RAND_RR513-1
RAND_RR513-1
EDUCATION AND THE ARTS helps improve policy and decisionmaking through
ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT research and analysis.
HEALTH AND HEALTH CARE
This electronic document was made available from
INFRASTRUCTURE AND www.rand.org as a public service of the RAND
TRANSPORTATION
Corporation.
INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS
PUBLIC SAFETY
C O R P O R AT I O N
N AT I ONAL SECUR I T Y R ESE AR C H DIV IS IO N
Countering Others’
Insurgencies
Understanding U.S. Small-Footprint
Interventions in Local Context
ISBN: 978-0-8330-8404-0
R® is a registered trademark
Cover image: Pakistani soldiers place barbwire to secure a street during a curfew
in Rawalpindi on Nov. 17, 2013 (Reuters/Faisal Mahmood).
This document and trademark(s) contained herein are protected by law. This
representation of RAND intellectual property is provided for noncommercial use only.
Unauthorized posting of RAND documents to a non-RAND website is prohibited.
RAND documents are protected under copyright law. Permission is given to duplicate
this document for personal use only, as long as it is unaltered and complete. Permission
is required from RAND to reproduce, or reuse in another form, any of our research
documents for commercial use. For information on reprint and linking permissions,
please see the RAND permissions page (www.rand.org/pubs/permissions.html).
RAND OFFICES
SANTA MONICA, CA • WASHINGTON, DC
PITTSBURGH, PA • NEW ORLEANS, LA • JACKSON, MS • BOSTON, MA
DOHA, QA • CAMBRIDGE, UK • BRUSSELS, BE
www.rand.org
Preface
This report documents the results of a project that assessed the reasons
why counterinsurgents in the developing world so often adopt counter-
insurgency strategies and practices at odds with U.S. preferences and
how the United States can influence its potential partners’ choices in
these conflicts.
The report is written for a general audience, although it is likely
to be of particular interest to those in the foreign policy and defense
communities, both civilian and military, concerned with counterinsur-
gency and security-sector assistance.
This research was sponsored by the Smith Richardson Foundation
and conducted within the International Security and Defense Policy
Center of the RAND National Security Research Division (NSRD).
NSRD conducts research and analysis on defense and national secu-
rity topics for the U.S. and allied defense, foreign policy, homeland
security, and intelligence communities and foundations and other non-
governmental organizations that support defense and national security
analysis.
For more information on the International Security and Defense
Policy Center, see http://www.rand.org/nsrd/ndri/centers/isdp.html or
contact the director (contact information is provided on the web page).
iii
Contents
Preface. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii
Figures. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix
Tables. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi
Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiii
Acknowledgments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xxi
Abbreviations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xxiii
CHAPTER ONE
Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
CHAPTER TWO
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Current American Counterinsurgency Thought. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Varieties of Counterinsurgency.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Bounded Accommodation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Discriminate Violence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Provision of Public Goods. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
A Typology of Counterinsurgency Models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Determinants of Counterinsurgency Strategy and Practice.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Political Inclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
State Capacity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
Military Superiority. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
Measures and Predictions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
v
vi Countering Others’ Insurgencies
CHAPTER THREE
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
Accommodation of the Reconcilable Opposition. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34
Political Inclusivity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
State Capacity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Military Sufficiency.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
Discriminate Use of Violence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
Political Inclusivity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
State Capacity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
Military Sufficiency.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
Integrating Quantitative Findings on Counterinsurgent Strategies.. . . . . . . . . 52
Conflict Termination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
Discriminate Use of Violence.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
Using Quantitative and Qualitative Analysis to Reinforce One
Another. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
CHAPTER FOUR
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
Background. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
Overview of the Counterinsurgency and Counterterrorism
Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
Insurgent and Terrorist Organizations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
Government Forces and Strategies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
The Role of the United States .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
Analysis of Philippine Counterinsurgency. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
Political Inclusion, Accommodation, and Restraint. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
Military Superiority. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
State Capacity and Counterinsurgency. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Analysis of U.S. Assistance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102
Capacity-Building and Enhanced Civilian Oversight.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
The U.S. Role: Limitations and Risks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
Contents vii
CHAPTER FIVE
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Introduction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Background. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
Context.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
Conflict Narrative. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
Analysis of Pakistan’s Counterinsurgency.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Political Inclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
State Capacity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
Military Superiority. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
Analysis of U.S. Assistance.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
Effects of U.S. Military Assistance.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159
Effects of U.S. Civil Assistance.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
U.S. Efforts to Influence Pakistan and Their Consequences. . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
Conclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170
CHAPTER SIX
Managing Troubled Partnerships. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Approaches to Managing Troubled Partnerships.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
Selectivity and Avoiding “Bad” Counterinsurgents.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176
Conditionality and Making Partners into “Good”
Counterinsurgents. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 177
Policy Prescriptions for Managing Troubled Partnerships. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185
General Principles.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 186
Bounded Accommodation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188
Regulated Violence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190
APPENDIX
Coding Notes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
Bibliography. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 201
Figures
ix
x Countering Others’ Insurgencies
xi
Summary
With the United States exhausted by more than a decade of war and
facing severe fiscal limitations, decisionmakers are striving to place
American defense policy on a more sustainable footing. Central to
this effort is a commitment to work through partner nations wherever
possible, providing support to countries with which the United States
shares interests or values while also ensuring that the primary responsi-
bility for these nations’ security remains their own. Thus the document
that currently guides U.S. defense policy states:
1 U.S. Department of Defense, Sustaining U.S. Global Leadership: Priorities for 21st Century
Defense, Washington, D.C.: Department of Defense, January 2012, p. 3.
xiii
xiv Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Research Findings
The answers to these questions provided in this report are derived from
a mixed-method research design incorporating both quantitative and
qualitative analysis. Simple statistical analyses are applied to a dataset
of counterinsurgencies that have terminated since the end of the Cold
Summary xv
War (72 in all) to understand the manner in which they were fought
and how they terminated. This broad overview frames more in-depth
analyses of two important recent cases of U.S. partnerships, the Philip-
pines and Pakistan, drawing on secondary literature, a wide variety of
quantitative data sources, and interviews conducted with several dozen
government officials, military officers, and civil society actors in the
Philippines, Pakistan, and the United States.
The report finds that the counterinsurgency strategies and prac-
tices adopted by regimes fighting rebellions are strongly shaped by the
characteristics of these regimes—in particular, the degree to which
they are politically inclusive and the extent of state capacity they pos-
sess. “Success stories” like the Philippines and Colombia have occurred
in countries characterized by relatively inclusive politics and reason-
able levels of state capacity. The governments of such countries typi-
cally adopt strategies that approximate the Western model of counter-
insurgency, often (misleadingly) referred to as the “hearts-and-minds”
approach. Unfortunately, only approximately one insurgency in eight
occurs in such best-case countries. The majority of rebellions take place
in worst-case conditions—that is, in countries that lack both inclusive
politics and state capacity. Regimes in this latter category are prone to
relying on blunt applications of military force to contain or suppress
rebellion.
The quantitative analysis conducted in this study paints a stark
picture of the different trajectories that conflicts follow in these best-
case and worst-case environments. As shown in Figure S.1, only 13
percent of civil wars in the best-case environments fail to reach an out-
come that the government finds acceptable (that is, either outright mil-
itary victory or a negotiated settlement acceptable to both sides); the
failure rate is nearly five times as high (60 percent) in the worst-case
environments. Non-inclusive regimes are much more likely to suffer
outright defeat than are more-inclusive ones. Weak regimes are much
more likely to experience indeterminate ends to their conflicts, where
insurgents retain their capabilities and de facto control over parts of
the country.
xvi Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure S.1
Counterinsurgent Regimes and Conflict Outcomes
100
80 Insurgent victory
Outcome (percentage)
Military stalemate,
60 no settlement
Military stalemate,
40 settlement
Government
victory
20
0
Low High Low High
inclusiveness inclusiveness inclusiveness inclusiveness
Low-capacity High-capacity
government government
RAND RR513-S.1
Figure S.2
Mass Killings by Counterinsurgent Regimes
100
Percentage of cases with mass
killings by government forces
80
60
40
20
0
More-democratic Less-democratic
governments governments
RAND RR513-S.2
Policy Implications
xxi
Abbreviations
xxiii
xxiv Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Introduction
With the United States exhausted by more than a decade of war and
facing severe fiscal limitations, decisionmakers are striving to place
American defense policy on a more sustainable footing. Central to
this effort is a commitment to work through partner nations wherever
possible, providing support to countries with which the United States
shares interests or values while also ensuring that the primary responsi-
bility for these nations’ security remains their own. Thus the document
that currently guides U.S. defense policy states:
1 U.S. Department of Defense, Sustaining U.S. Global Leadership: Priorities for 21st Century
Defense, Washington, D.C.: Department of Defense, January 2012, p. 3. Such a turn in U.S.
defense policy is nothing new. In fact, the United States adopted a remarkably similar policy
as it sought to extricate itself from the Vietnam War. In the speech in which he announced
the “Vietnamization” of the Vietnam War, President Nixon proclaimed a core principle of
what would become known as the Nixon Doctrine: “We shall furnish military and eco-
nomic assistance when requested . . . but we shall look to the nation directly threatened
to assume the primary responsibility of providing the manpower for its defense” (Richard
Nixon, “Address to the Nation on the War in Vietnam,” November 3, 1969, P-691101).
1
2 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
2 See, for instance, Max Boot and Richard Bennett, “Treading Softly in the Philippines,”
The Weekly Standard, Vol. 14, No. 16, January 5–12, 2009; T. X. Hammes, “Counterinsur-
gency: Not a Strategy, but a Necessary Capability,” Joint Force Quarterly, No. 65, 2nd Quar-
ter, 2012, pp. 48–52; Robert D. Kaplan, “Imperial Grunts,” The Atlantic, October 2005;
David Kilcullen, The Accidental Guerrilla: Fighting Small Wars in the Midst of a Big One, New
York: Oxford University Press, 2009, p. 283; Steven Metz, The Army’s Strategic Role, Carl-
isle Barracks, Pa.: Strategic Studies Institute, Army War College, 2009; Thomas E. Ricks,
“More Salvadors, Fewer Vietnams,” The Best Defense, February 19, 2013; David Tucker and
Christopher J. Lamb, “Restructuring Special Operations Forces for Emerging Threats,” Stra-
tegic Forum, Institute for National Strategic Studies, National Defense University, No. 219,
January 2006. On the internal debates within the Department of Defense, see Nancy A.
Youssef, “Pentagon Rethinking Value of Major Counterinsurgencies,” McClatchy News, May
12, 2010.
Introduction 3
military personnel, diplomats, and aid workers are more likely adapt
to local circumstances rather than attempting to re-create a partner
nation in the image of the United States.
The likelihood of success using the small-footprint, or indirect,
approach in such circumstances is inextricably bound with the local
context and particularly the nature of the partner government. Where
the partner government is hopelessly corrupt, abusive toward its own
population, or incompetent and ineffective, or where the partner gov-
ernment is pursuing goals that diverge significantly from those of the
United States, the small-footprint approach can become deeply prob-
lematic.3 Generally speaking, the United States faces two risks when
working with and through partner governments fighting counterin-
surgencies and similar conflicts. First, there is the risk that the partner
government will be ineffective, thus potentially embroiling the United
States in a perpetual conflict.4 Second, there is the risk that the partner
government will be abusive, potentially subjecting the United States
to blowback from the populations that have been abused.5 Working
with even highly problematic partners may be the appropriate policy
choice, depending on the U.S. interests at stake and the goals of the
U.S. partnership. But in such cases the United States should enter into
these partnerships with eyes wide open to the likelihood of success and
the potential risks.
Too often, the importance of local context is minimized in discus-
sions of U.S. security strategy, particularly in relation to the problems
of fragile states. Proponents of small-footprint and indirect approaches,
for instance, overwhelmingly cite as models the recent U.S. operations
in the Philippines and Colombia, without ever providing any indica-
3 For recent cautionary observations about the potential of working through partner gov-
ernments, see, for instance, Daniel L. Byman, “Friends Like These: Counterinsurgency and
the War on Terrorism,” International Security, Vol. 31, No. 2, Fall 2006, pp. 79–115; Nathan
Freier, “The New Theology: Building Partner Capacity,” Small Wars Journal, May 27, 2010.
4 See especially Ariel E. Levite, Bruce W. Jentleson, and Larry Berman, eds., Foreign Mili-
tary Intervention: The Dynamics of Protracted Conflict, New York: Columbia University Press,
1992.
5 See, for instance, Kilcullen, 2009; Michael Scott Doran, “Somebody Else’s Civil War,”
Foreign Affairs, Vol. 81, No. 1, January/February 2002, pp. 22–42.
4 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
The study seeks to understand how local circumstances shape the “art
of the possible” in such contexts and how the United States can best
maximize the potential and minimize the risks of these often uneasy
alliances. More specifically, the study asks three central questions:
6 Examples include Boot and Bennett, 2009; Geoffrey Lambert, Larry Lewis, and
Sarah Sewall, “Operation Enduring Freedom–Philippines: Civilian Harm and the Indi-
rect Approach,” Prism, Vol. 3, No. 4, September 2012, pp. 117–135; Linda Robinson,
“The Future of Special Operations,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 91, No. 6, November-December
2012; Gregory Wilson, “Anatomy of a Successful COIN Operation: OEF-Philippines and
the Indirect Approach,” Military Review, November-December 2006, pp. 2–12; and Paul
Wolfowitz and Michael O’Hanlon, “Plan Afghanistan,” Foreign Policy, October 28, 2011.
