Slides Macro Week 11
Slides Macro Week 11
World Economy
Based on CORE’s The Economy: Unit 18 and Unit 1.8
Overview
Part 1
Exchange rates and Balance of Payments
From Begg et al Ch 24 and 25
Part 2
What is Globalisation?
Specialisation and gains from trade
Winners and losers from trade specialisation
(From Core Unit 18 and Unit 1.8)
Part 3
Globalisation and anti-globalisation
Trade and Growth
Conclusions
(From Core Unit 18)
Exchange Rates
§ But the global convergence of wages has been much less than the
convergence of goods and asset prices
§ By buying at a low price in export markets and selling at a higher price in import
markets, traders can make a profit as long as the price gap is higher than the total
cost of trade
§ The practice of buying a good at a low price in one market (or country) to
sell it at a higher price in another.
§ Through the process of buying cheap and selling dear – the price rises in the low
price market and falls in the high price market leading one price in both markets
§ Arbitrage explains why the price gap equals trade costs: Arbitrage continues until
the price gap has been driven down to the trade cost, and further arbitrage is
unprofitable
Price gap
§ Even so, for most goods and factors there will be some gap
§ A low price gap reflects a much more globalised world in which trade is
cheap
PRICE
price in Japan
price in the US
QUANTITY
Trade costs have declined over time
§ As trade costs fall (and the price gap falls) – the volume of trade rises
§ The wheat price gap between the UK and the US started to decline at about the same time
that shipping costs started to fall (due to the introduction of steamships on long-distance
routes). The volume of wheat shipped across the Atlantic rose dramatically
§ The transatlantic trade in wheat is not an isolated example. International price gaps fell
sharply on many routes and for many commodities between 1815 and 1914
History of trade in mechandise
Protectionist policies and deglobalisation
§ Transatlantic shipments of wheat fell after 1914, and price gaps rose, suggesting a
rise in trade costs and therefore deglobalisation
§ This is often done to protect domestic industries and jobs against foreign
competition
§ This requires trade you must engage in trade to acquire the goods you do not
produce
§ Nations specialise in the production of the goods and services in which they are
relatively low-cost producers
§ Specialisation and trade allows for mutual gains for the people of trading
countries
§ Specialisation and trade may benefit some groups within a country while harming
others for example, those producing goods that compete with imports
Reasons for specialization
– The production of aircraft is subject to economies of scale. The Boeing Plant in Everett,
Washington is the largest building in the world.
– Writing computer code is not subject to economies of scale, but good software is produced in
areas in which a very large number of people are working on similar tasks, sharing information
and innovating.
– The production of clothing requires a lot of labour but not an extensive amount of capital
goods, this suits Mauritius.
– Parts of Canada’s climate and land suites the production and export of wheat.
§ Economies of scale: doubling all the inputs to a production process more than
doubles the output.
§ Bigger volumes of output can be produced at lower cost per unit
§ For instance: doubling the amount of land and time used for production would
more than double output
§ Greta is lucky: Wheat Island has better soil (for both crops)
– Greta has an absolute advantage in both crops
– Although Carlos’ land is worse overall for producing both crops, his disadvantage
is less (relative to Greta) in apples than in wheat.
– To see this note that for apples 1250/1000 = 1.25; for wheat 100/40 =2.5
Carlos’ feasible production
Feasible production frontier: The Carlos’ feasible set: He can produce anywhere between the
red line that joins points A and B is origin and the feasible production frontier.
the feasible production frontier for
Carlos. It shows all the combinations
of wheat and apples that can be
produced by Carlos in a year Carlos’s choice: He can choose to produce any
combination on (or inside) the frontier. For
example, he could produce 2,000 tonnes of
wheat and 5,000 apples, as shown by point C.
Carlos
Without trade PRODUCTION = CONSUMPTION
§ In the absence of trade, the feasible production frontier is also the feasible consumption
frontier. This is because each person spends time producing only wheat and apples, and can
consume only the amount they produce
§ The shape of the indifference curves represents Carlos’ preferences over wheat and apples.
