Computational principles of mobile robotics 2ed. Edition Gregory Dudek pdf download
Computational principles of mobile robotics 2ed. Edition Gregory Dudek pdf download
https://ebookultra.com/download/computational-principles-of-
mobile-robotics-2ed-edition-gregory-dudek/
https://ebookultra.com/download/mobile-robotics-second-edition-jaulin/
https://ebookultra.com/download/computational-physics-2ed-edition-
thijssen-j/
https://ebookultra.com/download/computational-fluid-dynamics-2ed-
edition-chung-t-j/
https://ebookultra.com/download/principles-of-macroeconomics-sixth-
edition-n-gregory-mankiw/
Principles of Microeconomics 7th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw
https://ebookultra.com/download/principles-of-microeconomics-7th-
edition-n-gregory-mankiw/
https://ebookultra.com/download/principles-of-economics-5th-edition-n-
gregory-mankiw/
https://ebookultra.com/download/principles-of-economics-8th-edition-n-
gregory-mankiw/
https://ebookultra.com/download/principles-of-microeconomics-6th-
edition-n-gregory-mankiw/
https://ebookultra.com/download/principles-of-macroeconomics-5th-
edition-n-gregory-mankiw/
Computational principles of mobile robotics 2ed. Edition
Gregory Dudek Digital Instant Download
Author(s): Gregory Dudek; Michael Jenkin
ISBN(s): 9780521871570, 0521871573
Edition: 2ed.
File Details: PDF, 9.84 MB
Year: 2010
Language: english
9780521692120cvr.qxd 6/23/10 4:53 PM Page 1
Jenkin
Dudek
Praise for the first edition of Computational Principles of Mobile Robotics Gregory Dudek and Michael Jenkin
“Technical libraries are well advised to shelve this milestone work. Readers
Principles of
from among upper-division undergraduates, graduates, and researchers
will find a high level of legibility in the writing style, the attractive print
layout, and ample quality illustrations, equations, and photographs.”
– Choice
Mobile Robotics
SECOND EDITION
Mobile robotics is a multidisciplinary field involving both computer science and
engineering. Addressing the design of automated systems, it lies at the intersection
of artificial intelligence, computational vision, and robotics.
Researchers and students in the field of mobile robotics will appreciate this
comprehensive treatment of state-of-the-art methods and key technologies.
GREGORY DUDEK is James McGill Professor of Computer Science and the Director of the
School of Computer Science and of the Mobile Robotics Laboratory at McGill University.
SECOND
EDITION
MICHAEL JENKIN is a Professor of Computer Science and Engineering at York University.
He has coedited eight books on human and machine vision.
Gregory Dudek is James McGill Professor of Computer Science and the Director
of the School of Computer Science and of the Mobile Robotics Laboratory at
McGill University.
A catalog record for this publication is available from the British Library.
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of URLs for external
or third-party Internet Web sites referred to in this publication and does not guarantee that any content
on such Web sites is, or will remain, accurate or appropriate.
For Krys and Heather
Contents
Acknowledgments page xi
Preface to the Second Edition xiii
2 Fundamental Problems 18
2.1 Path Planning for a Point Robot 19
2.2 Localization for a Point Robot 21
2.3 Sensing for a Point Robot 23
2.4 Mapping for a Point Robot 25
2.5 SLAM for a Point Robot 25
2.6 Looking Forward 26
2.7 Further Reading 27
2.8 Problems 27
vii
viii Contents
Bibliography 353
Index 381
Acknowledgments
This book would not have been possible without the active support of our students and
colleagues who suffered through early drafts, provided imagery and papers, and put up
with us while this volume was being put together. The list of people who helped is much too
long to include here, but some require special mention: International Joint Conferences on
Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI), for letting us do a tutorial on mobile robotics that started us
on the journey; students at McGill and York, including Eric Bourque, Andrew Hogue, and
Yiannis Rekleitis, who suffered with photocopies of early drafts; Prof. Evangelos Milios
for his helpful comments and Prof. Evangelos Papadopoulos for his help on space robots;
Rob Sim for his figures; and Louis Dudek for his proofreading and helpful comments.