7 Michael W. Doyle and Nicholas Sambanis, Making War and Building Peace, Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2006, p. 31.
Introduction 5
This study examines the strategies and practices that regimes adopt
when fighting insurgencies. Other studies have examined the strategies
and practices that counterinsurgents supposedly should adopt, and still
others have focused on how external powers can help to provide them
the capabilities with which to conduct counterinsurgency. Surprisingly,
few studies have systematically examined how regimes actually do prac-
tice counterinsurgency.1 Fewer still have assessed whether the capabili-
ties the United States or other outside actors provide to these regimes
are used in support of counterinsurgency models that are likely to pro-
duce the strategic effects desired by the regimes’ sponsors.
The existing policy literature is focused overwhelmingly on the
experience of the United States and other Western nations. The ends
and means of counterinsurgency are frequently taken as a given, lead-
ing quickly to a narrow focus on operations and tactics. Such a focus
is understandable: Over the past decade, the United States has faced
the urgent task of dealing with its wars in Iraq and Afghanistan. As
the United States plans for the drawdown of its military presence in
Afghanistan and contemplates a wider range of light-footprint “shap-
ing” activities throughout the world, however, it is important for the
defense community to broaden its perspective.
1 For important exceptions, see Christopher Paul, Colin P. Clarke, Beth Grill, and Molly
Dunigan, Paths to Victory: Lessons from Modern Insurgencies, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND
Corporation, RR-291/1-OSD, 2013; Christopher Paul, Colin P. Clarke, and Beth Grill,
Victory Has a Thousand Fathers: Sources of Success in Counterinsurgency, Santa Monica, Calif.:
RAND Corporation, MG-964-OSD, 2010.
7
8 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
2 On the U.S. military’s doctrinal and other adaptations to irregular warfare, see especially
Joint and Coalition Operational Analysis, Decade of War: Vol. I, Enduring Lessons from the
Past Decade of Operations, Suffolk, Va.: Joint Staff J-7, June 15, 2012.
3 For an insightful discussion of the development of recent U.S. counterinsurgency doc-
trine and its limitations, see Jeffrey C. Isaac et al., “The New U.S. Army/Marine Corps Coun-
terinsurgency Field Manual as Political Science and Political Praxis,” Perspectives on Politics,
Vol. 6, No. 2, June 2008, pp. 347–360.
4 These limitations have been broadly recognized and have spurred U.S. practitioners to begin
expanding and adapting policy guidance for these conflicts. In January 2009, the U.S. Govern-
ment Counterinsurgency Guide was published, incorporating the insights of nine government
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 9
departments and agencies. Unlike U.S. Department of the Army, Field Manual (FM) 3-24,
the Counterinsurgency Guide is more forward-looking and examines the conditions under
which the United States should engage in future counterinsurgencies abroad. Five levels of
involvement spanning the gamut from the deployment of a single advisor to a robust direct
intervention are discussed. In addition, the U.S. Army is taking the lead on drafting a revi-
sion to FM 3-24 and has invited feedback from a wide range of scholars, practitioners, and
operators. As of this writing, the estimated date of publication is December 2013.
5 See, for instance, Hammes, 2012, p. 49, and remarks by Eliot Cohen, “To COIN or Not?”
transcript from a roundtable discussion co-sponsored by Foreign Policy and the RAND Cor-
poration, March 18, 2013.
10 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
6 Jason Lyall, “Are Coethnics More Effective Counterinsurgents? Evidence from the Second
Chechen War,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 104, No. 1, February 2010, pp. 1–20.
There are, of course, important exceptions. See especially Paul, Clarke, and Grill, 2010.
7 Paul Staniland, “States, Insurgents, and Wartime Political Orders,” Perspectives on Poli-
tics, Vol. 10, No. 2, June 2012, p. 244.
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 11
Varieties of Counterinsurgency
8 David R. Haines, “COIN in the Real World,” Parameters, Winter 2008–2009, pp. 50–51.
9 For a related argument, see Huw Bennett, “The Reluctant Pupil? Britain’s Army and
Learning in Counter-Insurgency,” London: Royal United Services Institute, 2009.
12 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Bounded Accommodation
The need to bring the reconcilable opposition into the political process
has long been recognized, but its importance has increased in recent
decades as the dynamics of insurgencies have changed.
Insurgencies endure much longer than they once did: The aver-
age duration of civil wars in the period immediately after World War
10 David Galula, Counterinsurgency Warfare: Theory and Practice, Westport, Conn.: Praeger
Security International, 2006 [1964]; Sir Robert Thompson, Defeating Communist Insurgency:
The Lessons of Malaya and Vietnam, Saint Petersburg, Fla.: Hailer Publishing, 2005 [1966].
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 13
II was only approximately two years, but by the post–Cold War era,
their duration had risen to about 15 years.11 This trend is rooted in
a number of factors that appear unlikely to change, including the
increasing availability of small arms and light weapons, the widespread
adoption of guerrilla tactics, the ready availability of rebel funding
through the trafficking of contraband, and the general unwillingness
of major powers to make large and indefinite commitments to allies
in the developing world.12 This steady upward trend in the duration of
insurgencies suggests that it is increasingly difficult to end these con-
flicts through outright military victory.
These conflicts are also extremely damaging to the countries in
which they are fought—so much so that they have been described
as “development in reverse.”13 Consequently, leaders with a stake in
the post-conflict future of their country may well decide that offering
at least portions of the armed opposition the opportunity to share in
power is superior to a long and damaging fight to the finish.
Moreover, insurgencies have extremely damaging consequences
beyond the borders of the country originally affected: They generally
increase the risk of spillover conflicts throughout the region in which
they occur, damage the economies of neighboring states, contribute
to flourishing transnational crime networks, spread pandemic disease,
and foster transnational terrorism.14 Unless outside powers are willing
11 James D. Fearon and David D. Laitin, “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War,” American
Political Science Review, Vol. 97, No. 1, February, 2003, p. 78. The exact durations of wars
vary according to how social scientists define what counts as a “civil war” and when the wars’
precise start and end dates are, but the general trend is broadly recognized. See also Monica
Duffy Toft, Securing the Peace: The Durable Settlement of Civil Wars, Princeton, N.J.: Prince-
ton University Press, 2010.
12 Fearon and Laitin, 2003; Toft, 2010; see also James D. Fearon, “Why Do Some Civil
Wars Last So Much Longer than Others?” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 41, No. 3,
pp. 275–301.
13 Paul Collier, V. L. Elliott, Havard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol, and
Nicholas Sambanis, Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Policy Development, Washing-
ton, D.C.: The World Bank and Oxford University Press, 2003, Ch. 1.
14 Collier et al., 2003, Ch. 2.
14 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
15 Stephen Watts, Caroline Baxter, Molly Dunigan, and Christopher Rizzi, The Uses and
Limits of Small-Scale Military Interventions, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation,
2012.
16 Toft, 2010, Ch. 1.
17 These distinctions between different types of insurgents parallel those in Stephen
Stedman’s typology of “spoilers,” in which he divides parties that can undermine peace pro-
cesses into three groups: what he terms limited, greedy, and total. The reconcilable opposition
corresponds to the first two of these groups, while the irreconcilable opposition corresponds
to the last. See Stephen John Stedman, “Spoiler Problems in Peace Processes,” International
Security, Vol. 22, No. 2, Fall 1997, pp. 5–53.
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 15
Discriminate Violence
There is strong support for the notion that government use of force usu-
ally must be discriminate to be successful.18 If the government employs
violence only against those who oppose it while leaving unharmed
those who are neutral, the population has considerable incentive to
avoid opposing the government. On the other hand, if neutrality is no
guarantee of safety (that is, if violence is indiscriminate), the popula-
tion is much more likely to seek safety or payment from rebels.19 There
is significant evidence to suggest that, much like the need to accommo-
date the reconcilable opposition, the imperative to use force discrimi-
nately is a counterinsurgency principle with broad applicability.
18 Paul et al., 2013; Paul, Clarke, and Grill, 2010; Matthew Adam Kocher, Thomas B. Pepinsky,
and Stathis N. Kalyvas, “Aerial Bombing and Counterinsurgency in the Vietnam War,”
American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 55, No. 2, April 2011, pp. 201–218; Monica Duffy
Toft and Yuri M. Zhukov, “Denial and Punishment in the North Caucasus: Evaluating
the Effectiveness of Coercive Counterinsurgency,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 49, No. 6,
2012, pp. 785–800. Not all analyses agree, however. See, for instance, Jason Lyall, “Does
Indiscriminate Violence Incite Insurgent Attacks? Evidence from Chechnya,” Journal of Con-
flict Resolution, Vol. 53, No. 3, June 2009, pp. 331–362.
19 T. David Mason and Dale A. Krane, “The Political Economy of Death Squads: Toward
a Theory of the Impact of State-Sanctioned Terror,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 33,
No. 2, June 1989, pp. 175–198.
16 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
20 U.S. Department of the Army, Stability, Army Doctrinal Publication 3-05, August 2012,
p. 10.
21 The World Bank, Fragile States: Good Practice in Country Assistance Strategies, Washing-
ton, D.C., 2005, p. 3.
22 See especially, Paul, Clarke, and Grill, 2010, 2013, for research in favor of this view. For
a contrasting perspective, see Eli Berman, Jacob N. Shapiro, and Joseph H. Felter, “Can
Hearts and Minds Be Bought? The Economics of Counterinsurgency in Iraq,” Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 119, No. 4, August 2011, pp. 766–819. Note that Paul’s work exam-
ines specific practices rather than regimes’ ability to implement those practices. It may well
be that highly capable states are more likely to succeed in counterinsurgency campaigns if
they provide public goods, while efforts by extremely weak states to provide public goods
may have the opposite effect. The importance of understanding the character of the counter-
insurgent regime is a theme to which this report frequently returns.
23 Lant Pritchett, Michael Woolcock, and Matt Andrews, Capability Traps? The Mechanisms
of Persistent Implementation Failure, Washington, D.C.: Center for Global Development,
Working Paper 234, December 2010.
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 17
24 See for instance Jeffrey Herbst, States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Author-
ity and Control, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2000; Christopher Clapham,
“The Global-Local Politics of State Decay,” in Robert I. Rotberg, ed., When States Fail:
Causes and Consequences, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2004; Pierre
Englebert and Denis M. Tull, “Postconflict Reconstruction in Africa: Flawed Ideas About
Failed States,” International Security, Vol. 32, No. 4, 2008, pp. 106–139.
25 See, for instance, Robert H. Bates, Prosperity and Violence: The Political Economy of Devel-
opment, New York: W. W. Norton, 2001.
26 Angel Rabasa, Steven Boraz, Peter Chalk, Kim Cragin, Theodore W. Karasik, Jennifer
D. P. Moroney, Kevin A. O’Brien, and John E. Peters, Ungoverned Territories: Understand-
ing and Reducing Terrorism Risks, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, MG-561-AF,
2007.
18 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure 2.1
Typology of Counterinsurgency Models
High
Political
accommodation
of reconcilable
opposition
Low
Public-goods provision
Low to disaffected
High
Low High communities
Discrimination in use of
violence against irreconcilable
opposition
RAND RR513-2.1
27 Other strategies besides these four are, of course, feasible. As the remainder of this chapter
and Chapter Three reveal, however, these four appear to be particularly common in practice.
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 19
Political Inclusion
The first critical characteristic of counterinsurgent regimes, politi-
cal inclusiveness, is understood here as the extent to which organized
28 Paul Dixon, “‘Hearts and Minds’? British Counter-Insurgency from Malaya to Iraq,”
Journal of Strategic Studies, Vol. 32, No. 3, 2009, pp. 353–381.
22 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
29 This concept is similar to Dahl’s concept of “polyarchy.” See Robert A. Dahl, Polyarchy:
Participation and Opposition, New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1972.
30 This claim was particularly common during the Cold War. See, for instance, Douglas
S. Blaufarb, The Counterinsurgency Era: U.S. Doctrine and Performance, 1950 to the Present,
New York: The Free Press, 1977; D. Michael Shafer, Deadly Paradigms: The Failure of U.S.
Counterinsurgency Policy, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988; and Mason and
Krane, 1989, pp. 175–198. However, the logic is more generalizable. Political scientists have
spelled out this logic in “selectorate theory”; see especially Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and
Alastair Smith, “Leader Survival, Revolutions, and the Nature of Government Finance,”
American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 54, No. 4, October 2010, pp. 936–950.
31 James D. Fearon, “Rationalist Explanations for War,” International Organization, Vol. 49,
No. 3, Summer 1995, pp. 379–414; Barbara F. Walter, “The Critical Barrier to Civil War
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 23
Settlement,” International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3, Summer 1997; Kenneth A. Schultz,
Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001.
32 The existing literature has not reached a consensus about the effects of democracy on coun-
terinsurgency outcomes. Paul, Clarke, and Grill, 2010, maintain that democracy is weakly
associated with counterinsurgent victory, but updated work in Paul et al., 2013, finds no such
relationship. Ben Connable and Martin C. Libicki find a very complex relationship between
democracy and victory. See Ben Connable and Martin C. Libicki, How Insurgencies End,
Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, MG-965-MCIA, 2010, pp. 186–187. Jason Lyall
finds no relationship. See Jason Lyall, “Do Democracies Make Inferior Counterinsurgents? Re-
assessing Democracy’s Impact on War Outcomes and Duration,” International Organiza-
tion, Vol. 64, Winter 2010b, pp. 167–192. It is important to note that the research in this
report is focusing on the post–Cold War era, while these other studies examined much
longer periods of time. There are many reasons to believe that the dynamics of insurgency
and counterinsurgency have shifted in recent decades, making it more necessary for regimes
now to reach an accommodation with the reconcilable elements of the armed opposition.
