Kochan Riordan 2016 Employment Relations and Growing Income Inequality Causes and Potential Options For Its Reversal
Kochan Riordan 2016 Employment Relations and Growing Income Inequality Causes and Potential Options For Its Reversal
Christine A Riordan
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, USA
Abstract
The growth of income inequality is now recognized to be one of the most important
developments in employment relations of our time. While inequality has increased in
many parts of the world, it has been most pronounced in the United States. We review
the factors that have been suggested to cause the growth in inequality and, given these
multiple causes, suggest a set of actions that might begin to reverse this trend. We give
special attention to the changes in the employment relationship related to labor market
institutions – including unions and other forms of worker representation, wage regu-
lations and enforcement, and safety net policy – while also accounting for explanations
and proposals that focus on technology, skills and education, and globalization.
Additionally, we argue that emerging forms of organizational restructuring are becoming
increasingly important to the study of inequality and its remedies.
Keywords
Globalization, income inequality, labor market institutions, organizations, skills and
education, wage policies
Corresponding author:
Thomas A Kochan, Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 100 Main Street,
E62-334, Cambridge, MA 02142, USA.
Email: [email protected]
420 Journal of Industrial Relations 58(3)
Introduction
The growth of income inequality is now recognized to be one of the most important
developments in employment relations of our time. While inequality has increased
in many parts of the world, it has been most pronounced in the United States. In
this article, we will review the factors that are suggested to cause the growth in
inequality and, given these multiple causes, suggest a set of actions that might begin
its reversal, with particular emphasis on the employment relationship and labor
market institutions. While we focus mostly on the US, we place the discussion in a
broader global context.
Figure 2. Decomposing the top decile US income shares into three groups, 1917–2014.
Source: Piketty and Saez (2007 [2015]).
Figure 3. The growing gap between productivity and workers’ hourly compensation,
1948–2014.
Source: Economic Policy Institute analysis of data from Bureau of Economic Analysis’ National
Income and Product Accounts and the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Consumer Price Indexes and
Labor and Productivity Costs (Bivens and Mishel, 2015).
Globalization
The next favorite explanation was globalization and the related decline of the
American manufacturing sector: since 1980, the US has lost just over one-third
of its manufacturing jobs. A number of studies have shown that workers displaced
from manufacturing jobs who regain employment experience wage reductions of
20% or more (Holzer et al., 2011: 125). A different study documents numerous
negative effects – declining wages, significant increases in income transfer pay-
ments, higher unemployment, and larger reductions in labor force participation –
experienced in communities exposed to increased import competition from China
(Autor et al., 2013). These community effects are more persistent than economic
theory would predict: the same study found relatively little geographic mobility
among those displaced. More recently, offshoring undertaken by US firms during
the 2002–2008 period has been shown to advantage higher-skilled (and higher-
paid) workers who undertake relatively more abstract and communication-depen-
dent tasks in their jobs (Oldenski, 2014).
Minimum wages. The first institutional feature thoroughly examined was the decline
in purchasing power of the national minimum wage. The current US$7.25 per hour
federal minimum stands at about 25% below the purchasing power of the min-
imum wage at its peak in 1968, which, had it kept up with inflation, would cur-
rently stand at approximately US$10.94 per hour.
The decline of the federal minimum wage’s real value is particularly deleterious
to those at the bottom of the wage distribution – historically, this has been espe-
cially so for women, who were less likely to be employed in unionized industries
upon their entrance to the labor market in the 1980s (DiNardo et al., 1996; Lee,
1999; Lemieux, 1993). Fortin and Lemieux (1997) estimate that had the real value
of the minimum wage in 1979 been maintained in 1988, the variance in female log
wages would have increased by 32.1% less than it actually did, compared to the
24.2% lesser increase in men’s wage dispersion under the same conditions. These
trends changed markedly during the 1990s and 2000s, when explosive growth of
top incomes became the primary driver of disparity in income (Lemieux, 2008).
Even so, the minimum wage is still an important institutional feature affecting
inequality, particularly among those at the bottom of the US wage distribution.