§ In the absence of trade, Carlos and Greta do best by selecting a point on the highest indifference
curve possible, given the constraint of their feasible production frontier
Greta can consume more of both goods than Carlos because of her superior productivity. We assume her
preferences are the same as Carlos’ (the indifference curves are the same shape). She consumes 6,000 tonnes
of wheat a year and 5,000 apples, as shown by point E.
Relative prices and comparative advantage (without trade)
§ An island has a comparative advantage in producing a good when it is relatively cheaper in their
economy (in the absence of trade).
§ While Greta has an absolute advantage in producing both products, Carlos has a comparative
advantage in producing Apples
§ For Carlos, the marginal rate of transformation between wheat and apples is 2.5: it takes the same
amount of land and labour to produce one tonne of wheat as it does to produce 2.5 apples.
§ For Greta the relative price of wheat to apples on Wheat Island is 1.25. Greta has a comparative
advantage in producing wheat. Her relative price of wheat is lower than on Apple island. If you
were to vising Greta, you would notice that her wheat is cheaper.
§ The relative price of apples is the reciprocal or inverse of the relative price of wheat, so if Wheat
Island has a comparative advantage in producing wheat, then Apple Island must have a
comparative advantage in producing apples.
§ Specialisation has enlarged the feasible consumption set for both Carlos and
Greta
§ Because both countries are now specializing in the good in which they have a
comparative advantage, the new consumption frontiers are above their
production frontiers
§ For each country, the two frontiers meet at the point at which they do not
trade (at the axis)
§ We can see that specialisation and international trade have led to an increase
in the size of the feasible consumption set for both countries.
§ Note, Greta cannot consume more than the maximum amount of apples Carlos
can produce (10,000), which is why her feasible consumption frontier does not
extend beyond 10,000 apples.
§ The expansion of their feasible consumption sets makes it possible for both
Carlos and Greta to reach a higher level of utility (a higher indifference curve)
§ Trade has been mutually beneficial: the welfare of both has improved
Consumption after specialization and trade
…. in exchange
for imports
2000 tons of
wheat
§ Suppose that Greta can determine the price of wheat because has more bargaining power
§ Since she is specializing in wheat (her comparative advantage) this means keeping apples cheap: she will
choose a price that increases the amount of apples she receives for each tonne of wheat she sells to
Carlos.
§ Here, we assume Greta has chosen a price of 2.25 apples for a tonne of wheat
§ This means trade and specialisation will increase the utility of both Carlos and Greta, but will increase
Greta’s utility by more
§ Typically, when countries trade, there are winners and losers within each
country
§ For example when South Africa imports cheap clothes from Bangladesh:
§ To think about winners and losers from trade we begin with a model of two stylized
countries USA and China, where specialisation is based on factor endowments
§ Only two goods are produced (under constant returns to scale):
– Aircraft (relatively capital intensive)
– Consumer electronics (relatively labour intensive)
§ USA
– An advanced economy with a long tradition of manufacturing
– Capital is relatively abundant
– Has absolute advantage in producing both goods
– Has comparative advantage in producing aircraft
§ China
– Less developed, but has become the world’s second-largest economy by exporting
manufactured goods
– Has an abundance of labour relative to capital
– Has a comparative advantage in consumer electronics production
Conflicts of interest
§ The relative price of the two goods affects how the gains from trade are
divided between the countries
§ The usual forces of demand and supply affect the relative price
§ The balance of bargaining power between the two affects the price too
§ Between countries:
§ Within a country, the beneficiaries of a rise in relative price are those that specialises in producing that
product
§ Trade and specialisation mean that resources shift from one industry to another.
§ In the US
– the increase in production of aircraft means that the US increases the demand for capital, the factor of
production used intensively in that industry
– The owners of capital benefit more from trade than workers, because capital becomes relatively scarce
as production of aircraft rises
– Workers previously employed in electronics in the US must try to find work in the expanding aircraft
manufacturing businesses
– Since the wealthy tend to hold proportionally more of their wealth in capital than the poor, we would
predict a rise in inequality
§ In China
– The demand for labour (used intensively in producing consumer electronics) will rise
– employment will expand in consumer electronics production
– Workers are in higher demand as consumer electronics production expands
– Wages rise as firms compete for workers. Lower unemployment lowers the cost of job loss, and firms
raise wages
– Workers benefit more from trade than the owners of capital, hence we would expect inequality to fall
Impact on employment
US and Chinese
economies with limited With greater
specialisation and specialisation and trade,
trade. the total size of each
To make comparison economy is larger: The
easy, the economies are size of the US economy
normalized to a size of has increased by 30% and
one the size of the Chinese
economy has increased
the numbers in the pies
by 40%.
show both the
proportion and size (in The prices at which they
brackets) of the slice of have traded (as
the economic pie that determined by
accrue to workers (red) bargaining) have resulted,
and the owners of in this case, in China
capital (blue) securing more of the
gains from trade.
The pie grows and shares of the pie change
§ Typically SA has:
– A deficit on its current account (the value of imports > the value of exports)
– A surplus on its financial account (the value of financial inflows > the value of financial
outflows)
§ In addition to trade finance, savings flow in order to purchase assets – this take the form of
portfolio investment and foreign direct investment.
South Africa’s Balance of Payments (1985-2018)
50
Net direct investment Net portfolio investment Net other investment
Balance on the financial account Balance on the current account
10%
8%
6%
4%
Percent of GDP
2%
0%
-2%
-4%
-6%
-8%
-10%
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
Trends in international asset holdings
51
§ For the rich countries that dominated international lending, the share of foreign assets divided by
GDP was high in the early part of the century, but declined after the great depression and in the
inter-war period
§ After 1945, New York took over from London as the global financial centre and the US eclipsed
Britain as the dominant international asset holder
Migration of people
Migration to the “new world”
53
§ When Europe was experiencing its population boom, as death rates fell sharply and birth rates fell
only with a lag, it was able to ship its surplus population to America and other parts of the world
(e.g. South Africa, Australia)
§ In the late nineteenth century, declining transport costs and rising wages made passage to America
and other parts of the world affordable for millions: immigrants accounted for more than half of
the increase in the US population
Migration has been heavily restricted
54
§ Immigration barriers became much stricter during and after the First
World War, and rich countries retain strict immigration barriers
Norway
Sweden
Germany France
USA
UK
Italy
Japan South
Korea
Portugal
Taiwan
Mexico
Sri Lanka
Immigration and workers
56
§ Firms are now getting work at lower wages, and so are more profitable. As a
result they will seek to expand production. To do this, they will invest in new
machinery. This will increase labour demand in the rest of the economy, and when
the new capacity is ready, firms will hire more workers.
§ In the short-run impact of immigration could be bad for existing workers in that
country: wages fall and the expected duration of unemployment increases. The
short run may last for years or even decades.
§ In the longer run, the increased profitability of firms leads to expanded
employment that eventually will restore the real wage and return the economy to
its initial rate of unemployment (if no further changes in the situation take place,
like another wave of immigration).
§ As a result, incumbent workers are no worse off. Immigrants are likely to be
economically better off too—especially if they left their home country because it
was difficult to make a living.
The politics of globalisation
Political backlash against globalisation
59
§ There is survey evidence that unskilled workers in rich countries are more
protectionist than skilled workers, but unskilled workers in poor countries
are more in favour of trade than skilled workers.
Glabalisation and anti-globalisation
60
§ If the losers, whether from the mobility of goods, investment or people, are
ignored, globalisation may turn out to be politically unsustainable in a democracy
Rodrick’s trilemma
three things
all of which are
valued but which
cannot all occur at
the same time
§ hyperglobalisation means that countries have to compete with each other for
investment, with the result that wealth owners will seek locations for their
investments in which labour has fewer rights and the environment is less
protected.
§ the political integration of Europe over the last few decades happened, in
part, so that governments could obtain the benefits of free trade, plus
the free movement of capital and labour,
§ while retaining some ability at the supranational EU-wide level to
regulate profit-making in the interests of fairness and economic stability.
§ The obvious problem is how to make sure that this EU-wide or global
governance is democratic as well as technocratic, and to allow voters to
change the system if they don’t like it
Example of Rodrick’s trilemma in South Africa
65
§ What are the best policies for governments to adopt if they seek to promote
long-run growth in living standards?
§ Some argue that it is a choice between two policy extremes:
– Seal the national borders and withdraw from the world economy!
– Let trade, immigration, and investment across national boundaries take place in
the absence of government regulation of any kind!
§ The reality is likely to be more complex
§ The question is how to exploit the contributions of the global economy to a
nation’s wellbeing, while minimizing the ways in which integration into the global
economy may retard it.
Growth-enhancing aspects of greater global economic integration
68
§ Competition:
– Limiting the impediments to trade in goods and services among nations increases the
degree of competition faced by firms in the local economy.
– This means that firms that fail to adopt new technologies and other cost-cutting methods
are more likely to fail and to be replaced by more dynamic firms.
– A firm that can export to the world market has the opportunity (if it can meet the
competition) of selling far more than it could were it restricted to the domestic market.
– This allows lower-cost production, which benefits home-economy buyers, employees, and
owners of these successful firms, as well as external buyers.
Government and integration
69
§ Ways that greater integration into the global economy might require greater government intervention
– In addition to economies of scale, another factor contributing to cost reductions is termed learning
by doing.
– Even if the firm never achieves large-scale production, costs of production typically fall over time.
– Tariffs protecting infant industries can give firms the time and possibly the scale of operation
necessary to become competitive.
§ Disadvantageous specialisation
– For reasons of history, some countries may specialise in sectors where there is a lot of potential for
innovation, whereas others specialise in sectors with little such potential.
– Many Latin American countries, for example, slowed growth by specializing in low-innovation sectors
such as natural resource extraction.
– Developing new specialisations may require direct government intervention, including infant
industry protection.
§ Redistribution
– Where global integration creates winners and losers, government is need to redistribution incomes
and balance this process
– Displaced workers need retraining for new employment opportunities created by globalisation
Different routes to development
70
§ There has not been a unique route to economic success during the past 150 years.
– These countries developed modern manufacturing sectors behind high tariff barriers that
sheltered them from British competition.
– In the late nineteenth century, the correlation between tariffs and economic growth across
relatively rich countries was positive.
– During the interwar period, tariffs were also positively correlated with growth.
– These countries have been very open to trade for more than 100 years and have prospered.
– Many East Asian governments have promoted trade while influencing its pattern by favouring
certain industries, or even certain firms, and by directing firms to compete in export markets
whilst providing some protection from import competition.
– On the one hand, countries in East Asia that encouraged their firms to compete in international
markets grew faster than Latin American countries that were more closed to international trade.
– On the other hand, after those Latin American countries reduced their tariffs in the early 1990s,
their subsequent economic growth rates were lower than during the more closed period 1945
to 1980.
Conclusion
72
§ If there is a lesson, it is that success does not depend on whether a country is more or less
integrated into the world economic system
§ Success depends on how well economic integration is managed by policies that promote
growth
– Economics can help to design and evaluate policies that secure the greatest possible
mutual gains among the world’s people participating in this new dynamic and
cosmopolitan economy.
– Economics can also identify groups whose livelihoods are under threat from the
globalisation process and propose policies to ensure that the gains made possible from
worldwide investment and exchange are fairly shared.