We have not examined previous eras (i.e., the Cold War era or earlier) to determine how this
relationship has changed over time, although there remains much important research to be
done on this topic.
24 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
33 See Gil Merom, How Democracies Lose Small Wars, New York: Cambridge University
Press, 2003.
34 For a highly nuanced discussion of the effects of democracy on the state’s use of violence,
see especially Christian Davenport, State Repression and the Domestic Democratic Peace, New
York: Cambridge University Press, 2007a. On the general propensity of more-democratic
regimes to use violence more selectively, see Kristine Eck and Lisa Hultman, “One-Sided
Violence Against Civilians in War: Insights from New Fatality Data,” Journal of Peace
Research, Vol. 44, No. 2, 2007, pp. 233–246.
35 Barbara Harff, “No Lessons Learned from the Holocaust? Assessing Risks of Genocide
and Political Mass Murder Since 1955,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 97, No. 1,
February 2003, pp. 57–73; Michael Colaresi and Sabine C. Carey, “To Kill or to Pro-
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 25
State Capacity
The second critical characteristic of the counterinsurgent is state
capacity—what Samuel Huntington called the degree rather than the
type of government.37 Like political inclusiveness, state capacity is an
important determinant of a regime’s ability to reach acceptable accom-
modations with armed opposition groups. In particular, state capacity
can influence a regime’s ability to achieve negotiated outcomes in two
ways:
tect: Security Forces, Domestic Institutions, and Genocide,” Journal of Conflict Resolution,
Vol. 52, No. 1, February 2008, pp. 39–67; R. J. Rummel, “Democracy, Power, Genocide,
and Mass Murder,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 39, No. 1, 1995, pp. 3–26.
36 Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, George W. Downs, Alastair Smith, and Feryal Marie Cherif,
“Thinking Inside the Box: A Closer Look at Democracy and Human Rights,” International
Studies Quarterly, Vol. 49, 2005, pp. 439–457; Davenport, 2007a; Christian Davenport,
“State Repression and Political Order,” Annual Review of Political Science, Vol. 10, 2007b,
pp. 1–23; Sabine C. Zanger, “A Global Analysis of the Effect of Political Regime Changes
on Life Integrity Violations, 1977–93,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 37, No. 2, 2000,
pp. 213–233.
37Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies, New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press, 1968, p. 1.
38 See, for instance, U.S. Department of the Army, 2006; Paul et al., 2013; Paul, Clarke, and
Grill, 2010; Connable and Libicki, 2010, pp. 186–187; and Robert I. Rotberg, “The Failure
and Collapse of Nation-States: Breakdown, Prevention, and Repair,” in Robert I. Rotberg,
ed., When States Fail: Causes and Consequences, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press,
2004.
26 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
39 For a formal explication of this logic, see especially Berman, Shapiro, and Felter, 2011. See
also Helge Holtermann, “Explaining the Development–Civil War Relationship,” Conflict
Management and Peace Science, Vol. 29, No. 1, 2012, p. 63.
40 Fearon and Laitin, 2003, p. 80, for instance, argues that “effective counterinsurgency
requires government forces to distinguish active rebels from noncombatants without
destroying the lives and living conditions of the latter. This is an extremely difficult political,
military, and organizational problem even for well-equipped and well-paid modern militar-
ies. . . . For less well-financed and bureaucratically competent states, the problem appears
to be nearly insoluble. Such states either cannot prevent the abuse of local powers by field
commanders or may even permit these abuses as a sort of tax farming to the military. That
is, they ‘pay’ the soldiers with the opportunity to loot and pillage, a practice that tends to
sustain rather than end insurgencies.” Stathis Kalyvas and Laia Balcells argue that govern-
ment forces have become almost indistinguishable from rebels in many conflicts, particularly
in the post–Cold War era. See Stathis N. Kalyvas and Laia Balcells, “International System
and Technologies of Rebellion: How the End of the Cold War Shaped Internal Conflict,”
American Political Science Review, Vol. 104, No. 3, August 2010, pp. 415–429. Perhaps the
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 27
Military Superiority
Counterinsurgency is, in the end, a form of warfare. The quality of
governance provided by the regime is critical, but without the req-
uisite military capabilities, governance is inadequate. Violent con-
flict emerges precisely because the parties to the conflict cannot find
a mutually acceptable solution to their disagreements within existing
political mechanisms. Even if the government improves the quality of
its governance during the course of an insurgency, a political solution
that does not sacrifice core government interests requires at a mini-
mum a military stalemate, if not the clear superiority of the governing
forces.42
For this reason, many observers have argued that the military
capabilities of a regime are a third determinant of counterinsurgency
approaches and outcomes. We argue that military capabilities play an
important role, but their effects can be understood only in terms of
the regime for which they fight. Consequently, we examine the effects
of military capabilities throughout this study and, in particular, their
archetypal example is the rise of “sobels” during Sierra Leone’s civil war—government sol-
diers by day who turned into rebels by night, preying on the general population in both of
these incarnations.
41 See for instance Jeffrey Herbst, “African Militaries and Rebellion: The Political Economy
of Threat and Combat Effectiveness,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 41, No. 3, May 2004,
pp. 361–362.
42U.S. Department of the Army, 2006, especially pp. 1–21; Nathan Leites and Charles
Wolf, Jr., Rebellion and Authority, Chicago: Markham Publishing Company, 1970.
28 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
• Regimes that are more politically inclusive and have higher degrees
of state capacity are more likely to adopt the classical approach to
counterinsurgency.
• Regimes that are more politically inclusive but possess only weak
state capacity are more likely to adopt informal accommodation
as their predominant strategy.
• Regimes that are less politically inclusive and have higher degrees
of state capacity are more likely to engage in strong-state repression.
• Regimes that are less politically inclusive and possess weak state
capacity are more likely to pursue containment strategies.
Table 2.1
Determinants of Counterinsurgency Strategy
Regime Characteristics
43 Freedom House, Freedom in the World, Washington, D.C., 2013. As described in greater
detail in Chapter Three and the Appendix, Freedom House scores were based on three differ-
ent time periods: the average score of the country throughout all years of conflict, the average
score in the final two years of conflict, and the average score from the five years prior to the
conflict’s onset.
44 Holtermann, 2012, p. 63. This variable is constructed as an index of three different fac-
tors: road density, proportion of the population that is urban, and telephone density. Unfor-
tunately, the data do not cover the entire period of the conflicts under review. Consequently,
we were forced to use the entire post–Cold War period as the basis for each country’s state-
reach score. Doing so clearly introduces some degree of distortion to the measure; countries
in which conflicts terminated in the early post–Cold War period, for instance, are more
likely to have a higher state-reach score than countries with conflicts that endured for much
of the post–Cold War period because the former states would have had more years of peace
(and thus opportunity to recover from wartime destruction) in the period being measured.
Despite this limitation, the state-reach variable still does a creditable job of differentiating
lower- and higher-capacity states. As with the rest of the quantitative analysis, details may be
found in the Appendix. The authors are grateful to Helge Holtermann for sharing his data.
30 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
civil service and the degree of its independence from political pressures,
the quality of policy formulation and implementation, and the cred-
ibility of the government’s commitment to such policies.”45
Finally, military superiority in counterinsurgency has tradi-
tionally been measured in terms of force-to-force ratios or force-to-
population ratios—that is, the ratio of government forces to insur-
gent forces or the ratio of government forces to the population
(typically expressed in terms of government forces for each 1,000
inhabitants of a country).46 James T. Quinlivan argued that force-to-
population ratios are the most appropriate rule of thumb for sizing
forces in counterinsurgency:
Others have argued instead that force-to-force ratios are the more
appropriate measure.48 Unfortunately, there is very little standardized
45 Daniel Kaufmann, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi, Governance Matters VIII: Aggre-
gate and Individual Governance Indicators, 1996–2008, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank,
Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 4978, June 2009, p. 6. As
with the state-reach variable, the limited number of years for which data were available
meant that we were forced to use available data for the entire post–Cold War period rather
than data from only the period of conflict. Similarly, despite this limitation of the data, gov-
ernment effectiveness remains a useful—if rough—measure of the underlying concept.
46 U.S. Department of the Army, 2006, pp. 1–13. On force-to-population ratios specifically,
see James T. Quinlivan, “Force Requirements in Stability Operations,” Parameters: U.S.
Army War College Quarterly, Vol. 25, No. 4, Winter 1995/1996, pp. 59–69. For critical exam-
inations of both ratios, see Steven M. Goode, “A Historical Basis for Force Requirements
in Counterinsurgency,” Parameters: U.S. Army War College Quarterly, Winter 2009/2010,
pp. 45–57; Joshua Thiel, “COIN Manpower Ratios: Debunking the 10 to 1 Ratio and
Surges,” Small Wars Journal, January 15, 2011.
47 Quinlivan, 1995-1996, pp. 59–69.
48 FM 3-24 suggests the use of both measures.
Counterinsurgency in Comparative Perspective 31
Table 2.2
A Typology of Counterinsurgent Regimes
Regime Characteristics
Predicted
Political State Dominant
Inclusivity Capacity n Cases Strategy
49 Data on government forces and country populations during the period of conflict are
from The World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI) dataset.
32 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 2.2—Continued
Regime Characteristics
Predicted
Political State Dominant
Inclusivity Capacity n Cases Strategy
1 More specifically, if any portion of an insurgency was fought after 1989 and before 2010,
it was included in this analysis. The original dataset of insurgencies underlying this research
was taken from Doyle and Sambanis, 2006, with data updated to 2010 from Watts et al.,
2012. See the Appendix for the cases and coding notes.
2 More detailed notes on all of the concepts, data, and coding decisions underlying this
quantitative analysis are given in the Appendix. The dataset on which the analysis relied and
more detailed findings are available upon request from the authors.
33
34 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
3 Data on formal peace agreements were taken from Doyle and Sambanis, 2006, and were
updated to 2008 by the authors of this report. See the Appendix for details of the coding
procedures.
4 See, for instance, Rabasa et al., 2007.
5 On the utility of formal peace agreements, see Virginia Page Fortna, “Scraps of Paper?
Agreements and the Durability of Peace,” International Organization, Vol. 57, No. 2, Spring
2003, pp. 337–372. Although Fortna writes specifically about interstate conflicts, the logic is
generally applicable to internal conflicts as well. On how the specific content of peace agree-
ments shapes post-conflict prospects for peace, see, for instance, Caroline Hartzell, Matthew
Hoddie, and Donald Rothchild, “Stabilizing the Peace After Civil War: An Investigation of
Some Key Variables,” International Organization, Vol. 55, No. 1, Winter 2001, pp. 183–208.
36 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 3.1
Conflict Outcomes in the Post–Cold War Era
Number of
Type of Conflict Outcome Conflicts
Government victory 17
Military stalemate, formal peace agreement 17
Military stalemate, no formal peace agreement 14
Insurgent victory 24
Political Inclusivity
The record of all conflicts that have terminated in the post–Cold
War era strongly supports the notion that more-democratic countries
are much better able than less-democratic countries to accommo-
date armed opposition movements without sacrificing core interests. 6
Figure 3.1 shows the relationship between a government’s degree of
democracy and its likelihood of securing a formally negotiated peace
to end an internal conflict. More-democratic countries are those that
6 Conflicts that were ongoing as of 2008 were excluded from the analysis.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 37
Figure 3.1
Relationship Between Democracy and Negotiated Settlements
100
Percentage of cases terminating
in negotiated settlements
80
60
40
20
0
More-democratic Less-democratic
countries countries
RAND RR513-3.1
score in the upper half of the Freedom House democracy index over
the course of a conflict, and less-democratic countries are those that
score in the bottom half of this index.7 As can be seen from Figure 3.1,
nearly half of the conflicts in more-democratic countries end in for-
mally negotiated settlements, while less than one-quarter of those in
less-democratic countries do.
Similarly, more-democratic countries are better able to achieve
an acceptable decisive outcome—that is, an end to an internal war in
which the government either wins an outright military victory or is
able to reach a formally negotiated peace agreement with the armed
7 Specifically, an average value of 4.0 on both the Political Rights and Civil Liberties
dimensions of the Freedom House index was used as the break point between more- and
less-democratic countries. Data on negotiated settlements were taken from Doyle and
Sambanis, 2006, updated to 2008 by the authors of this report. c2 = 2.7386, and the rela-
tionship is statistically significant at the 0.1 level (p = 0.098). In this calculation, all cases in
which a large military intervention occurred in the post-conflict period were dropped from
the sample on the assumption that the prospect of such an intervention would heavily condi-
tion the likelihood of a negotiated settlement. The relationship remains statistically signifi-
cant at the 0.1 level if those cases are retained. Data on foreign interventions, including the
distinction between large- and small-scale interventions, were taken from Watts et al., 2012.