Decline in unions and bargaining power. More recently, scholars have recognized that
decline in unions and worker bargaining power account for a sizable portion of the
problem. By 1980, union membership had been declining slowly for two decades,
and international competition was eating away at unionized manufacturing firms.
Membership’s abrupt and steep decline in the early 1980s – initiated by the Federal
Reserve’s efforts to break the back of rampant inflation; a harder management line
against unions, signaled by President Reagan’s firing of striking air traffic control-
lers; a deep recession; and the growth of non-union domestic competition – per-
sisted for the following three decades.
Tables 1 and 2 report previously unpublished data from research regarding the
changes in industrial relations in the 1980s (Kochan et al., 1986). Specifically, we
show that collective bargaining outcomes changed after 1980 due to a decline in the
power derived from strikes, centralized bargaining, and informal pattern bargain-
ing arrangements that spread negotiated wage settlements within local labor mar-
kets and industries. The analysis is based on regressions on wage changes
negotiated in collective bargaining units in manufacturing firms with 1000 or
more employees from 1957 to 1984. As Table 1 shows, prior to 1980, the coeffi-
cients on strikes, centralized (firm-wide rather than single plant-level) negotiations
426
Multi-plant, single firm structures .0039** (.0012) .0037** (.0012) .0058** (.0012) .0055** (.0012) .0067 (.0038) .0067 (.0039)
Multi-firm structures .0042** (.0013) .0043** (.0014) .0046** (.0014) .0046** (.0014) .0031 (.0043) .0028 (.0043)
Region-wide pattern bargaining .0046** (.0013) .0050** (.0014) .0036** (.0014) .0039** (.0014) .0085* (.0043) .0090* (.0043)
Industry-wide pattern bargaining .0045** (.0014) .0046** (.0014) .0043** (.0015) .0042** (.0014) .0057 (.0046) .0063 (.0046)
Strike 1–14 days .0075* (.0031) .0080** (.0030) .0039 (.0157)
Strike 15–24 days .0054 (.0046) .0020 (.0046) .0164 (.0158)
Strike 25 or more days .0052** (.0019) .0060** (.0019) .0029 (.0072)
R2 .50 .50 .55 .55 .31 .30
All equations in Tables 1 and 2 contain controls for changes in rates of inflation, employment growth/decline, unemployment and presence/absence of wage and price
guidelines or controls. Standard errors in parentheses.
Note: *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001.
Journal of Industrial Relations 58(3)
Kochan and Riordan 427
and regional and intra-industry pattern bargaining were positive and significant. In
contrast, from 1980 to 1984 (the last year these data were collected), the coefficients
are mostly either insignificant or negative.
The data in Table 2 show that overall, the model of wage determination under
collective bargaining that dominated in the 1957–1979 time period over-predicted
wage settlements in the early 1980s by 1.35% and, consistent with the results shown
in Table 1, over-predicted wage changes more in units with centralized bargaining
structures and intra-industry pattern bargaining traditions. Thus, the key sources
of power that unions used to increase wages and spread these gains within indus-
tries had declined. This decline is substantial: extrapolating from these findings, if
the magnitude of these wage outcomes persisted in bargaining, the 1.35% estimate
would account for nearly 20% of the difference in growth of productivity and
wages from 1980 through 2015. Although imprecise, this is in the same range as
more recent studies of the effects of union decline.
Similarly, Erickson (1992, 1996) documents the demise in the 1980s of specific
union contract clauses that had helped maintain pattern bargaining within and
across the aerospace, automobile, and agricultural implement industries.
Freeman (1980, 1982) also shows that leading up to the 1980s, unions played an
important role in reducing wage inequality within organizations, finding that the
dispersion of wages within unionized organizations of different industries ranged
from 5% to 50% lower than that found within non-unionized organizations.
Using more recent data, Western and Rosenfeld (2011) estimate the decline in
unionization accounts for as much as 20% to 30% of the rise in wage inequality
since the 1980s. The impact is strongest among less educated and blue collar men –
a group for whom unions reduced inequality prior to the 1980s by mitigating the
deleterious effects of a falling minimum wage (Freeman, 1993; Western and
Rosenfeld, 2011).