Finally, we thank Lauren Cowles and Cambridge University Press for encouraging us
do this in the first place.
xi
Preface to the Second Edition
The first edition of this book arose from a tutorial that was initially presented in 1993. It
evolved over a number of years and finally appeared in 2000. Robotics is, of course, a
rapidly changing field, and even as the first edition was appearing, it was apparent that it
would become dated rather quickly. Thus in late 2002, the first steps were taken toward
a second edition.
The field of mobile robotics continues to evolve, and this book has (we hope) evolved
with the field. Topics that were in their infancy when the first edition was published – such
as SLAM and multi-robot systems – have evolved into much more mature disciplines.
The mathematical foundations of much of mobile robotics has also matured, and this too
is reflected in this volume. In addition to updating the various algorithms and methods
described in the first edition, the second edition is somewhat more self-contained. Specif-
ically, various mathematical techniques that were assumed in the first edition are now
introduced, albeit briefly, in appendices at the end of the text.
xiii
Random documents with unrelated
content Scribd suggests to you:
approximated at $260 per year per man, boy and porter, who two years ago
numbered 621,341.
In 1907, Special Agent Ames, of the Interstate Commerce Commission,
reported wages on the railways of the United Kingdom as follows:
Number and Pay of German Railway Employes by Principal Divisions for the
Year Ending December 31, 1908.
Increase
Employes Compensation Average
Division over
Number (Total) per year
1907
Combined with a falling off in revenues and an increase in the cost of materials
this increase in the compensation of employes had the effect of raising the
operating ratio of German railways from 69.01 in 1907 to 73.56 in 1908. It also
increased the proportion of wages to gross earnings from 37.25 to 40.1% and
had the effect of reducing the net revenues from 5.60% to 4.51% on the cost of
construction.
How railway labor fares under government ownership in a republic as
compared with its pay in an empire may be judged from a comparison of the
following statement as to the number and pay of the railways of Switzerland with
the like classes in the preceding table for Germany.
The wages paid the employes of Swiss railways in 1907 amounted to only 31.9
per cent. of the gross earnings, and yet they added enough to the cost of
operation to help increase the telltale ratio of expenses to revenues from 64.99
in 1906 to 67.29 in 1907. The result was increased operating expenses per mile
and a decrease in the amount available for interest in dividends from 3.26% in
1906 to 3.23% in 1907.
As the Swiss republic has to pay 3½% on government loans its investment in
railways does not appear to be a very profitable one.
While it is scarcely believable that many American families with incomes under
$200 spent less than $100 a year on food—the European percentage in such
cases being more credible—there is no reason to question the general economic
law reflected in this table, that "the proportion of income spent on food
diminishes as the income increases." But it is governed more by individual
tendencies, character and taste than by any rule or principle. Each family works
out the problem on its own account.
According to the evidence presented at recent arbitration hearings in this city,
American switchmen, as a body, belong in the classes whose family expenditures
are $1,000 or over. Irrespective of the incomes of other members of their
families, the arbitrators found "that the actual monthly earnings of switchmen in
the Chicago district, for those who worked full time runs from about $80 to $100
per month." This means over $1,000 yearly compensation. Therefore they are in
the class which spends less than 39% of its income on food.
The average income for all railway employes engaged in train service, that is,
enginemen, firemen, conductors and other trainmen, is probably above the
highest figure in the foregoing table and therefore the proportion of their income
spent for food would be approximately 36%.
But accepting 40% as approximately the proportion of the pay of all railway
employes spent on food, it follows that it takes only two-fifths of one per cent
increase in wages to take care of an increase of one per cent in the price of food.