38 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure 3.2
Relationship Between Democracy and Acceptable Decisive Outcomes
100
Percentage of cases terminating
in an acceptable outcome
80
60
40
20
0
More-democratic Less-democratic
countries countries
RAND RR513-3.2
8 c2 = 3.6409, and the bivariate relationship is statistically significant at the 0.1 level
(p = 0.056). If we are interested only in outright military victories, we find—perhaps
surprisingly—that democracies are somewhat more likely to win, although the difference
is not sufficient to achieve statistical significance. Relatively more-democratic states won
approximately one-quarter of the time (six cases out of 23), whereas non-democracies won
only approximately one-sixth of their counterinsurgencies (11 cases out of 65).
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 39
Figure 3.3
Relationship Between Democracy and Durable Peace
100
Percentage of cases returning to
80
war within five years
60
40
20
0
More-democratic Less-democratic
countries countries
RAND RR513-3.3
9 c2 = 2.8236 and p = 0.093. Cases in which a large foreign military force was deployed in
the post-conflict period were excluded from this analysis on the assumption that the post-
conflict trajectory of the country was too strongly influenced by the large-scale foreign inter-
vention to yield accurate information about the relationship between the domestic regime
and the conflict outcome. Data on foreign interventions, including the distinction between
large- and small-scale interventions, were taken from Watts et al., 2012.
10 Colombia had an average Freedom House score of 3.2 during the course of its conflict;
the Philippines had an average score of 3.5 throughout the period of its conflict with Muslim
separatist groups; and El Salvador had an average score of 3.8.
40 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
State Capacity
The data from the post–Cold War period also support the proposition
that state capacity influences a counterinsurgent’s ability to achieve an
acceptable outcome to a conflict.13 As discussed previously, this analy-
sis uses two measures of state capacity: state reach, a measure of a state’s
ability to penetrate social relations and exercise meaningful effects in
the population’s day-to-day lives, and government effectiveness, a mea-
sure of the bureaucratic capacity of the state.14 Counterinsurgents with
strong state capacity (as measured using either indicator) are more
11 These 89 cases include ongoing conflicts that were dropped from the statistical analysis of
outcomes.
12 The relationship between political inclusiveness and political accommodation is even
stronger if we focus only on a counterinsurgent regime’s level of democracy at the tail end of
a conflict. It may be that insurgents are less concerned about a regime’s democratic character
at the start of a conflict than they are about its character toward the end, when it is attempt-
ing to negotiate an end to fighting. On the basis of a counterinsurgent regime’s average
democracy score in the final two years of a conflict, more-democratic governments are more
than three times as likely to achieve a formally negotiated settlement than less-democratic
regimes, securing such settlements in 55 percent and 17 percent of cases, respectively (c2 =
9.2960 and p = 0.002, an extremely strong statistical relationship). Similarly, governments
that are more democratic toward the end of a conflict are much better able to achieve accept-
able decisive outcomes (again, defined as either a military victory by the government or a
military stalemate that is formally codified in a peace deal accepted by both sides). Approxi-
mately 70 percent of more-democratic governments are able to achieve such decisive results,
whereas just over 40 percent of less-democratic governments (c2 = 4.3799) can do so, and the
relationship is statistically significant at the 0.05 level, with p = 0.036). Finally, a government
that is more democratic in the final two years of a conflict is more likely to sustain a peace.
Nearly half (48 percent) of less-democratic regimes experienced a return to conflict within
five years of the end of a civil war, whereas only one-fifth (20 percent) of more-democratic
regimes did (c2 = 4.2656 and p = 0.039).
13 As in the analysis of political inclusiveness, the analysis of the effects of state capacity on
conflict outcomes excluded all cases of conflict that were still ongoing as of 2008.
14 States with high state reach are those that score above the midpoint (0.5) of Heltermann’s
state-reach index, while states with high government effectiveness are those with scores above
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 41
Figure 3.4
Relationship Between State Reach and Acceptable Decisive Outcomes
100
Percentage of cases terminating
with an acceptable outcome
80
60
40
20
0
High state reach Low state reach
RAND RR513-3.4
the median for conflict-affected countries (those that experienced civil wars in the post–Cold
War era).
15 c2 = 6.2045 and p = 0.013.
16 c2 = 4.8673 and p = 0.027.
42 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure 3.5
Relationship Between Government Effectiveness and Acceptable Decisive
Outcomes
100
Percentage of cases terminating
with an acceptable outcome
80
60
40
20
0
High government Low government
effectiveness effectiveness
RAND RR513-3.5
Figure 3.6
Relationship Between State Reach and Indeterminate Outcomes
100
Percentage of cases terminating
with an indeterminate outcome
80
60
40
20
0
High state reach Low state reach
RAND RR513-3.6
Military Sufficiency
Consistent with the findings in Chapter Two, data from the post–Cold
War era suggest an ambiguous relationship between a government’s
military capacity and conflict outcomes. High force-to-population
ratios and high force-to-force ratios are associated with somewhat
better odds of a government victory, but the difference between more
and less militarily-capable governments is not sufficient to be statisti-
cally significant in nearly any of the specifications we examined.18
18 We used two alternative break points for distinguishing between governments with high
and low force-to-population ratios: a 10:1,000 ratio and a 5:1,000 ratio. (We used these low
ratios rather than the doctrinally accepted 20:1,000 because, to the best of our knowledge,
there are no systematic data on police forces for all of the countries in our sample. Thus,
our calculations relied on only the military portion of a government’s security forces. Of
44 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
the 88 cases in our sample, 41 had force-to-population ratios of 5:1,000 or greater, so this
lower threshold is close to the median value.) We also relied on two alternative specifications
of force-to-force ratios. The first one used the doctrinally accepted ratio of 10 government
forces for every insurgent. Again, however, our data include only military forces, so such a
threshold is potentially artificially high. Consequently, we also used the median force-to-
force ratio from all of the countries in our sample as a second break point between high- and
low-capacity governments. Finally, we examined both the outcomes of all cases of insurgency
that ended in the post–Cold War era and the outcomes of only those cases in which a large
external intervention force did not deploy in the post-conflict period (on the assumption
that the prospect of such an intervention force would strongly influence the outcome of a
conflict). In all of these cases, the relationship operated in the expected direction: Govern-
ments with greater military capacity generally had somewhat better odds of winning. In only
one specification (using force-to-force ratios with the break point between high- and low-
capacity governments determined by the median value and with all cases for which we did
not have relatively precise data on insurgent strength dropped from the sample), however, did
the relationship achieve statistical significance.
19 Depending on the precise specification of the relationship used, the results can range
from no relationship whatsoever (i.e., high- and low-capacity states have almost exactly
the same odds of achieving a favorable decisive outcome) to a weak relationship (i.e., high-
capacity states tend to achieve better outcomes, but the relationship is not sufficiently strong
to be statistically significant at even the 0.1 level).
20 As with the other relationships in this analysis, higher force ratios typically lead to slightly
better odds of favorable outcomes but not sufficiently improved odds for the relationship to
be statistically significant. In some specifications, the relationship is actually reversed, and
higher force ratios are associated with slightly worse outcomes—but again, these relation-
ships achieve nowhere near statistical significance.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 45
outcomes; (2) there may be a relationship, but our methods are in-
adequate to reveal it; or (3) there may be a relationship between military
capabilities and counterinsurgency outcomes, but measures of simple
numerical superiority (i.e., capacity) are inadequate to capture it.
The first possibility flies in the face of U.S. military doctrine and
the writings of many of the most respected counterinsurgency theo-
rists. The possibility should not be dismissed, however. As discussed in
the Chapter Two, counterinsurgency warfare has changed profoundly
in the past few decades due to the proliferation of small arms and light
weapons, changes in funding streams, the spread of guerrilla tactics,
and a radically altered international context, among other reasons.
Whereas military victory was the norm in the decades following World
War II, a minority of insurgencies terminate in victory today. It is pos-
sible that although they are still important, military means simply do
not exercise the same degree of influence on conflict outcomes that
they once did.
It is also possible that our methods are inadequate to capture the
relationship between military capacity and conflict outcomes. In par-
ticular, it could be that especially dangerous insurgencies cause gov-
ernments to build large security forces. In this case, our results could
be biased by adverse selection: The countries with particularly difficult
insurgencies would create large security forces, leading to an appar-
ently inverse relationship between the size of the forces and success in
battling insurgencies. Such biases may be particularly apparent when
using force-to-population ratios. Our use of the force-to-force measure,
however, should at least partially alleviate this concern. Insofar as the
number of insurgents is an indication of the threat they pose to the
government, force-to-force ratios automatically control for the possi-
bility of adverse selection. Force-to-force ratios, however, also failed to
reveal any consistent relationship between military superiority and the
ability to secure favorable outcomes.
Finally, and perhaps most plausibly, the lack of a statistically sig-
nificant relationship between military capacity and conflict outcomes
could be driven by our measure of military superiority. Force ratios
capture only the number of government forces. They say nothing about
their equipment; their tactics, techniques and procedures; or their dis-
46 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
21 Chris Paul and his colleagues, for instance, find that in only five out of 85 cases did
government forces avoid “excessive collateral damage, disproportionate use of force, or
other illegitimate applications of force.” See Paul, Clarke, and Grill, 2010. Similarly, when
we compare Ulfelder and Valentino’s list of “mass killings” by government forces with the
list of recent civil wars, we find that governments engaged in mass killings (as defined by
Ulfelder and Valentino) in more than two-thirds of all cases of civil war or insurgency. See
Jay Ulfelder and Benjamin Valentino, Assessing Risks of State-Sponsored Mass Killing, Politi-
cal Instability Task Force, February 2008, with data updated through 2010 by the authors
of this report, and the list of civil wars taken from Doyle and Sambanis, 2006, updated in
Watts et al., 2012.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 47
Political Inclusivity
A broad review of the historical record of the past two decades strongly
supports the claim that democratic accountability is critically impor-
tant to preventing abuses and atrocities by government forces. Only
two relatively democratic countries (fewer than 10 percent of the total)
engaged in mass killings of civilians during the course of counterinsur-
gency campaigns in this period.23 In contrast, less-democratic countries
engaged in mass killings in more than one-third of all counterinsur-
gencies.24 Figure 3.7 shows the stark difference between the two types
of regimes in their propensity to use indiscriminate violence. Demo-
22 We used the most comprehensive data on large-scale killings by government forces that
we could find—Ulfelder and Valentino’s mass-killings database, developed as part of the
CIA-funded Political Instability Task Force. We then matched these events to Doyle and
Sambanis’ list of civil wars or insurgencies. We took the average of the high-end and low-end
estimates of civilian deaths, then determined the average number of deaths per year of the
conflict.
23As before, relatively democratic is defined as scoring in the top half of Freedom House’s
democracy index (i.e., an average combined score of 4 or less during the course of a conflict).
24 c2 = 6.9282, and the results are statistically significant at the 0.01 level (p = 0.008).
48 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure 3.7
Relationship Between Democracy and Mass Killings of Civilians by
Government Forces
100
Percentage of cases with mass
killings by government forces
80
60
40
20
0
More-democratic Less-democratic
governments governments
RAND RR513-3.7
State Capacity
As discussed in Chapter Two, state capacity might influence a regime’s
proclivity toward indiscriminate violence in two ways: Weak states may
be more likely to use indiscriminate violence because they lack suf-
ficient positive inducements to persuade discontented populations to
side with them, or they may be more likely to engage in abuses because
they lack sufficient oversight and control over their fielded forces. The
state-reach variable is probably a better choice of measures to test the
argument that weak regimes rely excessively on “sticks” because they
have too few “carrots.” The government-effectiveness variable is prob-
ably more appropriate for assessing the extent to which more-capable
governments are able sustain more-disciplined forces in the field.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 49
Military Sufficiency
An examination of the relationship between force ratios and mass kill-
ings of civilians produces seemingly inconsistent results. Force-to-force
ratios provide apparent support for the claim that less-capable regimes
resort to indiscriminate violence in desperation, lacking the military
Figure 3.8
Relationship Between Government Effectiveness and Mass Killings of
Civilians by Government Forces
100
Percentage of cases with mass
killings by government forces
80
60
40
20
0
High state reach Low state reach
RAND RR513-3.8
25 c2 = 0.2026 and p = 0.653 for the bivariate relationship including all cases. The lack of
a clear relationship is not changed by dropping cases in which a large, external interven-
ing force was present during the conflict or by dropping cases in which conflicts had not
concluded.
26 c2 = 3.4599 and p = 0.063.
50 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure 3.9
Relationship Between Force-to-Force Ratio and Mass Killings of Civilians by
Government Forces
100
Percentage of cases with mass
killings by government forces
80
60
40
20
0
High force-to-force Low force-to-force
ratio ratio
RAND RR513-3.9
27 Benjamin Valentino, Paul Huth, and Dylan Balch-Lindsay, “‘Draining the Sea’: Mass
Killing and Guerrilla Warfare,” International Organization, Vol. 58, No. 2, Spring 2004,
pp. 375–407; Alexander B. Downes, “Desperate Times, Desperate Measures: The Causes
of Civilian Victimization in War,” International Security, Vol. 30, No. 4, Spring 2006,
pp. 152–195; Reed M. Wood, Jacob D. Kathman, and Stephen E. Gent, “Armed Intervention
and Civilian Victimization in Intrastate Conflicts,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 49, No. 5,
2012, pp. 647–660; David Fielding and Anja Shortland, “The Dynamics of Terror During
the Peruvian Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 49, No. 6, 2012, pp. 847–862.