Deteriorating labor enforcement regimes and safety net. The absence of unions has yet a
different effect in low-wage sectors, where they have traditionally acted as a deter-
rent against wage theft and other labor standards violations that contribute to
inequality (Wright and Brown, 2013). A 2008 survey of over 4000 low-wage
428 Journal of Industrial Relations 58(3)
workers in the cities of Chicago, Los Angeles, and New York found that approxi-
mately 67.5% of respondents – who worked in non-union car washes, retail and
food service, and domestic work, among other sectors – faced wage reductions
through violations in the prior week. These included underpayment of wages,
lack of overtime pay, or working off the clock, and cost them nearly US$3000 in
wages over a year of full-time work (Bernhardt et al., 2013).
Compounding the problem is weakened enforcement capacity of the state, an
issue that has been observed in many countries (ILO, 2006). In the US, the number
of workers and establishments covered by the Fair Labor Standards Act has risen
steadily over the last two decades, yet the number of inspectors in the Department
of Labor has simultaneously declined (Weil, 2014). Enforcement of wage standards
is also hindered by the fact that 70% of wage and hour investigations result from
worker complaints (Weil, 2008), even though evidence suggests there is a mismatch
between industries where complaints are made and where violations are most com-
monplace (Weil and Pyles, 2005).
US social policy relevant to the safety net – as measured by social insurance and
the payroll and income tax systems, both of which grant access to safety net pro-
grams through employment – is the weakest among Organization for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries. By 2000, the US was spending
the least among this group in income transfers and cash social transfers for the
non-elderly (Smeeding, 2005). These weak safety net programs indirectly affect
growing inequality, as observed through the lack of paid family leave (Ray
et al., 2009) or work-sharing (Appelbaum, 2012), or the low rates of take-up of
unemployment insurance (DeNavas-Walt and Proctor, 2014; Schaefer, 2010).
firms (Appelbaum and Batt, 2014; Lazonick, 2009), (2) new models for pricing
stock options became available, leading firms to increase the portion of CEO
pay tied to share price improvements (Black and Scholes, 1973; Merton, 1971),
and (3) finance considerations dominated in corporate decision-making as the
pressures from Wall Street agents increased and the countervailing power of
unions declined (Jacoby, 2004; Useem, 1993). These developments in turn led to
growing inequality as gains were diverted from the full labor force to shareholders
and corporate officers. Although estimates vary, economists calculate that the cur-
rent ratio of CEO to average hourly worker pay is now approximately 300:1,
compared to only 20:1 in the 1960s (Mishel and Davis, 2015).
ambiguity over which employer is responsible for managing and controlling employ-
ees, and where there are workers misclassified as independent contractors (Kalleberg
et al., 2000). Studies in other countries have likewise demonstrated that a range of
human resource practices typically found in firms are either less likely to exist or to
be constrained by the same uncertainty of which employer is responsible for mana-
ging the workforce in networked organizations (Marchington et al., 2011).
Limited adoption and diffusion of high-road business models. A large body of empirical
research has documented the positive effects of sets of workplace practices labeled
‘high-performance work systems’ on productivity and other indicators of organ-
izational performance (Appelbaum et al., 2011). These work systems in turn are
supported by so-called high-road business strategies that compete on the basis of
achieving high productivity and service quality rather than by minimizing and
tightly controlling labor costs. The evidence on the relationship among these stra-
tegies and practices and wages is, however, somewhat mixed (Osterman, 1994):
positive wage effects are more likely to be experienced in unionized than non-
unionized firms (Bailey et al., 2001). Moreover, while there are case examples in
almost all industries of high-road firms that pay above-average wages (e.g.
Appelbaum et al., 2000; Cascio, 2006; Hoffer Gittell, 2003; Kochan et al., 2009;
Ton, 2014), the reality is these strategies have not widely diffused across American
industry. The mental model that labor is a cost to be minimized continues to
dominate the behavior of many business decision-makers and analysts. If the
hypothesis is correct that these high-road strategies and workplace practices are
necessary conditions for achieving the high productivity needed to support high
and increasing wages, the limited diffusion of these strategies and practices may
serve as another cause of wage stagnation.
Minimum and living wages. Starting in the 1990s, advocates have relied on minimum
and living wage campaigns to raise the wage floor in localities, cities, and states. By
many measures, these have been effective both in raising wages for those paid at the
minimum and those directly above them in the wage structure (Wicks-Lim, 2006).
Twenty-nine states currently have minimum wage levels that are higher than the fed-
eral minimum; of these, 15 have indexed their minimum wages to inflation. A growing
number of cities – such as San Francisco, CA and Seattle, WA – have followed suit,
and have recently passed or are pursuing legislation to increase their local minimum
wage to US$15 per hour over a number of years. Advocates also increasingly rely on
living wage campaigns; currently, over 140 cities and counties have enacted such laws
(Bernhardt and Osterman, 2016). Despite their spread, however, many of these poli-
cies cover a limited range of jobs – often work purchased or in other ways regulated by
local governments or part of local economic development efforts – and thus have
limited capacity to generate large-scale patterns of change.
Yet, in a hopeful sign, demands for change to the federal minimum wage are
flourishing at the national level. In many respects, these demands have been led by
workers and labor unions. The now-international ‘Fight for 15’ is one such example,
rooted in early efforts among fast-food workers to increase wages and realize the right
to organize in fissured work settings. Such efforts have effectively brought worker
voice and demands addressing wage inequality front and center within the Obama
Administration and among candidates of the upcoming 2016 US presidential election.
For instance, advocates in San Francisco, CA successfully created a new city entity,
the Office of Labor Standards Enforcement (OLSE), in 2001. The OLSE uses
innovative cross-agency information-sharing and enforcement strategies to address
wage violations and other labor standards infractions. To date, it has recovered over
US$17m in back wages and collected over US$2m in employer penalties (Dietz et al.,
2014). Notably, the OLSE also increases the effectiveness of enforcement activities
by directly engaging with community-based and worker organizations, a best prac-
tice documented in the literature (Fine and Gordon, 2010).
At a national level, the Obama Administration has proposed increased coverage
of salaried workers for overtime work, while also issuing a clarifying administrative
letter detailing the criteria for worker classification as an employee or an independ-
ent contractor (which determines coverage under wage and overtime rules). The
National Labor Relations Board has likewise issued a recent decision broadening
the definition of ‘employer’ for the purpose of determining whether subcontracted
work is covered under the nation’s labor relations statute, and similar cases con-
cerning companies such as Federal Express and Uber are being considered in fed-
eral and state-level courts. Scholars are also increasingly documenting enforcement
theories built on leveraging fissured, supply chain relationships among firms, often
referred to as strategic enforcement (Weil, 2008; Wright and Brown, 2013).
Government contracting rules. One area of considerable discussion is whether the fed-
eral government can or should use its power as a purchaser of goods and services as
a means of enforcing and improving employment standards. The model for doing
so comes from the US experience in enforcing and promoting the 1964 Civil Rights
Act, which prohibits discrimination in employment on the basis of race and sex,
among other protected groups. A subsequent Executive Order required govern-
ment contractors to demonstrate steps they take to achieve affirmative actions.
Later research demonstrated the efficacy of these requirements in promoting
non-discrimination and equal opportunities (Leonard, 1990). The question under
debate in government and academic circles is whether this model could be applied
to promote diffusion of high-productivity high-wage practices among government
contractors. This remains to be seen. President Obama signed an executive order,
effective in 2016, that requires contracting firms to disclose their records of com-
pliance and violation of labor and employment law. Some suggest expanding this
order by inserting high-productivity high-wage criteria in the specifications used to
select competing bidders for government contracts – a strategy that may substitute
for the role of pattern bargaining discussed earlier.
Next generation unions and sources of power. One of the biggest open questions facing
both the US and to some extent other countries is what will fill the void left by
union decline. While reproducing unions and collective bargaining in the mirror
image of their past is neither likely nor viable, alternative means are needed to
reinstate voice and bargaining at work. Indeed, unions are pursuing new strategies
to this end, such as non-traditional organizing of freelancers and supporting
434 Journal of Industrial Relations 58(3)
Alternative wage-setting criteria and norms. As noted earlier, the tandem movement of
productivity and real wages and compensation in the pre-1980s era was driven by,
among other factors, union agreements that aligned productivity gains and cost of
living clauses into collective bargaining contracts. New approaches to wage setting
at the level of the enterprise will be needed to ensure that those who work together
to generate productivity and profits have a fair chance of sharing in the gains
produced. Profit sharing, productivity gains sharing, and broad-based employee
stock ownership plans (Blasi et al., 2014) are alternative ways of embedding this
principle in the wage-setting processes within specific enterprises.
New federal rules will soon require publication of salary ratios between CEOs
and average workers in corporate reports. Whether this effort to increase trans-
parency will be powerful enough to change corporate practices remains to be seen.
Corporate boards may need stronger pressures to change the ways CEOs are paid
(such as changes in marginal income tax rates; Piketty, 2014), given the embedded
roles that compensation consultants play in spreading CEO compensation patterns
across firms and industries.
Labor policy. While each of the options reviewed can contribute to stimulating
wage growth and reducing inequality, sustained progress will require a funda-
mental change in national labor and employment policy. There are a number of
dimensions to such change: updating minimum wage laws and clarifying the
definition of the employer in fissured work settings, as described earlier, are
two glaringly necessary changes. Expansion of safety net programs – such as
the Earned Income Tax Credit, the Affordable Care Act, and paid family and
medical leave – can provide low-income workers better access to employment
opportunities while promoting overall economic growth (Lower-Basch, 2014).
Additionally, updating current laws that govern collective bargaining is yet
Kochan and Riordan 435
another step towards fundamental change, particularly since current law cannot
provide union representation coverage to all workers who want it (Ferguson,
2008). It remains to be seen whether changing labor relations policy is possible,
given that, both historically and recently, it has been the most difficult aspect of
US employment policy to change (Kochan, 2016).
Conclusion
The widespread recognition and growing public debates over income inequality are
producing a growing body of research on the causes of wage stagnation and
options for addressing it within private and public realms. Until recently, most
of the academic debate has focused on the relative importance of technology and
globalization as underlying causal forces, and on education – and to a lesser extent,
trade policies – as remedies. More recently, however, attention has turned to insti-
tutional factors including minimum wages, unions and their bargaining power, and
employment policies and their enforcement. We extend this literature here to focus
on some of the key changes in employment relationships and organizational prac-
tices that affect wages and related employment conditions at the enterprise level.
It is clear that these causal forces are closely interrelated and that no single
change in policy or organizational practice will suffice to reverse long-term
trends in wages. Investments in education are a necessary but far from sufficient
component of a broader strategy. So too are more direct efforts to build next
generation manufacturing industries in ways that support and sustain high-wage
jobs. Equally important, however, are actions aimed at bringing up the floor of the
wage structure through raises in minimum wages and better enforcement of
employment standards, modernization of labor policies that allow workers to
build new sources of bargaining power consistent with the modern economy,
and organizational changes that challenge the financialization of corporations
and encourage broader diffusion of firms that embrace high-road business strate-
gies and workplace practices.
The historical trends in inequality, and particularly in productivity-wage
growth patterns, suggest two final points. The current situation is the product
of trends of over 30 years’ duration and therefore it will take a sustained period
of wage growth to make up for lost ground. But the fact that turning points as
clear as the ones that reversed the high level of inequality in the US observed just
prior to the passage of the New Deal labor legislation in the 1930s and the
beginning of the productivity-wage gap around 1980 suggest that a broad-
based, systematic strategy that is well informed by research can change these
long-run trends and put the economy on a different path. Doing so again is
the defining challenge facing our field today.
Funding
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication
of this article.
References
Acemoglu D and Autor D (2011) Skills, tasks, and technologies: Implications for employ-
ment and earnings. In: Ashenfelter O and Card DE (eds) Handbook of Labor Economics,
vol. 4b. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Alvaredo F, Atkinson AB, Piketty T, et al. (2013) The top 1 percent in international and
historical perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(3): 3–20.
Appelbaum E (2012) Reducing inequality and insecurity: Rethinking labor and employment
policy for the 21st century. Work and Occupations 39(4): 311–320.
Appelbaum E and Batt R (2014) Private Equity at Work: When Wall Street Manages Main
Street. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Appelbaum E, Bailey T, Kalleberg A, et al. (2000) Manufacturing Advantage: Why High
Performance Work Systems Pay Off. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Appelbaum E, Hoffer Gittell J and Leana C (2011) High performance work practices and
economic recovery. Report, Employment Policy Research Network. Available at: http://
www.employmentpolicy.org/page-1797725#sthash.yEFch5zl.dpbs (accessed 18 February
2016).
Autor D (2010) The future of American jobs: The polarization of job opportunities in the
U.S. labor market. Report, Center for American Progress. Available at: https://www.am
ericanprogress.org/issues/labor/report/2010/04/30/7687/the-future-of-american-jobs/
(accessed 18 February 2016).
Autor D, Dorn P and Hanson GH (2013) The China syndrome: Local labor market effects
of import competition in the United States. American Economic Review 1036: 2121–2168.
Autor D, Katz L and Kearney MS (2008) Trends in U.S. wage inequality: Revising the
revisionists. The Review of Economics and Statistics 90(2): 300–323.
Bailey T, Berg P and Sandy C (2001) The effect of high-performance work practices on
employee earnings in the steel, apparel, and medical electronics and imaging industries.
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 54(2A): 525–544.
Barth E, Bryson A, Davis JC, et al. (2014) It’s where you work: Increases in earnings
dispersion across establishments and individuals in the U.S. IZA Discussion Paper
No.8437.
Batt R, Doellgast V and Kwon H (2004) The US call center industry 2004: National bench-
marking report. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University.
Bernhardt A and Osterman P (2016) Organizing for good jobs: Recent developments and
new challenges. Work and Occupations. Epub ahead of print 26 Jan 2016. DOI:10.1177/
0730888415625096.
Bernhardt A, Spiller MW and Polson D (2013) All work and no pay: Violations of employ-
ment and labor laws in Chicago, Los Angeles, and New York City. Social Forces 91(3):
725–746.
Bivens J and Mishel L (2015) Understanding and explaining the historic divergence between
productivity and a typical worker’s pay: Why it matters and why it’s real. Report,
Economic Policy Institute. Available at: http://www.epi.org/publication/understanding-
the-historic-divergence-between-productivity-and-a-typical-workers-pay-why-it-matters-
and-why-its-real/ (accessed 18 February 2016).
Kochan and Riordan 437
Black F and Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. The Journal of
Political Economy 81(3): 637–654.
Blasi JR, Freeman RB and Kruse D (2014) The Citizen’s Share: Reducing Inequality in the
21st Century. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Bluestone B and Kochan TA (2011) Toward a grand new bargain: Collective bargaining
approaches to labor-management reform in Massachusetts. Report. Boston, MA: The
Boston Foundation.
Bobo K (2009) Wage Theft in America. New York: The Free Press.
Card D and DiNardo JE (2002) Skill-biased technological change and rising wage inequal-
ity: Some problems and puzzles. Journal of Labor Economics 20(4): 733–783.
Cascio W (2006) Decency means more than ‘Always low prices’: A comparison of Costco to
Wal-Mart’s Sam’s Club. Academy of Management Perspectives 20: 25–28.
Davis SJ and Haltiwanger J (1991) Wage dispersion between and within U.S. manufacturing
plants, 1963–1986. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1991: 115–200.
DeNavas-Walt C and Proctor BD (2014) Income and poverty in the United States: 2013.
Current Population Reports. U.S. Bureau of the Census. Available at: https://www.cen
sus.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2014/demo/p60-249.pdf (accessed 18
February 2016).
Dietz M, Levitt D and Love E (2014) Enforcement of labor standards. In: Reich M, Jacobs
K and Dietz M (eds) When Mandates Work: Raising Labor Standards at the Local Level.
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, pp. 229–255.
DiNardo J, Fortin NM and Lemieux T (1996) Labor market institutions and the distribu-
tion of wages, 1973–1992: A semiparametric approach. Econometrica 64(5): 1001–1046.
Dube A and Kaplan E (2010) Does outsourcing reduce wages in the low-wage service
occupations? Evidence from janitors and guards. Industrial and Labor Relations Review
63(2): 287–306.
Erickson CL (1992) Wage rule formation in the aerospace industry. Industrial and Labor
Relations Review 45(3): 507–522.
Erickson CL (1996) A reinterpretation of pattern bargaining. Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 49(4): 615–634.
Ferguson JP (2008) The eyes of the needles: A sequential model of union organizing drives,
1999–2004. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 62(1): 3–21.
Fernandez-Macias E (2012) Job polarization in Europe? Changes in the employment struc-
ture and job quality, 1995–2007. Work and Occupations 39(2): 157–182.
Fine JR (2011) New forms to settle old scores: Updating the worker centre story in the
United States. Relations Industrielles/Industrial Relations 66(4): 604–630.
Fine JR and Gordon J (2010) Strengthening labor standards enforcement through partner-
ships with workers’ organizations. Politics and Society 38(4): 552–585.
Fortin NM and Lemieux T (1997) Institutional change and rising wage inequality: Is there a
linkage? The Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(2): 75–96.
Freeman R (1980) Unionism and the dispersion of wages. Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 34(1): 3–23.
Freeman R (1982) Union wage practices and wage dispersion within establishments.
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 36: 3–21.
Freeman R (1993) How much has de-unionization contributed to the rise in male earnings
inequality? In: Danziger S and Gottschalk P (eds) Uneven Tides: Rising Inequality in
America. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 133–164.
438 Journal of Industrial Relations 58(3)
Goldin C and Katz L (2008) The Race Between Education and Technology. Cambridge, UK:
Harvard University Press.
Gosling A and Lemieux T (2004) Labor market reforms and changes in wage inequality in the
United Kingdom and the United States. In: Card D, Blundell R and Freeman RB (eds)
Seeking a Premier Economy: The Economic Effects of British Economic Reforms, 1980–2000.
National Bureau of Economic Research. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press,
pp. 275–312.
Groshen EL (1991) Sources of intra-industry wage dispersion: How much do employers
matter? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(3): 869–884.
Hertz R (2010) Economic crisis and new social realities: Bait and switch and the American
Dream – Presidential Address 2010. Sociological Forum 25(4): 643–654.
Hoffer Gittell J (2003) The Southwest Airlines Way. New York: McGraw Hill.
Holzer HJ (2010) Is the middle of the U.S. job market really disappearing? A comment on
the ‘‘polarization’’ hypothesis. Report, Center for American Progress, Washington, DC.
Available at: https://cdn.americanprogress.org/wp-content/uploads/issues/2010/05/pdf/
Holzer_memo.pdf (accessed 18 February 2016).
Holzer HJ, Lane JI, Rosenblum DB, et al. (2011) Where Are All the Good Jobs Going? What
National and Local Job Quality and Dynamics Mean for U.S. Workers. New York: Russell
Sage Foundation.
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2006) Strategies and Practice for Labour
Inspection. International Labour Office Governing Body, Committee on Employment
and Social Policy. Geneva, Switzerland: ILO.
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2015) Global Wage Report 2014/15: Wages and
Income Inequality. International Labour Office. Geneva, Switzerland: ILO.
Jacoby SM (2004) Employing Bureaucracy: Managers, Unions, and the Transformation of
Work in the 20th Century. New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc.
James J (2012) The college wage premium. Economic Commentary, vol 10. Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.
Kalleberg AL, Reskin B and Hudson K (2000) Bad jobs in America: Standard and non-
standard employment relations and job quality in the United States. American
Sociological Review 65: 256–278.
Kochan TA (2016) Shaping the Future of Work. New York: Business Experts Press.
Kochan TA, Eaton A, McKersie RB, et al. (2009) Healing Together: The Kaiser Permanente
Labor Management Partnership. Ithaca, NY: Cornell/ILR Press.
Kochan TA, Katz HC and McKersie RB (1986) The Transformation of American Industrial
Relations, 2nd edn. (1994). Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.
Kochan TA, Smith M, Wells J, et al. (1994) Human resource strategies and contingent
workers: The case of safety and health in the petrochemical industry. Human Resource
Management 33: 55–78.
Lazonick W (2009) Sustainable Prosperity in the New Economy: Business Organization and
High-Tech Employment in the United States. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research.
Lee D (1999) Wage inequality in the United States during the 1980s: Rising dispersion or
falling minimum wage? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(3): 977–1023.
Lemieux T (1993) Unions and wage inequality in Canada and the United States. In: Card D
and Freeman RB (eds) Small Differences that Matter: Labor Markets and Income
Kochan and Riordan 439
Maintenance in Canada and the United States. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press,
pp. 69–107.
Lemieux T (2008) The changing nature of wage inequality. Journal of Population Economics
21: 21–48.
Leonard JS (1990) The impact of affirmative action regulation and equal employment law
on black employment. Journal of Economic Perspectives 44(4): 47–63.
Locke RM (2013) The Promise and Limits of Private Power: Promoting Labor Standards in a
Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lower-Basch E (2014) How today’s safety net promotes work – And how to do more.
Report, Center for Law and Social Policy. Available at: http://www.clasp.org/
resources-and-publications/publication-1/How-Todays-Safety-Net-Promotes-Work-
And-How-To-Do-More-1.pdf (accessed 18 February 2016).
McCain M (2009) Serving students: A survey of contracted food service work in New
Jersey’s K-12 public schools. Report, Rutgers Center for Women and Work, New
Brunswick, NJ.
Marchington M, Rubery J and Grimshaw J (2011) Alignment integration and consistency
in HRM across multiple-employer networks. Human Resource Management 50(3):
313–339.
Merton RC (1971) Theory of rational option pricing. The Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science 4(1): 141–183.
Mishel L and Davis A (2015) Top CEOs make 300 times more than typical workers. Report.
Economic Policy Institute Issue Brief #399. Available at: http://www.epi.org/publication/
top-ceos-make-300-times-more-than-workers-pay-growth-surpasses-market-gains-and-
the-rest-of-the-0-1-percent/ (accessed 18 February 2016).
Oldenski L (2014) Offshoring and the polarization of the U.S. labor market. ILR Review
67(Supp.): 734–761.
Osterman P (1994) How common is workplace transformation and who adopts it? ILR
Review 47(2): 173–188.
Piketty T (2014) Capital in the Twenty-first Century. Cambridge, MA: President and Fellows
of Harvard College, Harvard University Press.
Piketty T and Saez E (2007 (2015)) Income and wage inequality in the United States 1913–2002.
In: Atkinson AB and Piketty T (eds) Top Incomes over the Twentieth Century. A Contrast
Between Continental European and English-Speaking Countries. Oxford: Oxford University
press. Accessed at: http://topincomes.g-mond.parisschoolofeconomics.eu/ (accessed 18
February 2016, Data series updated by the same authors).
Piketty T and Saez E (2013) Top incomes and the Great Recession: Recent evolutions and
policy implications. International Monetary Fund Economic Review 61(3): 456–478.
Ray R, Gornick JC and Schmitt J (2009) Parental leave policies in 21 countries: Assessing
generosity and gender equality. Report, Center for Economic and Policy Research.
Available at: http://www.cepr.net/documents/publications/parental_2008_09.pdf
(accessed 18 February 2016).
Rosnick D (2015) Are 40 Cents a Day Big Gains? Washington, DC: Center for Economic
Policy Research, Available at: https://cepr.net/documents/TTIP-brief-08-2015.pdf
(accessed 18 February 2016).
Rubinstein SA and McCarthy JE (2014) Teachers Unions and Management Partnerships:
How working together improves student achievement. Report, Center for American
440 Journal of Industrial Relations 58(3)
Biographical notes
Thomas A Kochan is the George Maverick Bunker Professor of Work and
Employment Research, and the Co-Director of the MIT Sloan Institute for
Work and Employment Research at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Sloan School of Management.