D S D
Q0 Q1 Q2 Q S1
Q0 Q1 Q2 Q
SIMULTANEOUS INCREASE IN BOTH DEMAND AND SUPPLY
P D1 P S
D1 S1
D S D
S1
P0 P0
P1
D1 D1
S D S D
Q0 Q1 Q Q0 Q1 Q
SIMULTANEOUS INCREASE IN BOTH DEMAND
AND SUPPLY
D1
P S
S1
D
P1
P0
D1
S S1 D
Q0 Q1 Q
Increase In Demand But A Decrease In Supply
S1
S1 S
P P D1
D1
D S D
P1
P1
P0 P0
D1 D1
S D S D
Q0 Q Q1 Q0 Q
Increase In Demand But A Decrease In Supply
D1 S1
P
D S
P1
P0
D1
S D
Q0 Q 1 Q
Equilibrium using Algebra
𝑮𝒊𝒗𝒆𝒏 𝒕𝒉𝒆 𝒅𝒆𝒎𝒂𝒏𝒅 𝒇𝒖𝒏𝒄𝒕𝒊𝒐𝒏 𝒐𝒇 𝒕𝒉𝒆 𝒇𝒐𝒓𝒎
𝑸𝒅 = 𝒂 − 𝒃𝑷
And the supply function given as
𝑸𝒔 = −𝒄 + 𝒅𝑷
Determine equilibrium price and quantity
Solution
Set the equilibrium condition
In equilibrium 𝑸𝒅 = 𝑸𝒔 = 𝑸
𝒂 − 𝒃𝑷 = −𝒄 + 𝒅𝑷
Grouping like terms
Equilibrium using Algebra
Solution cont’d
Grouping like terms 𝒂 + 𝒄 = 𝒃𝑷 + 𝒅𝑷
Factor out the P so that we obtain
𝒂 + 𝒄 = (𝒃 + 𝒅)𝑷 and then divide both sides by b + d
Which leads us to
𝒂+𝒄
𝑷= − 𝑬𝒒𝒖𝒊𝒍𝒊𝒃𝒓𝒊𝒖𝒎 𝒑𝒓𝒊𝒄𝒆
𝒃+𝒅
To determine the equilibrium quantity, put the equilibrium price
into either the demand or supply function
Equilibrium using Algebra
Solution cont’d
Substituting the equilibrium price into the demand function, we obtain;
𝒂+𝒄
𝑸=𝒂−𝒃
𝒃+𝒅
𝒂𝒃 − 𝒃𝒄 𝒂 𝒃 + 𝒅 − 𝒂𝒃 − 𝒃𝒄 𝒂𝒃 + 𝒂𝒅 − 𝒂𝒃 − 𝒃𝒄 𝒂𝒅 − 𝒃𝒄
=𝒂− = = =
𝒃+𝒅 𝒃+𝒅 𝒃+𝒅 𝒃+𝒅
Therefore, the equilibrium quantity is given by
𝒂𝒅 − 𝒃𝒄
𝑸= − −𝑬𝒒𝒖𝒊𝒍𝒊𝒃𝒓𝒊𝒖𝒎 𝒒𝒖𝒂𝒏𝒕𝒊𝒕𝒚
𝒃+𝒅
Market Equilibrium
Using Algebra to Find the Equilibrium
D and S Curves: 𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟔𝟎– 𝟒𝟎𝒑 and 𝑸𝒔 = 𝟓𝟎 + 𝟏𝟓𝒑
We want to find the p at which Qd = Qs = Q, the
equilibrium quantity.
In equilibrium, it must be that Qs = Qd.
In Equilibrium, 𝟏𝟔𝟎 – 𝟒𝟎𝒑 = 𝟓𝟎 + 𝟏𝟓𝒑
We can obtain the same result if we use the D curve.
Market Equilibrium
Using Algebra to Find the Equilibrium
We use algebra to find the equilibrium price:
𝟓𝟓𝒑 = 𝟏𝟏𝟎, so 𝒑 ∗ = 𝑮𝑯𝑺𝟐
We can determine the equilibrium q by substituting this
p into either Qd or Qs.
Using the S Curve: 𝑸 ∗= 𝟓𝟎 + (𝟏𝟓 × 𝟐) = 𝟖𝟎
We find that the equilibrium quantity is 80 million lbs per
month.
ELASTICITIES
Elasticities
If a rock band increases the price it charges for
concert tickets, what impact will that have on
ticket sales?
More precisely, will ticket sales fall a little or a
lot?
Will the band make more money by lowering the
price or by raising the price?
Elasticities
The law of demand establishes that quantity
demanded changes inversely with changes in price,
ceteris paribus.
But how much does quantity demanded change?
This is very important to understand for many
economic issues.
This is what the price elasticity of demand is
designed to answer.
Elasticities
Think of price elasticity like an elastic rubber band.
When small price changes greatly affect, or “stretch,”
quantity demanded, the demand is elastic, much like
a very stretchy rubber band.
When large price changes can’t “stretch” demand,
however, then demand is inelastic, more like a very
stiff rubber band.
Elasticities
The price elasticity of demand measures how responsive quantity
demanded is to a price change.
The price elasticity of demand is defined as the percentage change
in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price.
∆𝑸
𝐏𝐞𝐫𝐜𝐞𝐧𝐭𝐚𝐠𝐞 𝐜𝐡𝐚𝐧𝐠𝐞 𝐢𝐧 𝐪𝐮𝐚𝐧𝐭𝐢𝐭𝐲 𝐝𝐞𝐦𝐚𝐧𝐝𝐞𝐝 𝑸
𝐏𝐄𝐃 = =
𝐏𝐞𝐫𝐜𝐞𝐧𝐭𝐚𝐠𝐞 𝐜𝐡𝐚𝐧𝐠𝐞 𝐢𝐧 𝐩𝐫𝐢𝐜𝐞 ∆𝑷
∆𝑸 ∆𝑷 ∆𝑸 𝑷 𝚫𝐐 𝐏 𝑷
= ÷ = × 𝐨𝐫 𝐏𝐄𝐃 = ×
𝑸 𝑷 𝑸 ∆𝑷 𝚫𝐏 𝐐
Elasticities
Good A Original New % Change Elasticity
Good B
Price 5 6 20%
Elasticities
Inelastic demand when 𝐞𝐩 <
𝟏
Fairly elastic when 𝐞𝐩 > 𝟏
Unitary elastic demand when
𝐞𝐩 = 𝟏
Perfectly inelastic demand
when 𝐞𝐩 = 𝟎
Infinitely elastic demand
when 𝐞𝐩 = ∞
Graphical Illustration of Point Elasticity of Demand
A
P1
𝜟𝑷
P2 B
C
𝜟𝑸
0 Q1 Q2 D’ Q
𝚫𝐏 = 𝐂𝐀; 𝚫𝐐 = 𝐂𝐁, ; 𝐏 = 𝐐𝟏 𝐀; 𝐐 = 𝟎𝐐𝟏
𝚫𝐐 𝐏
𝐛𝐮𝐭 𝐞𝐩 = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐
𝐂𝐁 𝐐𝟏 𝐀
⇒ 𝐞𝐩 = ×
𝐂𝐀 𝟎𝐐𝟏
𝐂𝐁
The first term in the equation = reciprocal of the
𝐂𝐀
slope of the straight line –DD’
𝐂𝐁
Straight line has a constant slope, hence the value of is
𝐂𝐀
the same at any point on the demand curve
Graphical Illustration of Point Elasticity of Demand
𝐐𝟏 𝐀
The second term - thus the price-quantity ratio-are
𝟎𝐐𝟏
𝟎
coordinates of poi (l intercept (D’)- =𝟎
𝟎𝐃′
Thus the numerical value of the price-quantity ratios varies
from infinity to zero. The value of 𝐞𝐩 thus depends on the
point on the demand curve
P 𝒆𝒑 = ∞
𝒆𝒑 > 𝟏
𝒆𝒑 = 𝟏
𝒆𝒑 < 𝟏
𝒆𝒑 =0
0 Q
𝐏
Illustration
𝟕𝟎 𝑩
∆𝑸
𝑫
𝟎 𝟏, 𝟓𝟎𝟎 𝟐, 𝟏𝟎𝟎 𝑸
Illustration
Solution
1. Price elasticity of demand from point A to B
∆𝑸 𝑷 𝟐, 𝟏𝟎𝟎 − 𝟏, 𝟓𝟎𝟎 𝟏𝟎𝟎 𝟔𝟎𝟎 𝟏 𝟔𝟎𝟎
𝜺𝑨→𝑩 = × = × = × =
∆𝑷 𝑸 𝟕𝟎 − 𝟏𝟎𝟎 𝟏. 𝟓𝟎𝟎 −𝟑𝟎 𝟏𝟓 −𝟒𝟓𝟎
= −𝟏. 𝟑𝟑
2. Price elasticity of demand from point B to A
∆𝑸 𝑷 𝟏, 𝟓𝟎𝟎 − 𝟐, 𝟏𝟎𝟎 𝟕𝟎
𝜺𝑩→𝑨 = × = × = −𝟎. 𝟔𝟕
∆𝑷 𝑸 𝟏𝟎𝟎 − 𝟕𝟎 𝟐, 𝟏𝟎𝟎
ARC Elasticity
Used when price changes are relatively high.
𝐏𝟏 + 𝐏𝟐 ൗ
𝚫𝐐 𝟐
𝐞𝐩(𝐚𝐫𝐜) = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐𝟏 + 𝐐𝟐 ൗ
𝟐
𝚫𝐐 𝐏𝟏 +𝐏𝟐 𝟐
𝐞𝐩(𝐚𝐫𝐜) = × ×
𝚫𝐏 𝟐 𝐐𝟏 +𝐐𝟐
𝚫𝐐 𝐏𝟏 +𝐏𝟐
𝐞𝐩(𝐚𝐫𝐜) = ×
𝚫𝐏 𝐐𝟏 +𝐐𝟐
The arc elasticity measures the average price elasticity
Further Illustration
𝟏
1. Suppose the 𝜺 = 𝒂𝒏𝒅 𝑸 = 𝟐𝟓 𝒖𝒏𝒊𝒕𝒔. What will be the change
𝟒
in quantity as a result of 20% fall in price of the commodity?
2. Suppose 𝜺 = 𝟒, what is the change in price that will cause a 10%
fall in quantity demanded?
Further Illustration
𝟏
1. Suppose the 𝜺 = 𝒂𝒏𝒅 𝑸 = 𝟐𝟓 𝒖𝒏𝒊𝒕𝒔. What will be the change
𝟒
in quantity as a result of 20% fall in price of the commodity?
Solution
𝑿 𝟏
1. Let X = % change in Q, then by definition =
𝟐𝟎% 𝟒
Multiplying both sides by 20%, we obtain
𝟏
𝑿 = 𝟐𝟎% = 𝟓%
𝟒
Thus approximately, the change in Q is 5% of 25 = 1.25units
Further Illustration
2. Suppose 𝜺 = 𝟒, what is the change in price that will cause a 10%
fall in quantity demanded?
Solution
𝟏𝟎%
2. Let X = % change in P, then by definition =𝟒
𝑿
Multiplying both sides by X, we obtain
𝟏𝟎% = 𝟒𝑿
𝟏𝟎%
Thus 𝑿 = = 𝟐. 𝟓%
𝟒
The price must rise by 2.5% in order to induce a 10% fall in Q.
Demand And Total Revenue
Once the market demand for various goods and services are known,
it becomes quite easy to estimate the revenue that firms are likely to
obtain.
This is because total consumer spending is equivalent to total
business receipts or revenue from sales.
Total consumer spending TCS:
𝐓𝐂𝐒 = 𝐏 × 𝐐 = 𝐓𝐑
If the market demand is linear the total-revenue curve will be a
curve which initially slopes upwards, reaches a maximum and then
starts declining.
Price Elasticity and Total Revenue
The total revenue can be computed by multiplying price by
the corresponding quantity.
E.g 𝐓𝐑𝟏 = 𝐏𝟏 ∗ 𝟎𝐐𝟏 The Marginal revenue is of particular
interest in this analysis.
Marginal Revenue is the change in TR that occurs as a
result of selling an additional unit of the commodity.
The slope of the TR curve gives us the MR
TR
𝑻𝑹
P 𝒆𝒑 = ∞
D
P2 A 𝒆𝒑 > 𝟏
P1 B 𝒆𝒑 = 𝟏
P3 C 𝒆𝒑 < 𝟏
D’ 𝒆𝒑 =0
Q2 Q1 Q3 Q
𝑴𝑹
Price Elasticity and Total Revenue
Elastic Demand: E d > 1.0
If price … Total revenue Because the percentage change in quantity is …
…
Larger than the percentage change in price.
Larger than the percentage change in price.
𝟏
𝐌𝐑 = 𝐏 𝟏 −
𝐞𝐩
Marginal Revenue and Price Elasticity
We noted that when the demand curve is falling the TR
curve initially rises, reaches a maximum and then starts
declining.
Thus
If 𝐞𝐩 > 𝟏 ⇒ the total revenue curve has a positive slope-
thus is still increasing and has not reached maximum point
𝟏
𝑷 > 𝟎 𝒂𝒏𝒅 𝟏 − > 𝟎 ⇒ 𝑴𝑹 > 𝟎
𝒆𝒑
Marginal Revenue and Price Elasticity
Substitutes No Substitutes
Possibility of Postponement
of Purchase
Income Levels
Application : Drones and the Lower Half of a Linear Demand Curve
Suppose a firm that produces
hobby drones (for civilian use)
has a linear demand curve for its
product, with a vertical intercept
of GH¢800. The firm currently
charges a price of GH¢300.
Should the firm raise its price?
Application : Drones and the Lower Half of a Linear Demand Curve
Solution
Should the firm raise its price?
Yes!
1. The price is below the
midpoint of the linear demand
curve, so raising price would
increase revenue.
2. It would need to make fewer
drones, so its costs would fall.
CROSS ELASTICITY
Measures the extent to which Changes in the price of one
commodity is affects the quantity demanded of another commodity
𝚫𝐐𝐱 𝐏𝐘
𝐄𝐱𝐲 = ×
𝚫𝐏𝐘 𝐐𝐗
The co-efficient of 𝐄𝐱𝐲 could either be positive or negative
depending on the type of commodity
If the two commodities in question are substitute it would be
positive
If the two commodities in question are complements it would be
negative
CROSS ELASTICITY
The co-efficient of Exy could either be positive or
negative or zero depending on the nature of the
relationship between the goods
Substitute goods: Exy > 0.
Complementary goods: Exy < 0.
No relationship Exy = 0.
Practice What You Know
Economists have studied that when the price of chicken increases,
people purchase less rice. With these two goods, which of the
following is true?
A. EC < 0, chicken and rice are complements.
B. EC > 0, chicken and rice are complements.
C. EC < 0, chicken and rice are substitutes.
D. EC > 0, chicken and rice are substitutes.
INCOME ELASTICITY
The income elasticity of demand is a measure of the relationship
between a relative change in income and the consequent relative
change in quantity demanded, ceteris paribus.
Thus, measures the responsiveness of quantity demanded to
changes in income
𝚫𝐐 𝐌
𝛄= ×
𝚫𝐌 𝐐
INCOME ELASTICITY
If the income elasticity is positive, then the good in
question is a normal good because the change in
income and the change in quantity demanded move
in the same direction.
If the income elasticity is negative, then the good in
question in an inferior good because the change in
income and the change in quantity demanded move
in opposite directions.
Practice What You Know
State whether you think the following goods are inferior, necessity,
or luxury goods:
•steak •laptop computers
•toothpaste •lawn-care service
•fast food •milk
•pedicures •gasoline
•new vehicles •cigarettes
•used vehicles •lottery tickets
Practice What You Know
Suppose that Kofi receives a pay increase at work, and his income
increases by 20 percent. As a result, Kofi decides to buy 12 percent
less ground beef. For Kofi, ground beef is a(n) ________________.
A. luxury good
B. necessity good
C. normal good
D. inferior good
Price Elasticity of Supply
Producers also respond to changes in price.
%QS
ES =
%P
Combining Supply and Demand
We’ve previously drawn shifts in demand and supply, and
studied the changes in equilibrium price and quantity.
How will the magnitude of the price and quantity changes
be affected if we alter the demand or supply elasticity?
Increase in Demand for Oil from China
Consumer surplus
What is it?
Willingness to pay: the maximum amount that a
buyer will pay for a good.
It measures how much the buyer values the good or
service.
The difference between what you paid, and what you
were willing and able to pay.
Consumer surplus
Buyer Willingness to Pay
James GH₵100
Jerry GH₵80
Winifred GH₵70
Gifty GH₵50
Consumer surplus
Buyers Price Quantity
Demanded
More than GH₵100 More than GH₵100 None
Demand
0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of
Albums
Price of
Album
(a) Price = GH₵80
100
James’ consumer surplus (20)
80
70
50
Demand
0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of
Albums
(b) Price = 70
Price of
Album
100
James’ consumer surplus (20)
80
Jerry’s consumer
70 surplus (10)
Total
50 consumer
surplus ($40)
Demand
0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of
Albums
Using Demand Curve to Measure Consumer Surplus
The market demand curve depicts the various
quantities that buyers would be willing and able to
purchase at different prices.
The area below the demand curve and above the
price measures the consumer surplus in the market
The formula for consumer surplus is given by:
P
P A
0
𝟏
𝐂𝐒 = × 𝐛𝐚𝐬𝐞 × 𝐡𝐞𝐢𝐠𝐡𝐭
𝟐
First In this case
Surplu 𝟏
P1
s
Surplus for B 𝐂𝐒 = × (𝟎 − 𝐐𝟐 ) × (𝐏𝟎 − 𝐏𝟐 )
new 𝟐∗
Additional
ConsumersSurplus 𝐐
P2
𝐂𝐒 = න 𝐟 𝐐 𝐝𝐐 − 𝐏 ∗ 𝐐∗
D 𝟎
0 Q1 Q2 Q
Producer Surplus
What is it?
The amount a seller is paid, minus the seller’s cost.
It measures the benefit to sellers participating in a market.
Cost: the value of everything a seller must give up to
produce a good.
The Cost of Four Possible Sellers?
Seller Cost
Akpors GH₵900
Akpordoos GH₵800
Kakporgbo GH₵600
Gbokataa GH₵500
Using Supply Curve to Measure Producer Surplus
Just as consumer surplus is related to the demand curve,
producer surplus is closely related to the supply curve.
Sellers Price Quantity
Supplied
Akpors, Akpordoos, GH₵900 or More 4
Gbokataa, Gbokataa
Akpordoos GH₵800 to GH₵900 3
Kakporgbo GH₵600 to GH₵800 2
Gbokataa GH₵500 to GH₵600 1
None GH₵500 to less 0
P
Supply
Akpors’ cost
900
Akpordoos’ cost
800
Q
1 2 3 4
Using Supply Curve to Measure Producer Surplus
The area below the price and above the supply curve
measures the producer surplus in a market.
900 Total Producer surplus
800
1 2 3 4
How a Higher Price Raises Producer Surplus
As price rises, producer surplus increases for two reasons:
Those already selling the product will receive additional
producer surplus because they are receiving more for the
product than before
Since the price is now higher, some new sellers will enter the
market and receive producer surplus on these additional units
of output sold
(b) Producer Surplus at Price P
Price
Additional producer Supply
surplus to initial
producers
D E
P2 F
P1 B
Initial surplus C
Producer surplus
to new producers
A
0 Q1 Q2 Quantity
The formula for Producer surplus is given by:
𝟏
= × 𝐛𝐚𝐬𝐞 × 𝐡𝐞𝐢𝐠𝐡𝐭
𝟐
In this case
𝟏
P𝐒 = × (𝟎 − 𝐐𝟐 ) × (𝐏𝟎 − 𝐏𝟐 )
𝟐
∗
𝐐
𝐏𝐒 = 𝐏 ∗ 𝐐∗ − න 𝐟 𝐐 𝐝𝐐
𝟎
THE INFLUENCE OF GOVERNMENT
POLICIES ON MARKET OUTCOMES
Big Questions
1. When do price ceilings matter?
2. What effects do price ceilings have on economic
activity?
3. When do price floors matter?
4. What effects do price floors have on economic
activity?
Price Controls
Price Ceiling Price Floor
Legally set maximum price Legally set minimum price
Rent control apartment, Minimum wage
price gouging
Three situations:
Three situations: Nonbinding
Nonbinding Binding
Binding Long-run effects
Long-run effects
The Influence of Government Policies on Market Outcomes
Price controls are legal restrictions on how high or low a
market price may go.
Attempt to set, or manipulate, prices through government
regulations in the market.
2 kinds of price controls:
Price Ceilings: a maximum price sellers are allowed to
charge for a good. It’s an upper limit for the price.
Price Floors: a minimum price buyers are required to pay
for a good. Its a lower limit for the price.
THE INFLUENCE OF GOVERNMENT POLICIES ON MARKET
OUTCOMES
Why Price controls?
During crisis times, emergencies or wars the government
wants to protect the consumers from rapidly increasing
prices.
If the equilibrium wage given by supply and demand for
low skilled workers is below poverty level, the government
can set a minimum wage
THE INFLUENCE OF GOVERNMENT POLICIES ON
MARKET OUTCOMES
▪ Equilibrium ▪ Price ceiling
Price Price
S
S
D D
4 4
3 3
Price
2 Ceiling
2
Shortage
Pe
PC Ceiling
Shortage
D
0 Qs Qe Quantity
Qd
Price controls: Price ceilings
Wasted Resources
People spend money, time and expend effort in
order to deal with the shortages caused by the
price ceiling.
You waste a lot of time looking for a good in case
of shortage, the time has it’s value! You can work
or just rest, do something better than look for a
good you’ can’t find.
Price controls: Price ceilings
Inefficiently Low Quality
Price ceilings often lead to inefficiency in that
the goods being offered are of inefficiently low
quality
In case of rent controls, the landlords will not
improve the conditions of the apartments, there
is no incentive since the rental fee is low but the
main reason is that since there is a shortage,
people are willing to rent the apartment as it is,
even in bad condition!
Price controls: price ceilings
Black Markets
A black market is a market in which goods or
services are bought and sold illegally—either
because it is illegal to sell them at all or because
the prices charged are legally prohibited by a
price ceiling.
If someone for example bribes (gives extra
money) to the apartment owners he will get the
apartment, but the honest people that don’t
break the law will never find one this way!
Demonstration on the Computation of Full Economic Price
Ghana recently accelerated its plan to privatize tens of thousands
of state-owned firms. The estimates of the market demand and
supply for the goods are given by
𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐𝑷
𝑸𝒔 = −𝟐 + 𝟐𝑷
Determine the equilibrium price and quantity.
The government raises a concern that the free market price might
be too high for the consumers and is planning to set a price ceiling
of GH¢1.5.
Demonstration on the Computation of Full Economic Price
Determine
(a) the quantity demanded,
(b) the quantity supplied,
(c) the amount of shortage and
(d) the full economic price paid by the consumers if a price
ceiling of GH¢1.50 is imposed in the market
Solution
𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐𝑷, 𝑸𝒔 = −𝟐 + 𝟐𝑷
𝑰𝒏 𝒆𝒒𝒖𝒊𝒍𝒊𝒃𝒓𝒊𝒖𝒎, 𝑸𝒅 = 𝑸𝒔 = 𝑸
𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐𝑷 = −𝟐 + 𝟐𝑷
𝟏𝟎 + 𝟐 = 𝟐𝑷 + 𝟐𝒑
𝟏𝟐 = 𝟒𝑷
Therefore, 𝑷 = 𝟑
To determine the equilibrium quantity, we substitute the value of P
into either the demand or supply function, either way the solution
will be the same.
Therefore, 𝑸 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐 𝟑 = 𝟒
Solution
𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐𝑷, 𝑸𝒔 = −𝟐 + 𝟐𝑷
a. Placing the ceiling price into both the demand and supply
functions, we obtain
𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐 𝟏. 𝟓 = 𝟕
b.
𝑸𝒔 = −𝟐 + 𝟐 𝟏. 𝟓 = 𝟏
c. The amount of shortage will be given by
𝑺𝒉𝒐𝒓𝒕𝒂𝒈𝒆 = 𝑸𝒅 − 𝑸𝒔 ⟹ 𝟕 − 𝟏 = 𝟔
𝑭 𝑭 𝑭 𝟗
d. 𝟏 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐𝑷 ⟹ 𝟐𝑷 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟏 ⟹ 𝑷 = = 𝑮𝑯𝑺𝟒. 𝟓𝟎
𝟐
Practice What You Know
Supply and demand generally become more elastic in the long run.
This means that shortages caused by price ceilings
_________________ in the long run.
A. disappear completely
B. become smaller
C. become larger
D. become infinitely large
Price Controls: Price Floor
S S
D Surplus
Price Price D
Price floor
4 4
3
3
2 2
Qd Q* QS Quantity
Demonstration of Cost of Purchasing the Surplus
Based on the analysis in problem above, the government worries
that the free market price might be too high for the producers to
earn a fair rate of return and is planning to set a price floor of
GH¢4.
Determine (a) the quantity demanded, (b) the quantity supplied,
and (c) the amount of surplus if a price floor of GH¢4 is imposed
in the market. (d) What is the cost to the Ghanaian government of
buying the surplus under the price floor?
Solution
𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐𝑷, 𝑸𝒔 = −𝟐 + 𝟐𝑷
With the price floor, we substitute the floor value into both the
demand and supply functions, so that
a. 𝑸𝒅 = 𝟏𝟎 − 𝟐 𝟒 = 𝟐
b. 𝑸𝒔 = −𝟐 + 𝟐 𝟒 = 𝟔
c. 𝑺𝒖𝒓𝒑𝒍𝒖𝒔 = 𝑸𝒔 − 𝑸𝒅 ⟹ 𝟔 − 𝟐 = 𝟒
d. Cost of purchasing the surplus= 𝑷𝒓𝒊𝒄𝒆 𝒇𝒍𝒐𝒐𝒓 × 𝑺𝒖𝒓𝒑𝒍𝒖𝒔 ⟹
𝑮𝑯𝑺𝟒 × 𝟒 = 𝑮𝑯𝑺𝟏𝟔
Price controls: Price floors
Why a Price Floor Causes Inefficiency
Inefficient Allocation of Sales Among Sellers
Price floors lead to inefficient allocation of sales among
sellers: those who would be willing to sell the good at the
lowest price are not always those who actually manage to
sell it.
Wasted Resources
Like a price ceiling, a price floor generates inefficiency by
wasting resources.
Minimum Wage
Minimum wage:
The lowest hourly wage rate that firms may legally pay
their workers
PT
A
B E
P1
C F
PS
D
D
Q
QT Q1
Before Tax After Change
Tax
Consumer 𝐀+𝐁+𝐄 𝐀 𝐀 − (𝐀 + 𝐁 + 𝐄)
Surplus = −𝐁 − 𝐄
Producer 𝐂+𝐃+𝐅 𝐃 𝐃 − (𝐂 + 𝐃 + 𝐅)
Surplus = −𝐃 − 𝐅
Tax 0 𝐁+𝐂 B+C
Revenue
Total 𝐀+𝐁+𝐄+𝐂+𝐃+𝐅 𝐀+𝐁 (𝐀 + 𝐁 + 𝐂 + 𝐃)
Welfare + 𝐂 + 𝐃 − (𝐀 + 𝐁 + 𝐄 + 𝐂
+ 𝐃 + 𝐅) = − −𝐄 − 𝐅
Elasticity and the Size of the Deadweight Loss
The size of the deadweight loss from a tax, as
well as how the burdens are shared between
buyers and sellers, depends on the price
elasticities of supply and demand.
The less elastic the curves are, the smaller the
deadweight loss.
P ST
S
PT
P1
PS
Q
QT Q1
P
ST
S
PT
P1
PS
D
Q
QT Q1
Elasticity and the Size of the Deadweight Loss
Elasticity differences can help us understand tax
policy.
Those goods that are heavily taxed often have a
relatively inelastic demand curve in the short run.
This means that the burden falls mainly on the
buyer.
It also means that the deadweight loss to society is
smaller than if the demand curve was more
elastic.
The Welfare Effects of Subsidies
If taxes cause deadweight or welfare losses, do
subsidies create welfare gains?
Think of a subsidy as a negative tax.
The Welfare Effects of Subsidies
If taxes cause deadweight or welfare losses, do
subsidies create welfare gains?
Think of a subsidy as a negative tax.
We see that the subsidy lowers the price to the
buyer and increases the quantity exchanged.
P
S
A S1
Ps
B H
Pe G
Pd C E F
D
D
Qe Q1 Q
With No Subsidy With Subsidy Impact of
Subsidy
𝑻𝑼
𝐴𝑼 =
𝑸
The relationship between TU,AU and MU (Utility Schedule )
𝑴𝑼𝒙
𝛌= , Thus the utility derived from spending the last cedi should
𝑷𝒙
be equal to the proportion of the MU obtained from the price of the
good.
Equilibrium Condition under the behavior
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Graphical representation
P,MU
E
𝜆𝑃𝑥
𝑀𝑈𝑥
0 Qty
Xe
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
𝑒1
𝜆𝑃3
𝑒0
𝜆𝑃𝑥
𝑒2
𝜆𝑃2
𝑀𝑈𝑥
0 X1 X X2
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium
From the diagram the consumer is in equilibrium at point e where
𝑴𝑼𝒙 = 𝝀𝑷𝒙
Assuming price of good X increases from 𝑷𝒙 to 𝑷𝒙𝟏 , then the
consumer can no longer be in a state of equilibrium at point e
because 𝑴𝑼𝒙 < 𝝀𝑷𝒙 . To restore equilibrium, the consumer has to
consume less of good X (Less than X units which is X1).
Equilibrium Condition Under the cardinalist’s Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium.
Per the law of diminishing marginal utility, the more units
consumed, the lesser the MU and the less units consumed, then
higher the MU. Therefore the consumer will derive a higher MU
from consuming less units. Equilibrium will be restored at point e1.
Assuming price falls to P2
There will be disequilibrium (𝑴𝑼𝒙 < 𝝀𝑷𝒙 ). For equilibrium to be
restored, the consumer has to consume more units of good X
Equilibrium Condition under the Cardinalist's Approach
Single Commodity Case (Good X)
Effect of a price a change on the equilibrium
Quantity consumed increases to X2. As more unit good X is being
consumed, the MU derived falls (per the law of diminishing
marginal utility) and equilibrium is restored at point e2.
Derivation of the Demand Curve under the Cardinalist's
Approach
The analysis used to explain the effect of a price change on the
equilibrium condition is used to derive the demand curve.
P,MU
𝑒1
𝜆𝑃3
𝑒0
𝜆𝑃𝑥
𝑒2
𝜆𝑃2
𝑀𝑈𝑥
0 X1 X X2
Equi-marginal Utility
In reality, household consume multiple goods concomitantly.
𝑴𝑼𝒙
The equilibrium condition for the single commodity case (𝛌 = )
𝑷𝒙
does not hold
The principles of equi-marginal utility is then adopted to explain
how consumers maximize the utility they derive from consuming
each good given their income constraints and prices of the
commodities in question.
Equi-marginal Utility
The principles or law of equi-marginal utility states that consumers
will distribute their income among the goods in such a way that the
marginal utility derived from the last cedi spent on each good is
equal
Mathematically
𝑴𝑼𝒙 𝑴𝑼𝒚 𝑴𝑼𝒛
= =……. , Where X to Z are different commodities
𝑷𝒙 𝑷𝒚 𝑷𝒛
consumed. For the sake of easy analysis the principle will be
restricted to two goods X and Y
Example, Px=4 Py=3, Income = GHS 34
Quantity
1 22 27 5.5 9
2 20 24 5 8
3 18 21 4.5 7
4 16 18 4 6
5 14 15 3.5 5
6 12 12 3 4
7 10 9 2.5 3
Given the equilibrium condition as
𝑴𝑼𝒙 𝑴𝑼𝒚
= , the consumer has three alternative bundles to choose
𝑷𝒙 𝑷𝒚
from two goods. Nonetheless, the consumer is constrained by
his/her income and the price of the two of goods. The consumer
can only consume less or equal to his/her budget
The budget constraint of the consumer is given by
PxX+PyY=Income
Cont’
Alternative 1
The consumer can consume 2 units of good X and 5 units of good Y.
The total expenditure will be 4(2)+3(5)=GHS23.00
GHS23.00<GHS34.00
The consumer’s expenditure is lesser than his/her income
Alternative 2
The consumer can consume 4 units of good X and 6 units of good Y.
The total expenditure will 4(4)+3(6)=GHS34
GHS=34.00=34.00, consumer’s expenditure equal to his/her income
Cont’
Alternative 3
The consumer can consume 6 units of good x and 7 units of good
y. The total expenditure will be 4(6)+3(7)=GHS45
GHS45>GHS34.00
Hence expenditure larger than income
Conclusion
Given the equilibrium condition and the budget constraints of the
consumer, this consumer will choose alternative 3. Thus s/he wull
consume 4 units of good x and 6 units of good y. This bundle gives
the consumer the maximum utility give his/her budget constraint
Cont’
Why not Option 1 or 3
The consumer does not choose alternative 1 although it meets the
two conditions because the consumer is rational. S/he has the
objective of maximizing his/her utility. The surplus (money left)
can be used to buy more of each good which will give the
consumer a higher utility than what s/he derives from consuming
the bundles in alternative 1.
The consumer does not choose alternative 3 although it give the
consumer the highest level of satisfaction. This is because the
consumer is constrained by their income and so cannot buy the
bundle of goods offered in alternative 3
Marginal Utility and the Elasticity of Demand
If, as the quantity consumed of a good increase, marginal utility
decreases quickly, the demand for the good is inelastic.
If, as the quantity consumed of a good increases, MU decreases
slowly, the demand for that good is elastic.
Example Px=4 and Py=4.5, Income =GHS34.00
Quantity
1 22 27 5.5 6
2 20 24 5 5.33
3 18 21 4.5 4.6
4 16 18 4 4
5 14 15 3.5 3.33
6 12 12 3 2.67
7 10 9 2.5 2
THE FIRM
𝑻𝑷
𝑨𝑷 = ,
𝑳
Marginal Product refers to the change in output that arises from an
additional unit of input employed
0 100 - 0 - 100 - -
1 100 100 50 50 150 150 50
2 100 50 80 40 180 90 30
3 100 33.33 100 33.33 200 66.67 20
4 100 25 110 27.50 210 52.50 10
5 100 20 130 26 230 46 20
Sunk Cost refers to cost incurred in the past that cannot be changed
by current decisions and therefore cannot be recovered.
Costs In The Short Run
Long Run Total Cost : In the long run, all factors of production are
varied. There is no fixed input so no fixed costs are incurred. Unlike
the short run where total cost is the summation of the total fixed
cost and the total variable cost, the long run total cost is equal to
the long run total variable cost.
The long run average total cost curve shows the lowest unit cost at
which the firm can produce any given level of output.
Costs In The Short Run
The long run average total cost curve
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Economies of scale are cost advantages firms experience or enjoy
in the long run in the form of lower average cost as production
increases in the long run.
Production becomes efficient because the cost of production can
be spread over a larger amount of goods.
The factors giving rise to economies of scale are be broadly
grouped
internal factors
external factors
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Internal Economies of Scale are factors resulting from the firms’
decisions and actions. They include:
Technical or technological economies of scale
Managerial economies of scale
Monopsony power
Network economies of scale
Bulk purchasing
External economies of scale are factors that are external to a firm
but within the same industry that bring cost benefit to a firm.
They usually are industry-wide decision and activities external to the firm.
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Examples of external economies of scale include
Infrastructure economies of scale
Specialization and division of labour
Tax incentives
Innovation and research
Access to raw materials from different firms for free or at lesser costs
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Diseconomies of Scale are costs disadvantages that firms
experience in the form of higher average cost as they increase
production in the long run.
That is, as production rises, the average cost of production also
rises.
Firms become worse off than they were in the short run.
The sources of diseconomies of scale are also group into internal
diseconomies of scale and external diseconomies of scale.
Economies and Diseconomies of Scale
Internal and External sources of Diseconomies of Scale
Managerial diseconomies
Higher input prices
Marketing diseconomies
Low morale
MARKETS
A market refers to the interaction between firms and buyers to
facilitate the transaction or exchange of goods and services.
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Perfectly Competitive Market also known as Competitive Market or
PCM refers to a market with many buyers and sellers trading
identical products so that each buyer and seller is a price taker.
Features
There are many sellers and many buyers
Homogenous and identical goods
No barriers to entry into or exit from the market
Perfect information between buyers and sellers
Both sellers and buyers are price takers
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Nature of Curves
Because producers are price takers, a firms revenue is proportional
to the units of goods it produces.
Under the PCM, the price of the good is equal to the average
revenue as well as the marginal revenue.
P=AR=MR is a horizontal curve because price is constant
A firm in the PCM maximizes profit by producing the quantity at
which its marginal cost is equal to its marginal revenue.
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Nature of Curves
Mathematically,
𝑻𝑹 = 𝑷 ∗ 𝑸
𝑻𝑹
𝑨𝑹 =
𝑸
𝑷∗𝑸
𝑨𝑹 =
𝑸
𝑨𝑹 = 𝑷
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Nature of Curves
Mathematically,
𝑻𝑹 = 𝑷 ∗ 𝑸
𝒅𝑻𝑹
M𝑹 =
𝒅𝑸
𝒅𝑷𝑸
𝑴𝑹 =
𝒅𝑸
P=MR=AR
0 Qnty
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Demand Curve
However, the market demand is downward sloping.
P=MR=AR
0 Qnty
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Profit Maximization
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Profit Maximizing Condition
Profit is maximized at the point where the MR curve in equal to the
MC curve, that is a necessary condition.
From the Curve, although MR=MC at point D, the firm is
encouraged to increase the output produced. This is because, with
the additional goods produced, the firm’s marginal revenue exceeds
its marginal cost until the point E.
Beyond point E, the firm incurs a higher cost more than the
revenue it earn from producing the good. The firm is therefore
encouraged to reduce the units of its output.
Perfectly Competitive Markets
Profit maximizing Condition
This is because when the firm reduces its output, the marginal cost
saved will be higher than the marginal revenue lost
Point E is the profit maximizing point. The firm is encouraged to
produce Q units at point E because that will give it the maximum
profit. The firm’s MR=MC.
The profit maximizing output level is produced at the point where
the MC=MR but the MC cuts the MR curve from below
Perfectly Competitive Markets
AR=DD
0
MR
Monopoly: The Price Maker
Profit Maximization of the Monopolist
AR/P/MR
MC
B
P
0 AR=DD
MR
Q
Monopoly: The Price Maker
Profit Maximization of the Monopolist
A monopolist maximizes profits by choosing the quantity at which
MR equal MC at point A
It then uses the demand curve to find the price that will induce
consumers to buy that quantity Point B
The profit of a monopolist is equal the its total revenue minus the
total cost
𝝅 = 𝑻𝑹 − 𝑻𝑪
Monopoly: The Price Maker
The Monopolist and Welfare
The monopolist charges a higher price than the price in the perfect
competitive market
The monopolist produces lesser units of a good than the output
level in the perfect competitive market.
The monopolist enjoys a greater producer surplus than producers
in the perfect competitive market
Consumers in the perfect competitive market enjoy greater
consumer surplus than consumers in the monopoly market.
Monopoly: The Price Maker
The Monopolist and Welfare
There is inefficiency in the monopoly market.
Resources are not allocated efficiently.
Consumers are worse off because of the higher price which has
been set by the monopolist and/or the limited units of output
produced.
Welfare loss
The surplus of consumers is transferred to the producer
The market welfare loss is indicated by the deadweight loss
Monopoly: The Price Maker
The Monopolist and Welfare
THANK YOU