28 c2 = 3.8651 and p = 0.049. If we instead use the median force-to-force ratio among all
cases of conflict in our sample as the break point between more- and less-capable govern-
ments, the relationship remains much the same, although it is not quite as strong and nar-
rowly misses achieving statistical significance.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 51
Figure 3.10
Relationship Between Force-to-Population Ratio and Mass Killings of
Civilians by Government Forces
100
Percentage of cases with mass
killings by government forces
80
60
40
20
0
High force-to-population Low force-to-population
ratio (≥5/1,000) ratio (<5/1,000)
RAND RR513-3.10
the large security sector is the cause of both the large insurgency and
the mass killings.
Much is at stake in parsing these alternative explanations. If the
first explanation is true, the appropriate policy response may well be
to build stronger security sectors to weaken insurgents. If the second
explanation is correct, such a policy would pour oil on the fire.
Unfortunately, the simple quantitative techniques used here do
not allow us to determine which of these rival explanations is correct.
Even the most sophisticated statistical techniques would provide only
partial insight into this question.31 To establish the conditions under
which strong military capabilities are likely to yield more or less dis-
criminate use of violence, it is helpful to turn to case studies. First,
however, it will be useful to integrate these quantitative findings into
a framework for understanding different types of counterinsurgent
regimes and the strategies they are likely to adopt.
Conflict Termination
Table 3.2 shows the relationship between different types of counter-
insurgent regimes and the outcomes of the counterinsurgency cam-
paigns they conduct.32 As described above, acceptable outcomes are
those in which the government either wins an outright military victory
or is able to achieve a formal negotiated solution to the conflict in the
31 Experimental methods provide the strongest identification strategies, but they are diffi-
cult to devise in such circumstances, and they provide results that are highly context-specific.
32 Cases in which conflicts had not terminated as of 2010 were not included in this table.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 53
Table 3.2
Counterinsurgent Regimes and Conflict Outcomes
%
Without
Accept-
able % of
Political State No Acceptable Out- All
Inclusivity Capacity Acceptable Outcome Outcome comes Cases
High High Croatia (1992–1995), El Russia (1994–1996) 13 13
Salvador (1979–1992),
Israel (1987–1997), Peru
(1980–1996), Philippines
(1972–1992), Turkey
(1984–1999), UK (1971–
1998)
High Low CAR (1996–1997), India Guinea Bissau (1998– 50 14
(1984–1993), Indonesia 1999), Nepal (1996),
(1999–2005), Mali Papua New Guinea
(1990–1995), Sri Lanka (1988–1998), Senegal
(2003–2009) (1989–1999), Sri Lanka
(1983–2002)
Low High Bosnia (1992–1995), Azerbaijan (1991– 50 17
Congo-Brazzaville 1994), Congo-
(1998–1999), Djibouti Brazzaville (1993–
(1991–1994), Morocco 1997), Georgia (1991–
(1975–1991), Nicaragua 1992), Georgia (1992–
(1981–1990), Russia 1994), Moldova (1991–
(1999–2007), South Africa 1992), Yugoslavia
(1976–1994) (1991), Yugoslavia
(1998–1999)
Low Low Angola (1997–2002), Afghanistan (1978– 60 56
Bangladesh (1974–1997), 1992), Afghanistan
Cambodia (1979–1991), (1992–1996), Afghani-
Egypt (1994–1997), stan (1996–2001),
Guatemala (1978–1994), Angola (1975–1991),
Indonesia (1990–1991), Angola (1992–1994),
Iraq (1991–1993), Chad (1980–1994),
Lebanon (1975–1999), Chad (1994–1997),
Mozambique (1976– Congo-Kinshasa
1992), Myanmar (1960– (DRC) (1996–1997),
1995), Nepal (2000– Ethiopia (1974–1991),
2006), Rwanda (1990– Ethiopia (1978–1991),
1993), Rwanda (1994), Haiti (1991–1995),
Sierra Leone (1998–2001), Indonesia (1975–1999),
Tajikistan (1992–1997), Iraq (1985–1996),
Yemen (1994) Kenya (1991–1993),
Liberia (1989–1990),
Liberia (1992–1997),
Liberia (1999–2003),
Pakistan (1994–1999),
Sierra Leone (1991–
1996), Sierra Leone
(1997–1998), Somalia
(1988–1991), Somalia
(1991–2002), Sudan
(1983–2005), Uganda
(1990–1992)
54 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
33 At the time of writing, between 8,000 and 12,000 foreign troops are anticipated to ini-
tially be in post-2014 Afghanistan. That number is expected to decline in subsequent years to
levels closer to those of Operation Enduring Freedom–Philippines (OEF-P) and similar mis-
sions, and even the initial number is still a small fraction of the 20:1,000 force-to-population
ratio specified in FM 3-24 and similar documents.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 55
and state capacity.34 The United States should therefore not expect that
its successes in OEF-P and similar operations will necessarily be repli-
cated elsewhere; indeed, the odds are often against such interventions
leading to a decisive outcome.
Of course, just because more than half of all insurgencies occur in
countries governed by the least-favorable type of regime, this does not
mean that more than half of all U.S. military interventions are likely
to occur in such countries. Indeed, the historical record suggests that
a disproportionate share of U.S. military interventions—somewhere in
the vicinity of half—occur in best-case environments.35 This propen-
sity might be explained by the fact that the odds of success are higher
in such countries, or the fact that the United States shares many values
and interests with such states. It is sobering, however, to consider the
number of least-favorable environments in which the United States has
already intervened and the levels of success it has experienced. Roughly
the other half of U.S. interventions have been in these worst-case envi-
ronments, and the outcomes in countries such as Afghanistan, Iraq,
Lebanon, Somalia, and Yemen are hardly promising.
Figure 3.11 presents these differences in conflict outcomes graphi-
cally, breaking them into each of the four categories used for this analy-
sis: government victory, military stalemate followed by a formally
negotiated settlement, military stalemate without a formally negotiated
settlement, and insurgent victory. As shown, high-capacity regimes his-
torically do not experience indeterminate outcomes—that is, military
stalemates unresolved by a formal settlement acceptable to all of the
major warring parties. More-inclusive regimes are much more capable
of achieving negotiated solutions to conflicts, thereby decreasing their
risk of outright defeat.36
34 The proportion of cases in each type of country was calculated from the entire sample of
insurgencies that have taken place in the post–Cold War era, whereas the proportion of cases
ending in an acceptable outcome was calculated using only those cases in which the insur-
gency had actually ended by our data cutoff date.
35 For a list of U.S. interventions, see Watts et al., 2012. The precise proportion of interven-
tions in each type of country depends on the time period examined and the exact definition
of intervention being used.
36 Figure 3.11 includes all cases of wars that have terminated in the post-conflict era. If we
drop from our sample cases in which large-scale external military interventions occurred in
56 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Figure 3.11
Conflict Outcomes by Regime Type
100
80 Insurgent victory
Outcome (percentage)
Military stalemate,
60 no settlement
Military stalemate,
40 settlement
Government
victory
20
0
Low High Low High
inclusiveness inclusiveness inclusiveness inclusiveness
Low-capacity High-capacity
government government
RAND RR513-3.11
either the conflict or the post-conflict periods, the relationship between political inclusion
and negotiated settlements becomes considerably stronger.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 57
Figure 3.12
Durable Peace by Regime Type
100
Durable peace (percentage)
80
Resumption of
conflict within
60 five years
Durable peace, no
resumption of
40 conflict within
five years
20
0
Low High Low High
inclusiveness inclusiveness inclusiveness inclusiveness
Low-capacity High-capacity
government government
RAND RR513-3.12
terms, they are also less likely to use violence discriminately.37 In only
two insurgencies—less than 9 percent of the total—did relatively more
politically inclusive regimes engage in the mass killings of civilians, and
both of those regimes were only marginally democratic. In contrast,
there were 24 cases of mass killings among less politically inclusive
regimes, with the worst type of counterinsurgent regimes (those exhib-
iting low inclusion and low state capacity) resorting to mass killings 39
percent of the time. The worst type of counterinsurgents (shown in the
bottom row of Table 3.3) were more than four times as likely to use
violence indiscriminately than more-inclusive regimes such as Colom-
bia and the Philippines in recent years, and they comprise well over
half of all regimes fighting insurgencies.
37 As in Table 3.1, military superiority is not shown as a variable in Table 3.2 because of the
ambiguous quantitative findings on the relationship between military capacity and mass
killings of civilians.
58 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 3.3
Counterinsurgent Regimes and Mass Killings
Regime
Characteristics Cases
38 See Gary King, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba, Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific
Inference in Qualitative Research, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994.
39 In the post–Cold War period, the Philippines have an average Freedom House score
of 2.9 (approximately two points away from complete democracy), while Pakistan has an
average score of 4.9 (two points higher than the Philippines and approximately two points
lower than complete autocracy along Freedom House’s scale from 1 to 7). The Philippines’
Freedom House ratings during both of its insurgencies are among the 19 highest-rated (most
democratic) of the 89 cases of insurgency in the post–Cold War era, while Pakistan’s ratings
from its insurgencies are both within the top 49. The Philippines’ government-effectiveness
rating places it among the top 25 cases, while Pakistan’s rating places it among the top 47.
Similarly, the Philippines’ state-reach score ranks it among the top 14 cases, while Pakistan’s
is among the top 39. Taken together, these statistics suggest that the Philippines typically
has ranked in the quartile of cases with the most-favorable characteristics (and often much
higher), whereas Pakistan has ranked roughly in the middle of all cases. Complete data are
available from the authors upon request.
60 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
40 All values and definitions were taken from The World Bank’s WDI, using post–Cold War
data.
41 Again, figures and definitions are from the WDI dataset.
42 Figures are from the Peace Research Institute Oslo (PRIO) Battle Deaths Dataset, Ver-
sion 3.0. Information on the composition of this dataset is available in Bethany Lacina and
Nils Petter Gleditsch, “Monitoring Trends in Global Combat: A New Dataset of Battle
Deaths,” European Journal of Population, Vol. 21, Nos. 2–3, 2005, pp. 145–166.
Quantitative Analysis of Counterinsurgency 61
Introduction
63
64 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Background
Overview of the Counterinsurgency and Counterterrorism
Environment
For most of its post-independence history, the Philippines has been a
democracy, albeit a fragile one characterized by political patronage and
coalitions dominated by relatively narrow, parochial interests. Wide-
spread poverty has hamstrung human development, and armed con-
flict has persisted since before the country’s independence in 1946. Of
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 65
Historical Background
Conflict has played a persistent role in the Philippine Islands for cen-
turies. Dating at least to the beginning of the Philippines’ encoun-
ter with Spain in 1521, irregular warfare has endured in the southern
and other parts of the archipelago. After the United States took con-
trol of the Philippines in 1898, a nationalist resistance that had been
active against Spain continued to violently resist U.S. rule. Following
a bloody counterinsurgency campaign, the United States emerged vic-
torious in 1902, but despite tamping down the Philippine nationalist
resistance, it never fully quelled resistance throughout its new territo-
rial holding; violent resistance from the Muslim Moro population in
the southern Philippines was especially persistent.
In 1935, the Philippines was granted self-governing common-
wealth status, with a plan put in place to transition the country to
full independence in 1945. In the meantime, the Philippines became a
key World War II location in the Pacific theater. In 1942, Japan occu-
pied the islands, controlling the country until the United States, along
with Filipino resistance forces, began to reclaim control in 1944 and
regained control in 1945. Following Japan’s surrender, the Republic of
the Philippines attained independence in July 1946. A democratic gov-
ernment was elected to coincide with national independence. Manuel
Roxas was elected the country’s first president in 1946. Foreshadow-
ing later periods on which we focus, the post-independence govern-
ment was almost immediately threatened by armed insurgencies. Most
threatening was the Hukbalahap, or “Huk,” a communist insurgency
that began a rebellion against the Roxas government in 1946 and was
not defeated until 1954.5
The United States played a significant role in the Philippines fol-
lowing the country’s independence. This role was not confined to help-
ing the Government of the Republic of the Philippines (GRP) coun-
ter the Huk insurgency. The GRP, under President Roxas, passed a
5 Harvey Averch and John Koehler, The Huk Rebellion in the Philippines: Quantita-
tive Approaches, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, RM-6254, 1970; Benedict J.
Kerkvliet, The Huk Rebellion: A Study of Peasant Revolt in the Philippines, Lanham, Md.:
Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2002.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 67
Military Bases Agreement in 1947 that gave the United States the
right to establish military bases and other installations, which in turn
meant that U.S. troops and materiel would have access to the Philip-
pines. The GRP-U.S. Mutual Defense Agreement (MDA) followed in
1952 to guide the overall direction for U.S.-GRP security coopera-
tion, including U.S. support to the Philippine government to counter
internal threats such as insurgencies.6 The MDA remained in place
after Philippine president Ferdinand Marcos—a close Cold War ally
of the United States—declared martial law in 1972, and it remained
an important mechanism for funneling U.S. aid to the regime until
Marcos was deposed in 1986. Following Marcos’ deposition, the Phil-
ippines transitioned to democracy. However, U.S.-GRP relations were
fragile, and when the U.S.-GRP basing agreement expired in 1991, the
Philippine Congress voted for the closure of Clark Air Base and Subic
Naval Base—two of the largest American military bases outside the
continental United States. Following the closure of the bases, U.S.-
Philippine security cooperation diminished dramatically before a Vis-
iting Forces Agreement between the two countries was signed in May
1999. This agreement provided the domestic legal basis that facilitated
the GRP’s enhanced security cooperation with the United States in the
2000s.
6 Sharon Advincula Caringal, “The Impact of U.S. Military Assistance on the Communist
and Secessionist Conundrum in the Philippines,” International Journal of Arts and Sciences,
Vol. 3, No. 15, 2010, p. 437. Illustrating the rupture in U.S.-GRP relations marked by the
closure of Clark and Subic, the U.S. Ambassador to the Philippines at the time, Richard
Solomon, recalled that “dealing with the base closures was practically the only thing I did as
Ambassador” (interview with Richard Solomon, Arlington, Va., June 2013).
68 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
sides agreed to hold further talks, NPA violence continued, and dis-
agreements in early November 2011 led to the peace talks being post-
poned. The NPA insurgency continued apace into 2012.
As of 2012, the NPA asserted that it had an active presence in 70
of the Philippines’ 81 provinces, yet its presence appears to be thin:
A 2007 Armed Forces of the Philippines (AFP) estimate claimed the
NPA was highly active in only 2,121 of the Philippines’ 42,000 baran-
gays, the country’s village-level administrative divisions. In February
2010, the AFP claimed that NPA influence had been further eroded,
with the group controlling only 1,077 barangays.7 Still, the government
considers the NPA its most serious threat, and indeed, the group is
responsible for considerably more attacks annually than the MILF and
the ASG combined.
cal entity in Mindanao. The future of the peace process was called
into question in October, following the MILF’s involvement in a clash
between the military and the ASG that left 19 soldiers dead.
Currently, the MILF is one of the most powerful militant groups
in Southeast Asia. It commands approximately 10,000 armed fighters
and has well-established bases from which it exerts political control
over local Muslim communities. Its principal areas of activity include
the southern provinces of Lanao del Norte, Lanao del Sur, Maguin-
danao, and North Cotabato.8 The group has extensive grassroots sup-
port, which means that the reservoir of potential fighters remains very
large. Not everyone joins exclusively for religious or ethnic purposes;
some join because of the poor economic conditions in Mindanao and a
lack of other opportunities. Senior military officials have estimated that
the MILF could easily mobilize an additional 8,000 to 10,000 fight-
ers within a short period of time. In recent years, however, the group’s
influence and threat to the GRP have declined somewhat. This decline
is in part due to government operations and the resulting deterioration
of the MILF’s conventional fighting strength, but it can also be linked
to the death of radical leader Salamat Hashim in 2003 and his replace-
ment by the more-moderate Ebrahim el-Haj Murad, who is more will-
ing to accept a negotiated settlement on expanded autonomy.9
terrorism efforts after the 9/11 terrorist attacks in the United States.
Indeed, a series of joint U.S.-Philippine military and political actions
have substantially degraded the ASG’s capabilities.
Although the ASG’s top leadership hierarchy has remained
unclear since Khadafy Janjalani was killed in 2006, numerous other
ASG commanders and subcommanders were subsequently killed
or captured, including ASG spokesman Jainal Antel Sali, alias Abu
Solaiman; Ismin Sahiron, the son of a top ASG commander; and other
key operatives, including Jundam Jamalul and Borhan Mundus. The
AFP claimed that 144 ASG rebels were killed, were captured, or sur-
rendered in 2007, bringing the total number of ASG rebels to fewer
than 400 (from a peak of between 1,000 and 1,200) for the first time
in years.
The ASG has nonetheless demonstrated that it can still inflict
significant casualties. In July 2007, ASG and MILF forces ambushed a
group of AFP Marines searching for a kidnapped Italian priest on Basi-
lan. Fourteen of the Marines were killed, ten of whom were beheaded.
In August 2007, the ASG conducted an attack that killed 15 AFP
Marines in Basilan province.10 For the foreseeable future, the group’s
propensity for kidnap-for-ransom operations ensures that it will pose a
threat to civilians, particularly foreign nationals. 11 At the same time, it
appears that the ASG is unlikely to pose more than a low-level threat to
Philippine and U.S. security forces in the south.
10 Jane’s World Insurgency and Terrorism, “Abu Sayyaf Group,” June 7, 2013, p. 7.
11 Fund-raising through criminality appears to have enabled the group to replenish its
depleted ranks by offering competitive wages to recruits, many of whom do not share the
previous generation’s Salafi jihadist ideology. Rommel C. Banlaoi, “The Sources of the Abu
Sayyaf ’s Resilience in the Southern Philippines,” CTC Sentinel, Vol. 3, No. 5, May 2010,
pp. 17–19.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 73
12The commands are Northern Luzon, Southern Luzon, Visayas, Western, East Mindanao,
West Mindanao, and National Capital.
13 Stuart Farris, Joint Special Operations Task Force–Philippines, School of Advanced Mili-
tary Studies, Fort Leavenworth, Kans.: U.S. Army Command and General Staff College,
2009, pp. 22–23.
74 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
14 Raymond Bonner, Waltzing with a Dictator: The Marcoses and the Making of Foreign
Policy, New York: New York Times Books, 1987, pp. 204–225; William E. Kline, The Fall of
Marcos: A Problem in U.S. Foreign Policymaking, Washington, D.C.: Institute for the Study
of Diplomacy, Georgetown University School of Foreign Service, 1992, pp. 18–19.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 75
15 Joel Rocamora, “Discontent in the Philippines,” World Policy Journal, Vol. 8, No. 4, Fall
1991, pp. 636–637.
16 Richard J. Kessler, “Marcos and the Americans,” Foreign Policy, Vol. 63, 1986, pp. 40–57.
17 Bonner, 1987, pp. 204–225; Kline, 1992, pp. 18–19.
18 Walden Bello, “Edging Toward the Quagmire: The United States and the Philippine
Crisis,” World Policy Journal, Vol. 3, No. 1, Winter 1985–1986, p. 31.
76 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
19 Interview with former U.S. Ambassador to the Philippines, Arlington, Va., June 2013.
This outcome is consistent with broader trends observed in Ely Ratner, “Reaping What You
Sow: Democratic Transitions and Foreign Policy Realignment,” Journal of Conflict Resolu-
tion, Vol. 53, No. 3, June 2009, pp. 390–418.
20 Interview with former commander, AFP Special Operations Command, Manila, Philip-
pines, June 2013.
21Maria Ressa, Seeds of Terror: An Eyewitness Account of Al-Qaeda’s Newest Center of
Operations in Southeast Asia, New York: Simon and Schuster, 2004.
22 Thomas Lum, The Republic of the Philippines and U.S. Interests, Washington, D.C.: Con-
gressional Research Service, Library of Congress, April 2012, p. 14.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 77
times higher than the U.S. aid received by any other southeast Asian
country.23
The United States intervened to support counterterrorism in the
Philippines as part of OEF-P. Akin to traditional foreign-internal-
defense strategies, the U.S. strategy in the Philippines later became
known as “the indirect approach.”24 Compared with U.S. operations
in other theaters, the operational method in OEF-P could aptly be
described as “indirect,” because of its relatively light footprint (approx-
imately 500–750 U.S. personnel operating under the Joint Special
Operations Task Force–Philippines [JSOTF-P]) and its focus on oper-
ating through indigenous security forces.
23 Lum, 2012.
24 Carolyn H. Briscoe, “Balikatan Exercise Spearheaded ARSOF Operations in the Philip-
pines,” Special Warfare, Vol. 17, No. 1, September 2004, p. 16.
78 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 4.1
Regime and Campaign Features of Philippine Counterinsurgency,
1972–2013
Discrimi-
State Political Accom- Public nate
Group Capacity Inclusion modate Goods Violence Strategy
state capacity in the four decades covered in this study. These improve-
ments, however, did not occur uniformly across the country. Typically,
the core regions closer to Manila enjoyed substantially higher access
to public goods than did the more peripheral regions of Mindanao
and especially the Sulu Archipelago. As a result, the government was
better able to employ strong-state counterinsurgency practices against
the NPA, which operated in both the core regions and the periphery,
than it was against the insurgencies that operated in the predominantly
Muslim peripheral regions—the MNLF, the MILF, and the ASG.
The GRP counterinsurgency practices shown in Table 4.1 are
divided into three broadly defined time periods. The first time period
begins with the imposition of martial law by President Marcos from
1972 to 1981 and runs through the end of Marcos’ presidency in 1986.
During this period, political inclusivity was low, as the imposition
of martial law made Marcos a de facto dictator until he was forced
from power. His investment in coercive capabilities to crush the NPA
is consistent with strong-state repression, even though Philippine gov-
ernment capacity could be considered only moderate in Manila and
some of the areas where the NPA operated. The GRP’s capacity was
even lower in the Muslim south, where the MNLF and the MILF
had established parallel state structures amid largely sympathetic co-
ethnic populations, and the broad government strategy employed
against these groups was consistent with containment.
The second time period, roughly spanning 1986 to 2000, can be
viewed broadly as a transitional period. During this period, the coun-
try transitioned toward democracy. Policies and operational methods
changed, but the government’s capacity to implement reforms was
limited. The limitations stemmed in part from the civilian govern-
ment’s weakness relative to the military, whose most senior officers
from the Marcos period retained much of the political clout Marcos
had conferred on them. Their disagreement with the civilian govern-
ment’s policy preferences and the military’s reliance on old tactics from
the Marcos period, which often involved conventional operations in
which force was applied indiscriminately, played a key role in shap-
ing the ultimate approach that was taken in countering insurgencies.
In this period, the democratically elected regime made attempts to
80 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
forge a peace agreement with each major insurgent group. But only
one such effort—the 1996 peace deal with the MNLF—succeeded.
Despite the increased level of political inclusiveness, the government’s
lack of capacity relative to the military often resulted in counterinsur-
gency approaches that most closely resembled containment. Such an
approach was evident, for instance, after peace talks with the NPA and
the MILF repeatedly broke down and intermittent large-scale military
operations resumed. The government also was left to pursue a contain-
ment strategy against the ASG, which was never interested in a nego-
tiated peace and was thus alternately ignored and dealt with through
military operations that in many cases relied on the use of indiscrimi-
nate firepower.
The third broad period began in 2001 after Gloria Macapagal-
Arroyo succeeded Joseph Estrada as President and significantly
expanded the country’s relationship with the United States in the wake
of the 9/11 attacks. U.S. assistance, both military and civil, increased
dramatically during this period. Although the dramatic expansion in
U.S. aid was inadequate to boost state capacity throughout the coun-
try in such a short period of time, it made a dramatic difference in
the government’s capabilities in the small peripheral region of the Sulu
Archipelago, where joint operations by the U.S. military and its Phil-
ippine partners gave the government an unprecedented reach. Demo-
cratic institutions were also increasingly consolidated in this period:
Despite allegations of electoral graft in 2004 and 2010, a return to
military rule appears increasingly unlikely. The government’s approach
to counterinsurgency has followed relatively predictable patterns:
Against the NPA, it undertook the closest approximation of the classic
counterinsurgency model that it had taken to date. Against the MILF,
it engaged in an ongoing peace process and worked to restrain the
military from conducting operations that could compromise the pro-
cess, an approach consistent with the informal-accommodation model
described in Chapter Two. And against the ASG, it has worked with
U.S. partners to combine civil-military operations with discriminate
targeting of ASG members—an approach that again approximates the
classic counterinsurgency model.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 81
Although the GRP’s policies over these four decades do not per-
fectly align with the behavior that we might expect based on the frame-
work presented in Chapter Two, the extent of congruence is remark-
able. In only two of the ten subcases depicted in Table 4.1 do GRP
policies clearly diverge from the behavior predicted by the framework:
the government’s approach to the MILF from 1986 to 2000 and its
approach to the ASG from 1991 to 2000. In both cases, the fledgling
democratic regime implemented containment strategies more com-
monly used by weak autocratic regimes. As discussed in more detail
below, these divergences from the behavior more typical of demo-
cratic regimes can be understood in terms of the country’s transition
to democracy. In the early years after the end of the Marcos regime,
democratic administrations were preoccupied with the critical tasks of
the transition. They did not have the necessary high-level engagement
or political capital to confront a military shaped by the Marcos era over
a conflict in a peripheral region. As the new regime consolidated its
authority, however, it was increasingly able to rely on more accommo-
dative approaches to moderate insurgents. Where the regime had the
necessary resources—specifically, against the insurgency that threat-
ened core territories (the NPA) and where the United States provided
extensive assistance focused on a relatively small peripheral region (the
campaign against the ASG)—it adopted the classical counterinsur-
gency policies common to higher-capacity, more politically inclusive
regimes.
These variations are explored in greater detail below.
25 These numbers come from the Correlates of War Project’s National Material Capabilities
Database (version 4.0). For more background on the database, see J. David Singer,
“Reconstructing the Correlates of War Dataset on Material Capabilities of States, 1816–
1985,” International Interactions, Vol. 14, 1987, pp. 115–132.
26 For a detailed overview of the NPA’s evolution, see Paz Verdades M. Santos, “The Com-
munist Front: Protracted People’s War and Counterinsurgency in the Philippines (Over-
view),” in Soliman M. Santos, Jr., and Paz Verdades M. Santos, eds., Primed and Purposeful:
Armed Groups and Human Security Efforts in the Philippines, Geneva: Small Arms Survey,
2005, pp. 17–32.
27 Eva-Lotta E. Hedman, The Philippines: Conflict and Internal Displacement in Mindanao
and the Sulu Archipelago, Writenet Report commissioned by the United Nations High Com-
missioner for Refugees, Emergency and Technical Support Service, March 2009, pp. 2–5.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 83
missions and their coordination with the AFP were limited. Multiple
sources suggest that the AFP was holding up largely on its own against
the NPA. In practice, the unsuccessful implementation of a whole-
of-government approach exacerbated the already strained relations
between the Aquino government and its civilian agencies and the AFP,
over which Aquino had only tenuous control.34
The civilians in Aquino’s government were poorly coordinated
and could not reach consensus on the appropriate measures to take
against insurgents. Many in the Congress viewed the insurgencies as
purely local phenomena, while others viewed them as a task for the
military. Either way, support for Aquino’s desired strategy was limited,
and implementation was often difficult.
With nowhere else to turn, Aquino, under intense pressure from
the military and with promises of increased U.S. support, reversed
course and launched a total-war policy against the NPA. Interestingly,
however, although the NPA sought to take advantage of the uptick in
AFP abuses, it was less able to do so under the democratically elected
Aquino than it had been under Marcos’ martial law, with support
less forthcoming from moderate elements of the population, perhaps
because the democratic system afforded possible opportunities for
reforms that would simply never happen if the NPA were to win.35
Negotiations between the Aquino government and the MNLF
led to the creation of the ARMM on August 1, 1989. This agreement
was hardly comprehensive, however: Of the 13 southern provinces and
nine cities that participated in the referendum held on the basis of the
Tripoli Accords, only four—Lanao del Sur, Maguindanao, Sulu, and
Tawi-Tawi—opted to be part of the ARMM. Marcos’ legacy haunted
the prospects for fuller implementation, as one of the reasons for the
failure of the referendum to garner a majority vote was Marcos’ encour-
34 Interview with GRP official, Quezon City, Philippines, June 2013; interview with AFP
officer, Makati, Philippines, June 2013; Devesa, 2005, p. 36.
35Dominique Caouette, Persevering Revolutionaries: Armed Struggle in the 21st Century,
Exploring the Revolution of the Communist Party of the Philippines, dissertation, Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University, 2004, pp. 483, 488.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 87
36 The NPA did not receive significant assistance from external sources during the Cold
War, with the exception of support from China from 1969 to 1976. The group’s strength, and
its entry into negotiations, varied more with changes in the regime it faced. “New People’s
Army,” START Terrorist Organization Profiles database, University of Maryland, College
Park, Md., undated.
37 One unanticipated byproduct of democratization and attempts at reconciliation—
imperfect as they were—was that they triggered NPA fractionalization, pitting hard-
line “reaffirmationists” against “rejectionists,” who opposed continuing the protracted
war strategy. The bickering between the two factions escalated until a series of bloody
internal purges of suspected traitors had riven the NPA, nearly leading to its col-
lapse. See International Crisis Group, The Communist Insurgency in the Philippines: Tac-
tics and Talks, Crisis Group Asia Report No. 202, Islamabad/Brussels, February 2011,
pp. 5–6.
88 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
who had lost favor with key elements of the AFP, Ramos had an acute
understanding of the importance of both addressing root causes of the
insurgencies and reconciling with the military. His policy objectives
reflected these priorities. Ramos repealed R.A. No. 1700, also known
as the Anti-Subversion Law, to open the door for former subversive
organizations to pursue political and social goals through political
means rather than armed struggle. To accommodate individual dis-
sidents, the Balik-Baril program was created; it reintegrated rebels who
surrendered their weapons to government authorities in exchange for
an up-front cash payment and additional payments to be made in sub-
sequent months that would enable all those who surrendered to take
up a livelihood program of their choosing. With regard to the mili-
tary, Ramos sought to accommodate the coup plotters of the 1980s by
granting them unconditional amnesty.
Overall, Ramos’ conciliatory policies held promise for addressing
the country’s insurgencies. For example, during his tenure, the number
of communist-influenced villages declined to its lowest point.38 The
reduction was sufficient, in fact, that the AFP’s role in combating insur-
gency was scaled back and eventually transferred, in 1996, to the Phil-
ippine National Police, along with the Department of the Interior and
Local Government and local government units (LGUs). These agen-
cies remained poorly coordinated, underresourced, and lacking in the
training and doctrine for counterinsurgency that the AFP had enjoyed.
In subsequent years, the GRP lost ground in its efforts against multiple
insurgent groups, including the NPA, and in particular, the MILF.
Ramos’ attempt to enact a whole-of-government approach to counter-
insurgency never fully gained the population’s confidence. Despite the
democratic handover from Aquino, the Ramos government’s bureau-
cracy was perceived by many as weak, uncommitted to reform, un-
coordinated, corrupt, and financially strained, all of which limited its
capacity to deliver on the promises of Lambat Bitag.39 Although the
communist insurgency reached the lowest point of its history during
the Ramos administration, the MILF and the ASG began to rise up
38 Devesa, 2005, p. 5.
39 Pena, 2007, pp. 59–61.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 89
again during the latter part of his term, as shown in Figure 4.1, in large
part because of the government’s failure to execute and sustain the con-
solidate and develop stages of the Lambat Bitag campaign strategy.40
Ultimately, the insurgents discovered many of the same opportunities
they exploited during the Aquino administration, playing on the peo-
ple’s grievances to increase their dissatisfaction with the government.41
This episode illustrates that the preferred policies of democratic regimes
can be undermined by inadequate capability to implement them—
a subject that will be further explored in the discussion of state capacity.
Ramos’ successor, Joseph Estrada, returned responsibility for
internal security operations to the AFP in 1998. After some initial
skirmishes, the military and the insurgent groups both escalated
Figure 4.1
Insurgent-Group Strength by Administration
25,000
20,000
Group strength
CPP-NPA
15,000 MILF
10,000
5,000
ASG
0
1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
42 These reasons include severe NPA fragmentation and internal disagreement over the
group’s objectives; economic rents NPA leaders were able to capture via “revolutionary taxes”
and front companies; and the GRP’s decision to make the NPA peace process a secondary
priority to the MILF process. International Crisis Group, 2011, pp. 7–9.
43 Zachary Abuza, Balik-Terrorism: The Return of the Abu Sayyaf, Carlisle, Pa.: Strategic
Studies Institute, September 2005, pp. 41–42.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 91
Military Superiority
A second explanatory factor associated with Philippine counterinsur-
gency strategy and outcomes is military superiority, which reflects the
balance—or imbalance—between government armed forces and the
size and capabilities of the insurgents and terrorists. Change over time
to the military balance can shape strategy and indeed did shape GRP
strategy. Contrary to the hypothesis that governments tend to be more
discriminating in their use of force when they enjoy significant military
superiority, however, the Philippines experience suggests that quantita-
tively superior government forces might use either high or low levels of
indiscriminate violence. The nature of the regime and the quality of
the counterinsurgency forces it deploys account better for the variation
over time in the Philippines.
The history of Philippines counterinsurgency since Marcos’
ouster maps onto this framework relatively well. Under Marcos, the
country was under de facto authoritarian rule for 14 years. Marcos’
military was significantly larger than the rebel forces he faced, particu-
larly after he invested hundreds of millions of dollars in the expansion
of the both the AFP and pro-government paramilitary forces to fight
armed dissident movements. Consistent with our framework, Marcos’
authoritarian regime did not bargain in good faith; rather, it know-
ingly implemented policies that would undermine the Moro Muslims’
demographic majority status in Mindanao and thus reduce the chances
that an agreed-upon referendum would force the concessions sought by
the MNLF. Moreover, the Marcos regime’s use of force became more
and more indiscriminate as the military’s relative dominance eroded
due to booms in rebel recruitment, particularly by the NPA from the
late 1970s through the first half of the 1980s.
Figure 4.2
Time Trend in PSF and NPA Numeric Strength and Force Ratio, 1978–2006
160
PSF (thousands)
140
120
100
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
NPA (thousands)
25
20
15
10
5
0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
60
PSF:NPA
40
20
0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
44 These statistics come from the Correlates of War project’s National Material Capabilities
database (version 4.0). For more on the National Material Capabilities data, see Singer, 1987,
pp. 115–132.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 93
Figure 4.3
ASG Estimated Strength, 1993–2003
1,400
1,270
1,200 1,150
1,030
1,100
Estimated strength
1,000
890
800
800
650
600
580 480
400 460
200
120
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
SOURCE: Office of the Deputy Chief for Intelligence, J2, Armed Forces of the
Philippines, 2004.
RAND RR513-4.3
45 Correlates of War Project’s National Material Capabilities database (version 4.0). See
Singer, 1987.
46 See, e.g., William Chapman, Inside the Philippine Revolution: The New People’s Army
and Its Struggle for Power, 1st ed., New York: W. W. Norton, 1987; Gregg R. Jones, Red
Revolution: Inside the Philippine Guerrilla Movement, Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989;
Soliman Santos, “Evolution of the Armed Conflict on the Communist Front,” in Phil-
ippine Human Development Report 2005: Peace, Human Security and Human Develop-
ment in the Philippines, 2nd ed., Quezon City, Human Development Network, 2005,
pp. 84–89.
94 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
best recruiter.47 For the period for which systematic estimates of NPA
strength are available, 1978–2006, the most striking period of growth
in NPA strength was during the Marcos era: During the period of
the most significant PSF growth in the Marcos era for which data are
available, 1978–1982, the estimated number of NPA members nearly
tripled, increasing from 2,760 to 7,750.48 Estimated NPA membership
increased to approximately 10,660 in 1983; 14,360 in 1984; 22,500
in 1985; and 24,430 in 1986.49 According to these data, the ratio of
PSF to NPA personnel was highest in the late 1970s and early 1980s
but declined steadily during this period and continued to decline until
1987.
Unclassified AFP annual estimates of ASG strength are shown
in Figure 4.3 for 1993 to 2003.50 These estimates confirm the conven-
tional wisdom that the ASG is the smallest of the three major Phil-
ippine threat groups. AFP intelligence suggests the group had only
120 members in 1993. This number increased steadily throughout
the 1990s and peaked at 1,270 in 2000, before beginning to steadily
decline in 2001 and 2002. The timing of the ASG’s decline coincides
with the deployment of U.S. SOF to the southern Philippines, first to
assist in establishing the Philippines’ premier counterterrorism unit,
the Light Reaction Company, in 2000, and then as Joint Task Force
510 (JTF-510) and then as JSOTF-P from 2002 on.51
47 Jones, 1989, p. 7.
48 Santos, 2005, p. 24.
49 Esperon, 2006, p. 5.
50 These were the only years for which unclassified annual estimates of ASG strength were
available. See Office of the Deputy Chief for Intelligence, J2, Armed Forces of the Philip-
pines, 2004, Annex IA. Quoted in Romulo C. Supapo, U.S.-Philippine Security Relations: Its
Implications for the Global War on Terrorism, Carlisle, Pa.: U.S. Army War College, March
2004, pp. 7–8.
51 Lambert, Lewis, and Sewall, 2012, pp. 120–121.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 95
52 Joseph H. Felter, Taking Guns to a Knife Fight: Effective Military Support to COIN, Car-
lisle, Pa.: U.S. Army War College, 2008, pp. 9–10.
96 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 4.2
AFP Unit Type and Conflict Deaths per Reported Incident, 2001–2007
ing in the Marcos era, it might have fed a very different operational
strategy—one that proved counterproductive during that era.
especially the ASG in the southern Philippines, along with the geo-
graphical constraints imposed by the islands where they operate, can
help government forces find insurgent camps and limits insurgents’
freedom of movement to elude apprehension when the military or
police are able to conduct timely operations. At the same time, parallel,
state-like structures built by the MNLF and the MILF make parts of
the southern Philippines akin to denied or hostile areas, in which the
AFP’s operational latitude is limited. Conversely, the more-dispersed
nature of the NPA has allowed it to better withstand strong govern-
ment offensives, although it has also made it more difficult for the
group to firmly establish its primacy.
The GRP’s limited capacity must be understood in comparative
perspective. Relative to all regimes battling insurgencies, which tend to
have very low governance and overall state capacity,54 the Philippines
has a reasonably competent governmental infrastructure that can pro-
vide some degree of public goods even in remote rural areas. Compared
with most of the countries of sub-Saharan Africa and many of the
poorer countries of Asia, it scores considerably better on both indices of
state capacity used in this study.55 The fact that it continues to struggle
to implement government policies, especially in the remote regions of
the country, is evidence of the challenges the classic counterinsurgency
model faces in most conflict-affected countries of the developing world.
Figure 4.4
Development Projects, Insurgent-Affected Barangays, and Guerrilla Fronts
Impact of DSO
(2001–2010)
3,000
Affected barangays
2,490 2,510
2,250 2,394
2,178 2,121
1,996 2,072 Projects
Number
1,500
1,381 1,077 1,123
Recipient barangays
750
0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
55 Guerilla fronts 62 52
51
28
0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
58Kathline Anne Sigua Tolosa, “The Rhetoric and Practice of the Security-Development
Nexus,” OSS Digest, 1st Quarter, 2010, pp. 32–33.
59 Jonathan P. Hastings and Krishnamurti Mortela, The Strategy-Legitimacy Paradigm: Get-
ting It Right in the Philippines, master’s thesis, Monterey, Calif.: Naval Postgraduate School,
December 2008, pp. 59–72; Ernesto C. Torres, Jr., A Success Story of Philippine Counterin-
surgency: A Study of Bohol, master’s thesis, Fort Leavenworth, Kans.: U.S. Army Command
and General Staff College, November 2010, pp. 8–9, 66–68.
60 Hastings and Mortela, 2008, pp. 68–69.
102 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
The U.S. military has played a significant role in the southern Philip-
pines in OEF-P since 2001, when the U.S.-Philippines security rela-
tionship was reestablished after security cooperation between the two
countries had diminished in the 1990s.
In the post-9/11 period, the Philippines became the Southeast
Asian front line of U.S. counterterrorism efforts in the Global War
on Terrorism. During the 1990s, there was relatively little interest in
the ASG or its links to foreign terrorist groups.62 But after the 9/11
attacks, the recognition that numerous key al Qaeda figures had used
the Philippines for various fund-raising and operational purposes and
that the Philippines served as one of its key potential staging grounds
for expanding al Qaeda’s influence in Southeast Asia, made the Philip-
pines a key interest of U.S. counterterrorism officials.63
U.S. interest in Philippine counterinsurgency, however, was
largely limited to the southern Philippines, and specifically to parts of
Mindanao, such as Basilan, Tawi-Tawi, and Sulu, where the al Qaeda–
linked terrorist network was believed to be most active. The U.S. resur-
gence in the Philippines did not—and was not intended to—address
the main insurgent threat to the GRP, the communist NPA. These
restrictions on U.S. activities have limited the influence of the United
64 Author interview with former JSOTF-P officer, April 14, 2013; author interview with
former U.S. government official, Manila, Philippines, June 24, 2013; author interview with
AFP Lt. Col., Quezon City, Philippines, June 22, 2013; author interview with AFP (Ret.)
Brig. Gen., Makati City, Philippines, June 23, 2013.
65 Thomas M. Scanzillo and Edward M. Lopacienski, “Influence Warfare: How the
Joint Special Operations Task Force–Philippines Maximizes Effects to Create Long-Term
Stability,” Center for the Study of Irregular Warfare and Armed Groups, February 2011.
104 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
the period of martial law and a sporadic one of the fragile democratic
governments of the 1990s—to the use of focused tactics that seek to
minimize harm to the civilian population. This transformation is con-
sidered a key component of the success against militant groups in the
past decade.66
during OEF-P has resulted in dramatic changes not only in the tacti-
cal proficiency and operational capacity of the AFP and other PSF, but
also in the AFP’s role in and level of local engagement.69
As a result of the American presence during OEF-P, Philippine
civil-military engagement was influenced in two important ways. First,
the U.S.-PSF military partnership enabled the AFP to reach local areas
and their primary administrative bodies, LGUs, as well as civilian
populations that previously were beyond the effective control of GRP
national-level mechanisms. This occurred not only through the provi-
sion of logistics support for AFP operations, but also through intel-
ligence support that helped the AFP to conduct timely, intelligence-
driven operations.70 The AFP, with U.S. support, was thus able to
engage in civil-military operations, support development efforts, and
develop a robust messaging strategy intended to influence the popula-
tion favorably toward the GRP. Second, the AFP’s extended reach and
ability to provide basic security functions meant LGUs and private citi-
zens were less likely to rely on local paramilitaries. The mutual reliance
of LGUs and civilian populations, on the one hand, and the AFP and
other GRP agencies, on the other hand, has since 2001 enhanced state
capacity by enabling the GRP to provide better security and other ser-
vices and to conduct tactical military operations in previously denied
areas of Basilan, Sulu, and other locations in the southern Philippines
where ASG and foreign militants operate.71
72 Ressa, 2004.
73 Abuza, 2005, pp. 14–16.
74 For a detailed overview of these scenarios and the risk of U.S.-backed counterterrorist
operations to the peace process, see David S. Maxwell, “Operation Enduring Freedom–
Philippines: What Would Sun Tzu Say?” Military Review, Vol. 84, No. 3, 2004, pp. 20–23;
International Crisis Group, Counterinsurgency vs. Counterterrorism in Mindanao, Asia Report
No. 152, Islamabad/Brussels, pp. 20–26; and Abuza, 2005, p. 15.
Counterinsurgency in the Philippines 107
Conclusions
The Philippines counterinsurgency environment has progressed in a
way that is largely consistent with the framework advanced in this
study. The Marcos regime declared martial law from 1972 to 1983 and
75 Since 2001, U.S. military assistance (the combined amount under the foreign military
financing [FMF], foreign military sales [FMS], international military education and training
[IMET], and excess defense articles), for example, grew from $10.5 million to $42.8 million
in 2007. Hall, 2010, p. 34.
76 Multiple interviews with AFP officers, Tarlac and Makati, Philippines, June 2013; multi-
ple interviews with former JSOTF-P officers, April 2013; interview with former U.S. military
attaché, Makati, Philippines, June 2013.
77 Interview with former JSOTF-P intelligence officer, Arlington, Va., May 2013.
108 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
the post-9/11 period, by which time the GRP had established con-
solidated, if imperfect, democratic institutions. Like other democrati-
cally elected governments that followed Marcos’ regime, the post-2001
Philippines has sought to negotiate an end to conflicts with groups it
considers reconcilable. These efforts have met with only partial suc-
cess: The MILF peace process holds significant promise for an agree-
ment, while NPA negotiations have never developed to the same stage
of maturity and are currently stalled.79
The Philippines has adapted the military side of its counterin-
surgencies toward a greater focus on the population, making progress
in minimizing civilian casualties and the incidence of indiscriminate
violence.80 Oversight and headquarters-level control of certain units in
certain locations remains limited, but U.S. military assistance and advi-
sors have facilitated a more sustained population-centric approach than
ever before by easing resource burdens and sharing operational meth-
ods and techniques for conducting a range of civil-military operations.
By injecting additional resources, oversight, and capabilities, the
U.S. military also appears to have helped to stabilize civil-military
relations—a chronic source of policy instability in the Philippines since
the transition to democracy in 1986. It is entirely possible, however,
that this stability will be fleeting, as there is no institutional mecha-
nism in place to build or sustain the capacity to maintain smoother
civil-military relations in the absence of the combination of qualities
and resources the United States brings to the environment.
Finally, although the United States’ partnership with the GRP
should be considered a success story, claims about that success should
be qualified by questions concerning the long-term sustainability of
the gains that have been made. Philippine capacity to counter insur-
gent and terrorist groups effectively and selectively is unquestionably
greater now than it was during any part of the pre-9/11 period. It is
unclear, however, whether the GRP will be able to deploy and sustain
certain capabilities that have enhanced its capacity and contributed
79International Crisis Group, The Philippines: Dismantling Rebel Groups, Asia Report
No. 248, Islamabad/Brussels, June 19, 2013b, pp. 1–3.
80 Lambert, Lewis, and Sewall, 2012, pp. 122–126.
110 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan
Introduction
1 National Intelligence Council, The Terrorist Threat to the Homeland, National Intelli-
gence Estimate, Washington, D.C., July 2007.
111
112 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
2 Pakistan’s democracy score on the seven-point Freedom House index has improved over
the past five years, but it has still not reached the midpoint.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 113
and state capacity (e.g., the Swat Valley), the government has adopted
approaches resembling classic counterinsurgency strategies. In periph-
eral regions like FATA and Balochistan, in contrast, the state has been
more prone to using force indiscriminately and denying even poten-
tially reconcilable opposition movements the opportunity for mean-
ingful political participation in state structures.
The U.S.-Pakistan security partnership is commonly regarded as
a failure, particularly since the steady decline in relations that began in
2011. Our analysis suggests that a more-nuanced view is appropriate.
The study clearly reveals the limits of U.S. leverage, even in countries to
which it provides large amounts of assistance, but it also reveals specific
circumstances under which the United States might positively engage.
Finally, it suggests the potential for even partners with unfavorable
characteristics to adopt elements of Western counterinsurgency best
practices, at least under certain conditions. To be clear, the story of the
U.S.-Pakistan relationship is not an encouraging one. It does, however,
hint at ways in which the United States might influence problematic
partners’ counterinsurgency practices on the margins.
The first section below provides background detail on the
Government of Pakistan (GoP), the insurgent groups it has fought
since 2001, and the counterinsurgency campaigns in FATA, Swat/
Malakand, and Balochistan during the pre- and post-2008 peri-
ods. The next section analyzes the influences of the three domestic
structural variables—political inclusion, state capacity, and military
superiority—across each of the eight subcases. The third section ana-
lyzes the role of the U.S. partnership assistance in shaping GoP strat-
egy. Finally, the chapter concludes with some key findings supporting
the broader claims of this report and some additional implications of
the Pakistan case.
Background
The GoP has presided over an extremely diverse and contentious ethnic
and political landscape carved out of British India in 1947. Throughout
nearly all of its independence, Pakistan has been considered a weak and
114 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
non-democratic state, but it has possessed a very large and capable pro-
fessional military. It has fought four major wars with its longtime rival,
India, as well as a number of counterinsurgency campaigns. Today, its
landscape is dotted with numerous militant organizations of ethno-
national, sectarian, and religious extremist variants, some of which the
GoP disregards, some which it directly fights, and some of which it
tacitly relies on as an internal or external national security tool. The
government has engaged in three major counterinsurgency campaigns
against the Tehrik-e-Taliban Pakistan (TTP) since 2001, its previ-
ously inchoate incarnations in FATA since 2002, the Tehrik-e-Nifaz-e-
Shariat-e-Mohammadi (TNSM) in the Swat Valley and Malakand
Division since 2007, and a range of Baloch nationalist insurgent organi-
zations in Balochistan since 2005. At certain points in time, it has pros-
ecuted all three counterinsurgency campaigns simultaneously, stretch-
ing the limits of an already weak state. Consequently, its approach to
these insurgencies has varied, following preexisting patterns of varying
geography, political topography, and state capacity across regions and
even subregions.
Context
Physical and Human Geography
The physical and economic landscape of Pakistan has been very
unevenly distributed, which has led some to describe it as an artificial
construct. Pakistan is roughly the size of France and the United King-
dom combined and home to 180 million people. While the province of
Punjab forms the bulk of Pakistan’s industrial base, population centers,
political authority, and arterial road networks, the province of Sindh
remains important as an agricultural center and home to Pakistan’s
largest city and commercial capital, Karachi. The Northwest Fron-
tier province, recently renamed Khyber-Pakhtunkwa (KP), has been
increasingly integrated into the political, economic, and social fabric
of Pakistan since the 1970s. However, the vast expanse of Balochistan
province, which makes up 47 percent of Pakistan’s territory but only
4.5 percent of its population, largely exists apart from the other three
provinces and is mainly valued for its natural-resource deposits and its
newly developed Gwadar port. FATA, Gilgit-Baltistan (previously the
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 115
3 For examples, see Akbar S. Ahmed, Resistance and Control in Pakistan, rev. ed., London:
Routledge, 2004.
116 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
was both one of the richest provinces and one of the chief contributors
to the British Indian Army,4 was directly governed.
While Islam is the official religion of Pakistan and over 96 per-
cent of the population is Muslim (the majority Sunni and about 10 to
15 percent Shia), religious friction persists. Pockets of religious minori-
ties of Christians, Hindus, Sikhs, and Ahmadis5 constitute the remain-
der, but their numbers have declined due to migration or conversion.
Sectarian tensions have frequently escalated to violence and acts of ter-
rorism, not only between Sunnis and Shias but also within the Sunni
majority (for instance, between the Barelvi and Deobandi sects).
On paper, Pakistan is the most urbanized country on the South
Asian subcontinent (excluding the Maldives), with 36 percent of the
population living in cities. In daily life, however, kinship networks
remain strong and have prevented the breakdown of old sociocultural
structures. The country’s ethno-linguistic diversity, combined with the
strength of kinship networks of collective solidarity, have left Pakistan
a weak state beset by many strong societies.6
Government
Regime type and political inclusion. Since its independence, Paki-
stan has vacillated between civilian-led and military-led governments.
For the most part, however, the politics of the country have not been
very democratic or politically inclusive, and the military has histor-
ically dominated politics even during periods of civilian rule.7 Even
though an elected civilian regime took office in 2008, a number of
scholars and practitioners do not consider Pakistan a democracy given
4 Tan Tai Yong, The Garrison State: The Military, Government and Society in Colonial
Punjab, 1849–1947, New Delhi, India: Sage Publications, 2005; Perry Anderson, “Why
Partition?” London Review of Books, Vol. 34, No. 14, July 19, 2012.
5 Ahmadis are a sect that claims to be a branch of Islam, but a Pakistani constitutional
amendment declared them a non-Muslim minority, and they are prohibited from identifying
themselves as Muslims.
6 Anatol Lieven, Pakistan: A Hard Country, London: Allen Lane, 2011, pp. 12–16.
7 Husain Haqqani, Pakistan: Between Mosque and Military, Washington, D.C.: Carnegie
Endowment, 2005.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 117
that the military retains substantial control, and civil liberties such as
individual rights, freedom of expression, and rule of law have remained
poor even as political rights improved.8
Greater checks and balances within the government of Pakistan
have emerged since 2008, and the military has generally refrained from
overt interventions in politics. The passage of the 18th amendment
to the Constitution in 2010 reduced the powers of the executive and
devolved greater powers to the legislature and provinces. The legislature
has also grown more assertive on domestic politics and some aspects of
security such as counterterrorism, although the military continues to
dominate most aspects of national security. A strong and independent
judiciary has emerged since 2007, with the Supreme Court expanding
its oversight role and holding the military, the executive, and the leg-
islature to account. