BEHAVIOURAL REMEDIES IN OLIGOPOLISTIC - CE-new
BEHAVIOURAL REMEDIES IN OLIGOPOLISTIC - CE-new
37
Journal on Competition Law and Policy Vol. 2, December 2021, pp. 1-44
Behavioural Remedies in
Oligopolistic Markets under the
Indian Merger Control Regime
Pemala Lama1 and Priya Bansal2
Abstract
Competition authorities primarily make use of two types of remedies,
namely, “structural” and “behavioural,” or a combination of the two1,
before clearing mergers that are likely to cause substantial harm to
competition. Of these, structural remedies have been the predominant
choice. However, of late, in the wake of the digital revolution and greater
emphasis on designing remedies on a case-by-case basis, behavioural
remedies have witnessed increased use. To this end, this paper seeks
to address the role of behavioural solutions in the oligopolistic market
structure under Indian competition law, with a focus on the merger control
regime. It also intends to understand and critically analyse the literature
on the problem of oligopolistic markets and the approach adopted with
respect to remedies employed by the competition authorities of various
jurisdictions (including the European Union (EU), the United States of
America (USA), Canada, South Korea, Brazil, and India) to address the
problem. Furthermore, the paper aims to examine the scope and limitations
of behavioural remedies and their potential role in the conditional
clearance of mergers. We use the number and nature of merger control
investigations in the aforementioned jurisdictions in which behavioural
remedies were adopted during 2015–19 to examine the conditions under
which these remedies were used. The findings indicate that there is no
1Deputy
Director, Economics Division, Competition Commission of India;
[email protected]
2Research Associate, Economics Division, Competition Commission of India;
[email protected]
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
2
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
1. Introduction
The merger control regime in India became operative on 1st June 2011 along
with notifications of Sections 5 and 6 of the Competition Act, 2002. There
have been over 750 filings, and CCI is yet to block a single combination.
A proposed combination is approved by the CCI if, prima facie, it is of the
view that the transaction does not or is not likely to cause an appreciable
adverse effect on competition (AAEC). This may be referred to as the Phase
I investigation, whereby CCI approves notifications within 30 working
days. However, if CCI’s assessment shows the likelihood of AAEC in
the concerned market at the prima facie stage, a Phase II investigation is
carried out.
From 2014 to April 2021, in approximately 22 cases, CCI made use of
remedies to grant clearance in Phase I or, after investigation, Phase II.
CCI may employ structural, behavioural, or hybrid remedies as per its
discretion. Structural remedies are usually preferred in horizontal mergers
and involve the sale of one or more businesses, physical assets, or other
rights to address competitive harm in order to maintain or restore the
competitive structure of the market (International Competition Network,
2016). Such remedies aim to strengthen an existing player and/or create
a new competitor so as to provide independent firms with incentives to
maximise profits while preserving some of the efficiencies of a proposed
merger. It also involves self-policing and low monitoring costs, is easy to
administer, readily enforceable, and accomplished over a short duration.
On the other hand, behavioural or conduct remedies are usually preferred
in vertical mergers (Wilson, 2020b); these are designed to modify or
2
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
2. Literature Review
2.1 The Problem of Oligopoly vis-à-vis Antitrust Concern
In order to understand the implications of competition on economic
performance, one has to return to the economic theory of perfect competition
and compare it with monopolistic and oligopolistic market outcomes.
At the outset, perfect competition entails the sovereignty of consumers
and producers as price-takers who are able to sell only at the market
price. According to neo-classical economic theory, perfect competition
3
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
4
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
not only enhances allocative and productive efficiency, which will ipso
facto maximise social welfare, but also maximises consumer welfare and
increases dynamic efficiency by stimulating innovation. This follows from
the assumption that producers are rational and wish to maximise profit,
and thus, will continue to produce and supply as long as it is profitable to
do so and goods and services can be acquired at the lowest cost possible.
On the other hand, a monopolist, being a price-fixer, can influence the
price either by reducing the volume of its production or by increasing
the price. Thus, such a market structure is characterised by allocative
inefficiency, also known as “deadweight loss,” along with productive and
dynamic inefficiency. It is to be noted that the conditions/assumptions of
perfect competition and monopoly in their purest form are extremely rare
and unlikely to be observed in reality. However, there exist intermediate
market structures between the two extreme market structures, such as
oligopoly, wherein some firms sell slightly differentiated products and
hold and value consumer loyalty, thereby lending the firms some degree
of market power.
The problem of oligopolistic markets is considered one of the most
difficult problems for competition authorities, particularly due to “tacit
coordination” (also called “conscious parallelism,” “tacit collusion,” etc.),
where firms are able to take advantage of certain features of the market and
coordinate their behaviour on prices, output, etc., by directly or indirectly
taking into account their competitors’ strategies and likely reactions that
would result in an infringement of antitrust provisions (Amarnath, 2013).
Therefore, with modern markets being characterised by oligopolistic
market structures, increasing market consolidation, and greater
interdependence between industries, and consequently, higher market
power, competition policy emerges as a respite for firms facing resultant
anti-competitive outcomes for the preservation of healthy competition
in the market. However, according to Whish and Bailey (2015), the
competitive process contains an inevitable paradox: one competitor may
win by being the most innovative and most responsive to customers’ wishes
and producing goods and services in the most efficient way possible and
4
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
succeed in seeing off its rivals. It would be strange, and indeed harmful, if
that firm is then condemned for being a monopolist.
Therefore, in oligopolistic markets, firms are in a position to earn
supra-competitive profits by observing each other’s reaction function/
behaviour and strategising their own business actions accordingly, while
simultaneously having a high degree of resultant responsive limitation
such that it will reduce the level/extent of competition in the market.
The empirical evidence to illustrate the relationship between market
structure, the conduct of firms in the market, and the behaviour of firms
is often referred to as the structure–conduct–performance paradigm
(SCP paradigm). Competition law seeks to check the actions of firms that
can harm the structure of the market, conduct that can foreclose access
to market, and mergers and acquisitions that can reduce the number of
firms operating in the market so as to maintain or restore a competitive
market structure that is likely to have a positive impact on the conduct
and performance of firms operating in the market.
Over the years, several studies have been conducted in order to
understand the conditions that trigger tacit collusion. One such study was
undertaken by Mason (1939) that focused on the relationship between
prices and the number of sellers in the market. This led to the emergence
of the Harvard School, which found a link between oligopolistic market
concentration and supra-competitive profits in the SCP paradigm
(Bain, 1968; Kaysen & Turner, 1959), i.e., oligopolies are able to reap
supra-competitive profits due to their unreasonable degree of market
power (the structural view of oligopolies).
According to the Harvard School and structuralists such as Areeda
and Hovenkamp (2017), Turner (1962), and Kaysen (1951), a direct
correlation exists between the structure of the market, the conduct of
firms on the market, and their performance, and that tacit coordination
occurs in a concentrated market structure. This is because market forces
are inadequate to challenge the entrenched power of a dominant firm,
and leading firms in highly concentrated industries employ conscious
parallelism to avoid price competition, thereby earning abnormal profits.
Entry barrier is viewed as a principal reason for poor performance of
5
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
6
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
6
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
7
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
8
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
8
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
9
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
10
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
10
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
11
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
12
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
Cases entailing q
uasi-
Type of
Year structural remedy Sector
merger
(Total number: 9)
Orange/Jazztel Telecommunications Horizontal
2015 Transport &
IAG/Aer Lingus Vertical
Infrastructure
Worldline/Equens/
Financial services Conglomerate
PaySquare
Horizontal/
Hutchison/Vimpelcom Telecommunications
Vertical
2016
Liberty Global/BASE Horizontal/
Telecommunications
Belgium Vertical
Energy and Natural Horizontal/
SFR/Dansk Fuels
Resources Vertical
Horizontal/
Liberty Global/Ziggo Telecommunications
Vertical
Energizer/Spectrum
2018 Electronics Horizontal
Brands
Horizontal/
Hutchison/Wind Tre Telecommunications
Vertical
Cases entailing
Type of
Year behavioural remedy Sector
merger
(Total number: 14)
PRSfM/STIM/GEMA Media/Entertainment Horizontal
Transport & Horizontal/
SNCF/Eurostar
2015 Infrastructure Vertical
Liberty Global/De
Media/Entertainment Vertical
Vijver Media
Dentsply/Sirona Healthcare Conglomerate
Microsoft/LinkedIn Digital/Technology Conglomerate
2016
Vertical/
ASL/Arianespace Aerospace & Defence
Conglomerate
12
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
Vertical/
Broadcom/Brocade Digital/Technology
2017 Conglomerate
Rolls Royce/ITP Aerospace & Defence Vertical
Transport & Horizontal/
Daimler/ BMW
Infrastructure Vertical
2018 Discovery/Scripps Media/Entertainment Horizontal
Vertical/
Qualcomm/NXP Digital/Technology
Conglomerate
Varta AG/Energizer Electronics Vertical
Telia/ Bonnier Vertical/
Media/Entertainment
2019 Broadcasting Conglomerate
Vodafone/Liberty
Telecommunications Horizontal
Global
Source: Press Corner, European Commission.
Accessed at https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/home/en
13
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
14
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
14
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
and Telia’s competitors in telecom and TV distribution shut out from the
market by preventing their access to the advertising space on the merged
entity’s TV channels. In both transactions, one of the primary remedies
that was proposed was an access remedy entailing licensing requirements
in relation to TV/AV channels on fair, reasonable, and non-discriminatory
(FRAND) terms.
In the three mergers pertaining to the digital space, the likelihood of
data interoperability being compromised post the merger (that locks in
customers to one platform over its rivals, thus creating entry barriers)
emerged as the key competition harm.
In Qualcomm/NXP (2018), apart from interoperability, there were
concerns in relation to the incentive of the merged entity to make it difficult
for other suppliers to access NXP’s technology, along with the merger
giving way to combine the two entities’ significant intellectual property
portfolios relating to NFC (near field communication) technology.
Resultantly, Qualcomm committed to offer licences to NXP’s technology
and trademarks and follow standards of interoperability, both for a period
of eight years, and a commitment not to acquire NXP’s standard essential
patents.
In Broadcom/Brocade (2017), the EC had concerns regarding the
complementarity of the products supplied by the merging entities and
the sharing of confidential information. The concerns were addressed via
interoperability requirements and a commitment to protect third-party
confidential information.
In Microsoft/LinkedIn (2016), the EC had concerns that Microsoft would
pre-install LinkedIn on all Windows PCs and that Microsoft would
integrate LinkedIn into Microsoft Office and combine the user database
of the two entities. In order to address these concerns, Microsoft agreed
to abide by a set of commitments for five years. Two commitments were
in relation to interoperability and provision of access. Additionally, it
was left to the discretion of PC manufacturers/distributors to install/not
install LinkedIn on Windows. Users were also given the leeway to remove
LinkedIn from Windows if PC manufacturers/distributors decided to
pre-install it.
15
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
16
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
Cases entailing
Type of
Year quasistructural remedy Sector
merger
(Total number: 2)
US Renal Care, Inc./DSI
2015 Healthcare Horizontal
Renal
2017 Red Venture/Bankrate Digital/Technology Horizontal
Cases entailing
Type of
Year behavioural remedy Sector
merger
(Total number: 4)
Enbridge Inc./Spectra Energy and Natural Horizontal/
2017
Energy Corp Resources Vertical
2018 Northrop/Orbital ATK Aerospace & Defence Vertical
NEXUS Gas
Energy and Natural Horizontal/
Transmission/
Resources Vertical
2019 Generation Pipeline
Industrial &
Staples/Essendant Vertical
Manufacturing
Source: Press Releases, Federal Trade Commission.
Accessed at https://www.ftc.gov/newsevents/press-releases.
16
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
In two of the mergers that entailed the use of behavioural remedies, the
competition concern was purely vertical. In Northrop/Orbital ATK (2018),
Northrop (“Acquirer”) is one of the four companies capable of supplying
the US government with missile systems, while Orbital ATK (“Target”)
is the premier supplier of solid rocket motors (SRMs)—an essential input
for missile systems for propelling missiles to their intended targets. The
competition assessment established the following theories of harm: (a)
incentive and ability on the part of Northrop to harm competition for
missile contracts by either withholding access to its SRMs or increasing
SRM prices to competitors which, in turn, could force competitors to
raise their respective prices, invest less aggressively to win missile
programs (thus hampering innovation), or decide not to compete at all
(creating barriers to entry and expansion); and (b) the proposed merger
would give Northrop access to the proprietary information that missile
contract competitors share with their SRM vendor while also creating a
risk that the proprietary information of a rival SRM supplier supporting
Northrop’s missile system business could be shared with Northrop’s
vertically integrated SRM business. One of the key highlights that
emerged from the merger assessment is that missile systems and SRMs
are high-technology, defence-specific products that required specialised
facilities to be manufactured, and thus, new competitors were unlikely to
enter the market anytime soon.
In Staples/Essendant (2019), Staples (“Acquirer”) is the largest vertically
integrated reseller of office products and one of the only two retail office
supply superstores in the US, while Essendant (“Target”) is one of the
two wholesale distributors of office supplies. The theory of harm that
emerged from the merger related to the likelihood of Staples gaining
access to commercially sensitive business information on Essendant’s
reseller customers and the resellers’ end customers, which could allow
Staples to charge higher prices when bidding against a reseller for an end
customer’s business.
In Enbridge Inc./Spectra Energy Corp (2017), Enbridge (“Acquirer”) and
Spectra Energy (“Target”) are natural gas transmission companies. The
theory of harm related to a reduction in natural gas pipeline competition
17
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
18
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
in three offshore natural gas producing areas in the Gulf of Mexico that
could lead to higher prices for natural gas pipeline transportation from
those areas and increase the likelihood of tacit or explicit coordination
between two pipelines. The reason for the same could be attributed to
the merger giving Enbridge an ownership interest in both pipelines, thus
providing access to sensitive information as well as significant voting
rights over one of the pipelines.
In NEXUS Gas Transmission/Generation Pipeline (2019), Nexus Gas
Transmission (“Acquirer”) and Generation Pipeline (“Target”) operate in
the market for pipeline transportation of natural gas. It was found that
Nexus’s purchase of Generation from North Coast Gas Transmission LLC
and several other owners is anti-competitive due to a non-compete clause
that keeps North Coast from competing to provide natural gas pipeline
transportation in parts of the Ohio counties of Lucas, Ottawa, and Wood
for three years after the acquisition closes.
In three out of the four merger settlements (entailing use of
only behavioural remedies) during 2015–19, the FTC mandated the
establishment of internal firewalls to prevent the leak of confidential
information (which could trigger price rise, hampering of innovation and
erection of entry barriers).
In Northrop/Orbital ATK, the FTC also implemented a supply
obligation towards competitors that entailed non-discriminatory pricing,
scheduling, quality, etc. The merger between NEXUS Gas Transmission
and Generation Pipeline stands out, given that the order of the USFTC
particularly required the parties to execute a revised sale agreement
eliminating the non-compete clauses therein. Thus, the US has provided
conditional clearance to mergers with behavioural remedies even in cases
exhibiting purely vertical relations.
Canada
Table 3 shows that behavioural remedies have been used in a single
merger investigation in Canada, while the corresponding figure for quasi-
structural remedies is six during 2015–19.
18
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
19
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
20
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
(2015). The transaction concerned the market for retail sale of wireless
telecommunications products and services. While the Bureau dismissed
unilateral effects, it identified coordinated effects as a competition
concern owing to the ownership of GLENTEL by BCE and Rogers that
could facilitate access to each other’s sensitive information as well as for
competing wireless carriers for whom GLENTEL provided distribution
services. This could result in consumers paying higher prices for wireless
products and services as BCE and Rogers would likely derive critical
information on competitors’ promotions and subscriber information
through GLENTEL, which could affect all sales channels. To ensure
competition in the market post the merger, the Bureau mandated the use
of administrative firewalls.
In Canada, according to the legal test for a merger remedy (Information
Bulletin on Merger Remedies in Canada, 2006), “the remedy need not
address all competitive harm that may be caused by the transaction
but must reduce it to the point where it is no longer ‘substantial’.” To
understand the approach of the Bureau, the paper has looked at a few
mergers that involved the use of quasi-structural remedies. For instance,
in Superior/Canwest (2017), Superior is Canada’s largest national propane
retailer, while Canwest operates in the retail bulk propane distribution
business in western Canada. It was found that the merger would likely
lessen competition substantially in 22 of the 25 relevant geographic
markets where Superior and Canwest competed with one another locally
in the market for retail sale of bulk propane. The theory of harm related to
post-merger price increases that were likely to occur in the 22 markets and
high barriers to effective entry (in particular, customer switching costs
and existing contracts with incumbent suppliers). The Bureau, however,
concluded that no remedy was required in 10 local markets because the
efficiency gains resulting from the transaction were likely to clearly and
significantly outweigh the likely anti-competitive effects in these markets.
Among the remedies imposed, in addition to the sale of assets in the
remaining 12 markets, the Bureau required that Superior waive contract
terms that impede customer-switching in four markets. These terms
20
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
21
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
22
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
22
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
Media/
2019 Disney/Fox Horizontal
Entertainment
Cases entailing
Year behavioural remedy Sector Type of merger
(Total number: 14)
Transport & Horizontal/
2015 ALL/Rumo
Infrastructure Vertical
Bradesco/Banco do
Brasil/Itaú Unibanco/ Financial Services Vertical
Santander/CEF
Industrial and
Saint Gobain/SiCBRAS Horizontal
2016 Manufacturing
Itaú Unibanco/ Horizontal/
Financial Services
Mastercard Vertical
Horizontal/
Bradesco/HSBC Financial Services
Vertical
Latam/Iberia/British Transport &
Horizontal
Airways Infrastructure
Itaú Unibanco/Citibank Financial Services Horizontal
2017
BM&F Bovespa/Cetip Financial Services Vertical
Media/
AT&T/Time Warner Vertical
Entertainment
Itaú Unibanco/XP Horizontal/
Financial Services
Investimentos Vertical
Energy & Natural
2018 WEG/TGM Conglomerate
Resources
Energy & Natural Horizontal/
Petrotemex/Petrobras
Resources Vertical
SM Empreendimentos Horizontal/
Healthcare
/AllChemistry Vertical
2019
Horizontal/
NotreDame/Mediplan Healthcare
Vertical
23
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
24
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
24
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
25
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
26
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
South Korea
Table 5 shows that behavioural remedies have been used in 10 mergers
in South Korea, while quasi-structural remedies have been used in only
two mergers during 2015–19.
Table 5. C
lassification of Sector and Type of Merger—Korean Fair
Trade Commission (KFTC) (2015–19)
Cases entailing
quasistructural
Year Sector Type of merger
remedy (Total
number: 2)
Transport & Horizontal/
2017 Maersk/HSDG
Infrastructure Vertical
Vertical/
2018 Qualcomm/NXP Digital/Technology
Conglomerate
Cases entailing
behavioural
Year Sector Type of merger
remedy (Total
number: 10)
SeAH Besteel/Posco Industrial & Horizontal/
Specialty Steel Manufacturing Vertical
Hyundai Steel/
Industrial &
Dongbu Special Vertical
Manufacturing
Steel
2015 Hanwha/Samsung Energy & Natural Horizontal/
General Chemicals Resources Vertical
Lotte Department
Store/Daewoo Horizontal/
Consumer & Retail
Department Store Vertical
Masan
Esmeralda/DS Energy & Natural Horizontal/
2017
Power Co. Resources Vertical
Horizontal/
LG U+/CJ Hello Telecommunications
Vertical
26
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
27
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
28
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
28
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
29
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
30
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
merger review is the step that was followed to define the relevant market,
where the overlapping R&D activities of parties, specialised R&D assets
or technical expertise in the overlapping area, and identification of close
substitutes, pipeline products, and portfolios was considered to define the
market.
CCI observed that both parties are vertically integrated agricultural
companies with significant capabilities in the value chain of supply of
agricultural inputs, and since there are substantial entry barriers in the crop
protection segment, the proposed combination would create one of the
largest vertically integrated players in the global agricultural market. CCI
further assessed horizontal and vertical overlaps resulting from the merger
and the resultant possible conglomerate effects due to complementary
product portfolios of the parties. In the non-selective herbicides market
and in the herbicide tolerant traits market, CCI opined that Bayer is
one of the few significant alternatives to Monsanto; thus, the proposed
combination would eliminate an important competitive constraint from
the relevant market. In the market for the licensing of Bt traits for cotton
seeds in India, entry barriers were significant and Monsanto had a strong
market position. Even though Bayer was not present in the Indian market,
CCI held the view that Bayer is one of the few potential competitors with
the capability to effectively constrain Monsanto in the relevant market.
In the market for the licensing of parental lines or hybrids for corn seeds,
the combination would result in the consolidation of two major players in
terms of the strength of seed traits and trait stacks.
In order to address the aforementioned concerns, CCI cleared the
combination with a mix of structural and behavioural remedies which
required Bayer to divest some of its businesses. The behavioural remedies
included a commitment by Bayer that the combined entity would not
offer its clients, farmers, distribution channels, and commercial partners
bundled products that might potentially have the effect of excluding
competitors, and Bayer would follow non-exclusive licensing on a FRAND
term for seven years. Bayer also undertook providing access through
licences on FRAND terms for seven years to existing Indian agro-climatic
data, subscriptions to the combined entity’s digital farming products,
30
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
31
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
32
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
32
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
noted that the primary purpose of the remedy is to preserve the present
independent economic options/choices available to consumers which
would be lost because of the proposed combination, and that modifications
should be such that they allow for the establishment of independent
competitors in the relevant market(s) or strengthening existing
competitor(s) for the concerned markets. Accordingly, the combination
was cleared with certain behavioural remedies which, inter alia, included
white-labelling arrangements with third-parties of five products of the
target for a five-year period; provision of a non-exclusive technology
licence for a further five-year period to one of the third-parties that had
availed of the white-labelling; distribution-related remedies to remove de
facto exclusivity (i.e., deletion of termination clause, discontinuation of
loyalty rebates, etc.); and price cap and commitments in relation to R&D,
exports, and non-rationalisation of L&T products.
The instant case highlights the peculiar/distinct facts and circumstances
of the case, i.e., the highly integrated and indivisible nature of the LV
switchgear industry, and a structural remedy would effectively defeat the
objective of the remedy. Therefore, behavioural remedies were adopted to
create viable, credible, and long-term competitors to address competition
harm. Until now, the CCI’s preferred remedy in horizontal mergers
has been the straightforward divestment or a mixed/hybrid remedy.
However, this is a classic case, wherein CCI has not followed a straitjacket
rule and instead relied on a case-by-case analysis of combination after
considering the peculiarities of each case.
An interesting case of merger control in digital markets with network
effects is the OLA/HMC (2019) case, which involved the acquisition of
a minority stake by Hyundai Motor Company (HMC) and Kia Motors
Corporation (KMC) in ANI technologies Pvt. Ltd. (ANI/ OLA) and Ola
Electric Mobility Private Limited (OEMPL). HMC is engaged in the business
of manufacturing and distribution of automobiles, automobile parts, and
accessories, after-sales services, and R&D of automotive engineering
across several countries. KMC is also engaged in the manufacture of
automobiles, their parts, and accessories, as well as after-sales services
across several countries, and belongs to the HMC group. OLA/ANI is
33
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
34
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
34
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
Taxi Marketplace shall not (i) give preference to the driver based solely
on the brand of passenger vehicle(s) manufactured by the Acquirers or
(ii) discriminate against any driver based solely on the brand of passenger
vehicle(s) manufactured by any other automobile manufacturer (i.e., other
than the Acquirers).
4. Conclusion
Analysis of the data on the type of remedies adopted by six jurisdictions
during 2015–19 shows that the EC and Brazil have made use of “behavioural
remedies” in a significantly higher number of mergers, followed by India
and South Korea, which have shown an increasing inclination towards
such remedies, with a moderate degree of use. USA and Canada, on the
other hand, have been more selective in terms of the remedies they chose
to adopt.
Further, analysis of data on the type of merger/competition concerns
in different jurisdictions highlights that vertical/conglomerate mergers
are more often subjected to behavioural remedies and typically constitute
a longer duration, ranging from 3–8 years and, at times, 20–25 years
depending on the type of behavioural remedy employed. For instance, a
behavioural remedy that constitutes firewalls may be imposed for a fairly
longer duration of 20–25 years (as was done by EC in ASL/Arianespace)
while the imposition of price limits (as in a number of mergers in South
Korea) and access remedies (as in the case of the digital mergers in EC and
number of cases in India) may be imposed for a relatively shorter duration
of 3–8 years.
With regard to the nature of competition harm, the analysis is reflective
of the fact that mergers that give rise to coordinated effects/tacit collusion
may likely lead to sharing of sensitive information between parties to the
detriment of their competitors either in a vertical supply chain or in a
horizontal merger. This adversely affects prices, creates entry barriers, and
hampers innovation at the same time. Behavioural remedies, particularly
the implementation of firewalls, mechanisms of corporate governance,
and imposition of price limits, may be useful in such a scenario, as is
evident from the analysis.
35
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
36
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
36
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
Endnotes
1Referred to as “hybrid/quasi-structural” remedies.
2For
our analysis, we have classified access remedies under behavioural
remedies.
37
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
38
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
References
Administrative Council for Economic Defense (2017). CADE approves with
restrictions the transaction between BM&F Bovespa and Cetip. http://
en.cade.gov.br/press-releases/cade-approves-with-restrictions-the-
transaction-between-bm-f-bovespa-and-cetip
Administrative Council for Economic Defense. (2016). CADE approves with
restrictions joint venture between banks in the sector of credit information
services. http://en.cade.gov.br/press-releases/cade-approves-with-
restrictions-joint-venture-between-banks-in-the-sector-of-credit-infor-
mation-services
Administrative Council for Economic Defense. (2016). CADE approves
with restrictions joint-venture between Saint Gobain and SiCBRAS in
the silicon carbide market. http://en.cade.gov.br/press-releases/
cade-approves-with-restrictions-joint-venture-between-saint-gobain-
and-sicbras-in-the-silicon-carbide-market
Administrative Council for Economic Defense. (2016). CADE approves, with
restrictions, joint venture between Itaú Unibanco and Mastercard. http://
en.cade.gov.br/press-releases/cade-approves-with-restrictions-joint-
venture-between-itau-unibanco-and-mastercard
Administrative Council for Economic Defense. (2016). CADE authorizes
HSBC’s acquisition by Bradesco.” http://en.cade.gov.br/press-releases/
cade-authorizes-hsbc2019s-acquisition-by-bradesco
Administrative Council for Economic Defense. (2017). CADE authorizes the
acquisition of Citibank retail business by Itaú-Unibanco. http://en.cade.
gov.br/press-releases/cade-authorizes-the-acquisition-of-citibank-
retail-business-by-itau-unibanco
Amarnath, A.B. (2013). The oligopoly problem: Structural and behav-
ioural solutions under Indian competition law. Journal of the Indian Law
Institute, 55(3), 283–306. https://www.jstor.org/stable/43953671
Antitrust in Asia – The business impact of fast-evolving competition
laws. (2018). Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer. https://www.freshfields.
38
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
com/49fad8/globalassets/our-thinking/campaigns/antitrust-in-
asia/06304_pg_act_asia-guide_aw_new.pdf
Areeda, P. E., & Hovenkamp, H. (Eds.) (2017). Antitrust Law: An Analysis
of Antitrust Principles and their Application (Vol. I).
Bain, J. S. (1968). Industrial Organisation (2nd ed.). John Wiley & Sons.
Bagwell, K. & Wolinsky, A. (2000). Game theory and industrial Organisation
[Discussion Paper #0102-36]. Columbia University.
Bork, R. H. (1978). The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself. Free
Press.
Chan-ok, S., & Eun-joo, L. (2019). S. Korea’s mega OTT platform Wavve
readies for launch next month. Pulse. https://m.pulsenews.co.kr/view.
php?year=2019&no=646827
Chatterjee, P. & Gautam, S. (2009–12). Competition Law in India Vs USA
and EU. LegalEra. http://www.nishithdesai.com/fileadmin/
user_upload/pdfs/New_Competition_Law_in_India_vs_USA_and_
EU.pdf.
Combination Registration No. C-2015-07-288, Order dated 04.05.2016. (2016).
Competition Commission of India. https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/
default/files/Notice_order_document/C-2015-07-288.pdf
Combination Registration No. C-2016/05/400, Order dated 08.06.2017.
(2017). Competition Commission of India. https://www.cci.gov.in/
sites/default/files/Notice_order_document/Order%20-31_400%20
18.07.2017_Public%20Version%20-%20WebUpload.pdf
Combination Registration No. C-2017/08/523, Order dated 14.06.2018. (2018).
Competition Commission of India. https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/
default/files/Notice_order_document/Order_14.06.2018.pdf
Combination Registration No. C-2018/07/586, Order dated 18.04.2019. (2019).
Competition Commission of India. https://www.cci.gov.in/sites/
default/files/Notice_order_document/Public1.pdf.
39
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
40
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
40
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
41
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
42
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
42
Behavioural Remedies in Oligopolistic Markets …
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
solution/skin/doc.html?fn=7d391fb5cbe9f55e215f040c4e0d0cbf76
90d08c70922bece9bf2cddbebb2f98&rs=/fileupload/data/result/
BBSMSTR_000000002402/
Korea Fair Trade Commission. (2015). Remedies imposed against the proposed
merger deal between Hanwha and Samsung General Chemicals. http://
www.ftc.go.kr/solution/skin/doc.html?fn=bda748a12c261c61e6fa
67222cb669be31b7168c0076ecc6028c62874e180f59&rs=/fileupload/
data/result/BBSMSTR_000000002402/
Korea Fair Trade Commission. (2017). KFTC orders the world’s no. 1 & 7
shipping companies to withdraw from shipping alliances and not to extend the
contract. http://www.ftc.go.kr/solution/skin/doc.html?fn=712051a
ff0ab1df14cb347ca6cf565ca227c085cedb2cf919e8286e2e35a1179&rs=/
fileupload/data/result/BBSMSTR_000000002402/
Maier-Rigaud, F., & Loertscher, B. (2020). Structural vs. behav-
ioral remedies. Competition Policy International. https://www.
competitionpolicyinternational.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/04/
CPI-Maier-Rigaud-Loertscher.pdf
OECD. (2001). Recommendation of the OECD council concerning struc-
tural separation in regulated industries. http://www.oecd.org/daf/
competition/OECD-Recommendation-on-Structural-separation-
regulated-industries.pdf
Posner, R. (1979). The Chicago School of antitrust analysis. University of
Pennsylvania Law Review, 127(4), 925–948.
Turner, D. (1962). The definition of agreement under the Sherman Act:
Conscious parallelism and refusals to deal. Harvard Law Review, 75(4),
655–706. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1338567
Whish, R., & Bailey, D. (2015). Competition Law (8th ed.). Oxford University
Press.
Wilson, T. (2020a). Merger remedies in India: Having an upper
hand. Kluwer Competition Law Blog. http://competitionlawblog.
kluwercompetitionlaw.com/2019/04/01/merger-remedies-in-india-
43
Competition Commission of India Journal on Competition Law and Policy
44
Fair Competition
for Greater Good
having-an-upper-hand/?doing_wp_cron=1591182132.7083458900451
660156250.
Wilson, T. (2020b). Merger remedies – Is it time to go more behavioural.
Kluwer Competition Law Blog. http://competitionlawblog.
kluwercompetitionlaw.com/2020/02/21/merger-remedies-is-it-time-
to-go-more-behavioural/?doing_wp_cron=1591936146.452514886856
0791015625
Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation. (2020). Lines of
business restrictions – Background note. OECD. https://one.oecd.org/
document/DAF/COMP/WP2(2020)1/en/pdf
Yao, D. A., & De Santi, S. (2004). Game theory and the legal analysis of
tacit collusion. Antitrust Bulletin, 38(1).
Young-sin, L., & Jeehyun, C. (2019). SK Broadband gets conditional
approval to merge with t-broad. Pulse. https://pulsenews.co.kr/view.
php?year=2019&no=1099540
44