With this in mind it becomes instructive to follow the retail prices of the
various articles of food as selected by Mr. Wright in his inquiry into the cost of
living in 1901 and adopted by the Bureau of Labor in subsequent Bulletins. These
for thirty articles of food for the eighteen years 1890 to 1907, as given in Bulletin
No. 77 of the Bureau of Labor, and for the two years 1908-1909 as computed
from Bradstreet's index and other sources of commodity prices, are given in the
following statement relatively to the average price for 1890 to 1899 == 100:
Milk,
Corn Fish, Fish, Flour, Fresh, Mola‐ Pork,
Year Eggs Lard Mutton Fresh
Meal Fresh Salt Wheat unski‐ sses
mmed
1890 100.0 100.6 99.3 100.7 109.7 98.2 100.5 104.7 100.7 97.0
1891 109.7 106.9 99.6 101.7 112.5 99.8 100.5 101.7 100.6 98.7
1892 105.2 106.8 100.1 102.2 105.1 103.6 100.6 101.2 101.0 100.5
1893 103.1 108.1 100.1 103.4 96.1 117.9 100.4 100.6 99.9 107.0
1894 102.2 96.3 100.4 101.5 88.7 106.9 100.2 100.3 97.8 101.8
1895 100.8 99.3 99.8 98.9 89.0 100.1 100.0 99.0 98.7 99.7
1896 95.0 92.8 100.2 97.5 92.7 92.5 99.9 98.7 98.7 97.4
1897 93.7 91.4 99.8 95.2 104.3 89.8 99.7 97.7 99.6 97.6
1898 95.0 96.2 100.5 98.8 107.4 93.9 99.4 97.9 100.4 98.6
1899 95.1 101.1 100.2 100.2 94.6 97.1 98.9 98.2 102.6 101.7
1900 97.4 99.9 100.4 99.1 94.3 104.4 99.9 102.2 105.6 107.7
1901 107.1 105.7 101.4 100.9 94.4 118.1 101.1 101.3 109.0 117.9
1902 118.8 119.1 105.0 102.8 94.9 134.3 103.3 102.1 114.7 128.3
1903 120.7 125.3 107.3 108.4 101.2 126.7 105.8 103.8 112.6 127.0
1904 121.5 130.9 107.9 111.7 119.9 117.3 106.3 104.0 114.1 124.0
1905 122.2 131.6 109.9 113.8 119.9 116.6 107.0 104.4 117.8 126.6
1906 123.2 134.2 116.2 116.8 180.1 128.0 108.9 105.3 124.1 137.7
1907 131.6 137.7 120.6 121.6 117.7 134.2 116.8 107.7 130.1 142.5
1908 154.0 140.2 116.2 118.4 140.0 132.1 115.4 102.2 126.4 141.6
1909 160 142.2 120.4 122.6 154.4 153.8 141.6 106.4 134.8 168.2
Pork,
Pork, Pork, Potat‐
Salt, Vine‐
Year Salt, Salt, oes, Prunes Rice Sugar Tea Veal
dry or gar
Bacon Ham Irish
pickled
1890 95.8 95.3 98.7 109.3 116.8 101.3 118.6 100.0 98.8 102.9
1891 96.6 98.9 99.3 116.6 116.5 102.5 102.7 100.4 99.6 105.5
1892 99.1 100.5 101.9 95.7 113.5 101.3 96.2 100.2 100.0 102.7
1893 109.0 108.7 109.3 112.3 115.6 98.4 101.5 100.1 100.0 99.5
1894 103.6 103.4 101.9 102.6 100.9 99.0 93.8 98.7 98.7 99.8
1895 99.4 99.2 98.8 91.8 94.2 98.8 91.8 98.5 98.5 98.9
1896 96.7 95.5 97.6 77.0 86.8 96.7 96.6 98.8 99.5 97.2
1897 97.4 97.3 98.2 93.0 84.3 97.9 95.7 98.5 99.9 97.4
1898 100.2 99.1 95.1 105.4 86.3 101.7 101.3 100.7 101.2 97.9
1899 102.9 101.8 99.2 96.1 85.1 102.4 101.7 104.4 103.7 98.3
1900 109.7 107.7 105.3 93.5 83.0 102.4 104.9 105.5 104.9 98.5
1901 121.0 117.5 110.2 116.8 82.6 103.5 103.0 106.7 108.8 98.9
1902 135.6 132.5 119.4 117.0 83.4 103.5 96.1 106.0 114.9 99.1
1904 137.9 125.8 118.4 121.3 79.6 101.6 101.9 105.8 115.5 98.9
1905 138.8 126.0 118.5 110.2 81.4 102.6 98.2 105.5 123.2 102.6
1907 157.3 141.2 130.7 120.6 88.4 108.5 99.6 105.3 125.0 104.5
1908 142.4 137.4 112.0 138.4 — 105.1 100.0 108.6 124.2 112.4
1909 180.0 151.2 145.0 120.0 — 103.3 105.0 109.0 130.2 113.0
No authority is claimed for the prices in these tables for the years 1908 and
1909. They merely represent the tendencies in those years, as found in official
and unofficial wholesale prices of the several commodities, and there are often
striking divergences between wholesale and retail prices over short periods.
Eventually they follow the same course, although not always in the same
proportion.
Now let us see how the average retail price of these 30 articles of food
compares with the average daily pay of the four representative classes of railway
employes in train service for the ten years 1899 to 1909.
The amazing feature of this statement is that the United States produces and
exports to the United Kingdom enormous quantities of breadstuffs, meat and
provisions, which constitute the chief articles of food in London and which are
sold there at prices from 20% to 25% lower than in New York. Clearly it is the
high scale of wages that fosters the high cost of living in the United States and
there can be little question but it breeds the high wages it feeds on.
It is humanly certain, though economically unsound, that wages will continue
to advance with the cost of living and will not recede proportionately as prices of
food fall. But both will decline together when for any considerable period there is
a surplus of efficient labor for the requirements of American industry. Even
railway labor in the most stable of all employments yielded to this influence in
1893 and 1894; and the prices of food receded to the low mark in the following
years 1895, 1896 and 1897. Not until wages took their upward turn in 1898 did
the cost of food begin to show above the index average of 1890-1899.
IV
CAPITALIZATION
According to the Twenty-third Annual Report of the Interstate Commerce
Commission the amount of railway capital, including stocks and bonds
"outstanding in the hands of the public on June 30, 1908, was $12,840,091,462,
which, if assigned on a mileage basis, shows a capitalization of $57,230 per mile
of line."
In the face of all the fustian about over-capitalization of American railways, this
is a most remarkable admission, not only of their moderate, but of their
decreasing capitalization per mile.
In its report on the Intercorporate Relationships of Railways, dated March 10,
1908, the Commission found that as the result of its investigation the figure for
railway capital outstanding in the hands of the public, "Measuring the claim of
railway securities on railway revenues," reduced the amount "from $67,936 per
mile of line (1906) to $58,050 per mile of line."
Of course there was never any justification for using the larger sum as a true
measure of railway capitalization, for it was known to contain at least 15%
duplicated capital.
In its Statistics of Railways for the year ending June 30, 1907, the Commission
gave the net amount of railway capital outstanding in the hands of the public at
that date, "assigned on a mileage basis as $58,298 per mile of line," or $1,068
more than the figure reported for 1908.
As the computation for 1908 was made on a basis of 224,363 miles of line, this
would indicate a shrinkage of no less than $239,616,480 in the par value of
railway capital. It is needless to say there was no such shrinkage.
Capitalization
1909
(182,046 Miles Owned)
Capital stock $6,199,919,551
Funded debt 8,015,841,805
Receivers' certificates 20,497,447
$14,236,258,803
Rental of 39,086 miles, $120,784,982, capitalized at
5%. 2,415,699,640
Total $16,651,958,443
Deduct:(a)
Railway stocks owned (actual value) $1,889,157,214
Other stocks owned (actual value) 206,461,423
Railway bonds owned (actual value) 1,054,095,905
Other bonds owned (actual value) 140,282,728
3,289,997,270
(a) The par value of these stocks and bonds owned is given as $4,739,231,832.
An estimate of $25,000 per mile for the 11,870 miles of line not reporting to
this Bureau would add $296,750,000 to the above total. From this should be
deducted $150,000,000 for the sum assigned by the Official Statistician "to other
properties," and we arrive at the following close approximation of the true
measure of the capital employed in the transportation industry of the United
States:
This $724,483,163 is the balance in the hands of the 368 companies of the
moneys received by them from transportation, or, as the Official Statistician now
calls it, "rail operations," for the payment of interest, rent, other deductions,
dividends, additions and betterments, reserves, surplus and deficits. But before
proceeding to this distribution these companies received $200,725,696 income
from other sources, principally interest and dividends on stocks and bonds
owned and for rent of track, and a net balance of $5,410,338 from outside
operations. The total of these two sums, $206,136,034, may be arbitrarily
applied first to offset the item of rent, $120,784,982, paid for leased lines and
track, and the balance in payment of interest and dividends in proportion to the
value of bonds and stocks owned as above, viz.: 36% and 64%, respectively.
This enables us to make the following distribution of the net operating income
of the railways reporting to this Bureau, as follows:
This table shows the actual disposition made of the net income from operation
of the roads reporting to this Bureau, representing 97% of the railway business
of the United States, except that $120,784,982 of the income from other sources
has been eliminated from the account and applied to offset the rental paid by the
reporting roads.
It will be observed that the gross dividends declared were only $226,791,289,
which is 3.64% on the par value of the stock of the 368 reporting companies.
Misrepresentations as to Dividends.
The discrepancy between this condition and the official statement as to
dividends declared in 1908 calls for an analysis of the latter. This reads, "The
amount of dividends declared during the year (1908) was $386,879,362, being
equivalent to 7.99% on dividend-paying stock. For the year ending June 30,
1907, the amount of dividends declared was $308,088,027."
Two income accounts—one of operating roads and the other of leased roads—
for the year ending June 30, 1908, give a clew as to how the Official Statistician
more than doubles the dividends actually paid out of transportation revenues.
The gross total is made up of these four items:
Operating roads:
Dividends declared from current income $271,328,453
Dividends declared out of surplus 57,733,808
Leased roads:
Dividends declared from current income 33,843,577
Dividends declared out of surplus 27,550,596
Total $390,456,434
This total was equivalent to 4.15% on the net capitalization of the roads
represented. The rental paid the lessor roads constituted the fund from which
those roads paid their interest and dividends. Further remark on the misleading
and harmful statement of the Official Statistician as to dividends declared in 1908
is unnecessary.
V
COST OF CONSTRUCTION
Incomplete as are the figures of the cost of the railways of the United States,
and exclusive as they are of the millions put back into the properties out of
income for additions, betterments and reconstruction in the process of operation,
yet the statistics of the cost of construction and equipment afford a complete
answer to all charges that American railways are over-capitalized.
Upon the question of the cost of road and equipment in 1909, the returns of
the 368 roads reporting to this Bureau furnish the following data:
Item Amount
Cost of road (182,046 miles owned) $6,603,504,463
Cost of equipment 1,122,409,813
Undistributed cost of road and equipment 3,080,064,960
Cost of 39,086 miles leased lines rental capitalized 2,415,699,876
Total $13,220,678,876
$13,417,438,876
as the cost of road and equipment of the 233,002 miles of line employed in the
transportation industry of the United States in 1909, or
Capitalization Valuation by
Miles of Line
per Mile State, per Mile
Minnesota, 1907 7,596 $44,206 $54,201
Washington, 1908:
Great Northern 806 44,078 73,900
Northern Pacific 942 70,278 106,500
Oregon R. R. & Navigation Co 501 43,012 38,900
Wisconsin, 1906 7,135 33,424 34,630
Even Senator Albert B. Cummins of Iowa has seen such a bright light on this
subject that in his speech before the Traffic Club of Chicago last February he said
that he would not be willing to make a present valuation of railroad property a
basis for determining rates, "for the reason that it was more than probable that
the present capitalization of between fifteen and sixteen billions would be
increased to twenty billions."
In the Bureau's Statistics for 1908 it was said:
"If the valuations in Minnesota and Washington, made by none too friendly
commissions, are any criterions of what a national valuation made under
presumably unbiased federal authority would be, the present cost to reproduce
the railways of the United States would be nearer $20,000,000,000 than any sum
within the anticipations of those agitating for such valuation."
Capitalization of Foreign Railways.
With both sides of the balance sheet testifying to a capital investment in
American railways of under $60,000, and official valuation abandoned because it
would demonstrate that they could not be reproduced for less than $80,000 per
mile, the reader is asked to compare the American figures with those of the
capitalization, or cost of construction, of the principal foreign countries set forth
below. These have been compiled from the latest available official returns.
Capital or Cost of
Year Country Miles of Line
Construction Per Mile
Europe:
1908 United Kingdom 23,205 $6,382,296,742 $275,040
1908 Germany 35,558 3,903,848,400 109,788
Russia in Europe (exclusive
1907 80,985
of Finland) 32,900 (a)3,170,876,360
1907 France (b)24,730 3,447,366,000 139,390
1907 Austria 13,427 1,515,576,885 112,879
1907 Hungary 11,769 741,586,391 63,010
1907-
124,730
08 Italy (State roads only) 8,699 1,086,000,000
1905 Spain (13 roads) 6,840 583,632,000 85,327
1906 Sweden 7,938 257,408,450 32,427
1907 Belgium (State only) 2,537 430,800,000 169,806
1907 Switzerland 2,740 298,709,210 109,000
Other Countries:
1909 Canada 24,104 1,608,990,656 66,752
1908 British India 30,576 1,364,669,375 44,632
1907 Argentine Republic 13,690 820,433,796 59,930
1908 Japan 4,444 190,173,728 42,800
1909 United States of America 233,002 13,508,711,173 57,976
(a) Russian capitalization, including railways in Asia, covers a total of 39,277 miles,
from which the capital per mile is computed.
(b) This is exclusive of 4,259 miles of local interest.
The most striking feature in this table is the steady advance it shows in the
capital cost of German railways. In ten years this has increased from 251,597
marks per kilometer in 1898 to 283,608 in 1908, i. e. 31,731 marks per kilometer
or $12,282 per mile. This means an increase of $991,687,440 in capital cost for
an increase of only 5,525 miles of line.
VI
Number Number of
Year
Reporting Stockholders
If the ownership of railway bonds, which is even more widely distributed than
that of stocks, could be traced, it would be found that over a million investors are
interested in the financial welfare of the railways. This would give to each an
interest of $13,000, from which the average income is not over $520 a year.
The attempt of the Commission in 1908 to secure evidence that the control of
the railways was concentrated in a few hands by calling for a statement of the
"ten largest holders of voting securities" of the reporting companies having
established that nowhere did they own a majority or an approach to a majority
of the controlling stock, inquiry along that line was dropped in 1909.
In railways, as in any republic, the latent power is widely distributed among
the many, while the administrative responsibility is necessarily entrusted to the
few.
VII
Here it is shown that the passenger service rendered has increased 12%
more than the passenger revenues. But more significant than this is the
column of yearly increases in service by percentages. This utterly explodes
the theory that passenger travel is greatly stimulated by low fares—aside
from some positive incentive to increased travel, such as periodical
expositions, the Louisiana Purchase Exposition for instance, the effect of
which is clearly traceable in the increased service in 1905, which includes
the heavy travel during the months of heavy attendance, July 1 to
December 1, 1904.
The 2-cent passenger laws were passed so as to become generally
effective July 1, 1907, and their effect on passenger receipts during the
following year was such that these receipts were actually less in 1909 than
in 1907, although the service performed by the railways was over 6%
greater. Had the railways received the same rate in 1909 that they did in
1907 their revenue from passengers would have been nearly $29,000,000
more than it was.
Average
Passengers Mileage Receipts
Passengers Average Average Passenger
Carried Passenger per
Year Carried Passengers Journey Revenue
One Mile Trains Passenger
(Millions) in Train Miles (Millions)
(Millions) (Millions) Mile
(Cents)
The several increases shown in the first, second, third and sixth columns
of the table reflect the general advancement in passenger traffic. That of
45% in the average passengers to a train marks the progress in density of
that traffic which may eventually place it on a profitable basis. In
Massachusetts, where this density yields an average of 79 passengers to a
train there is no demand for a two-cent rate statute, for the conditions have
made a rate of 1.64 cents profitable. In the group of states consisting of
Ohio, Indiana, Michigan, Illinois, Iowa, Wisconsin and Minnesota, where the
density of traffic yields only 46 passengers by train, a statutory two-cent
fare becomes confiscatory because it costs at least one dollar to operate a
passenger train one mile and 46 times two cents is only 92 cents. Moreover
the 46 passengers per train is only an average and there are as many trains
that average less as more. The average has to be raised above 50 to yield
any margin of profit on passenger traffic. If it were not for the density of
traffic in the New England and North Atlantic group of states the average for
the entire United States would be well below 46 passengers per train.
The steady increase in the distance traveled per passenger reflects the
effect of trolley competition in diverting the short haul passenger traffic.
The most noteworthy feature of the seventh column is the decline of
98/1000ths of a cent in the average receipts per passenger mile between
1907 and 1909, making a new low record after hovering around the two
cent mark for fourteen years. As noted above, this reduction in the average
cost the railways nearly $29,000,000 on the passenger traffic of 1909.
In this connection it is interesting to recall that between 1888 and 1893
the Official Statistician, then as now Professor Adams, made the following
computation of the average cost of carrying one passenger one mile for the
whole United States:
It will be observed that the average receipts per passenger mile in 1909
are below the computed cost in every one of the years above named,
except 1891. When the advance in the cost of everything necessary to the
service—track, labor, equipment, conveniences, speed, terminal facilities—is
considered, the practical coincidence of average cost and receipts leaves no
margin for legitimate profits.
Mail Express
Percentage Percentage
Year Revenues of Revenues of
Earnings Earnings
Annual
Transportation Number of
Postal
of Mail by Railway
Revenues
Railroads Mail Clerks
(Miles)
Compared with the increase of only 41.5% in the revenues from mail
received by the railways during the same period, each one of the above
percentages testifies to a positive reduction in the rate received by the
railways for the service. And if the increase in weight of mail carried in 1909
were known, the contrast between the service and the pay would be more
striking. In 1899 the total weight of all mail was reported as 635,180,362
pounds. In 1907 the estimates made from the special weighing placed the
weight of mail carried that year at 1,290,358,284 pounds, or an increase of
nearly 105% in eight years. By reference to the above table it will be seen
that the railway revenues from mail between 1899 and 1907 increased only
40%. The contrast is illuminating. In its light the charge that the railways
are in any way responsible for the postal deficit is grotesque.
Freight Traffic
According to the monthly returns to the Interstate Commerce
Commission, the proportion of revenues from freight of the railways of the
United States to total earnings from operation, for the years 1908 and 1909,
receded to the unusually low figures of 68.51% and 68.88% respectively.
The official summary for 1908, based on the annual returns, shows a
proportion of 69.17% for that year, which probably is nearer the mark.
The annual reports to this Bureau for 1909 yield a proportion of 69.18%
for last year.
Accepting this proportion taken from the annual returns as being based
on the same character of reports as those from which former ratios were
derived, the preponderance of freight traffic is shown in bold relief in the
following statement of the ratio of its revenues to total earnings from
operation, 1899 to 1909:
Proportion of Proportion of
Freight Freight
Year Year
Revenues to Revenues to
Total Earnings Total Earnings
The average proportion for the nine years preceding 1908 is seen to be
slightly above 70%, and the fact that it was almost one point below 70% in
1908 and 1909 indicates that it was the freight traffic that bore the brunt of
the business depression which curtailed railway revenues during those
years.
In no other of the leading countries of the world does the freight traffic
assume the overwhelming relative proportion that it does in the United
States. In the United Kingdom it amounts to 50.35%; in France to 53.64%;
and in Germany, including express and mail, to 65%. If these were classed
with freight in the United States, it would raise the proportion for that traffic
here to over 74%.
Welcome to our website – the ideal destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. With a mission to inspire endlessly, we offer a
vast collection of books, ranging from classic literary works to
specialized publications, self-development books, and children's
literature. Each book is a new journey of discovery, expanding
knowledge and enriching the soul of the reade
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
ebookultra.com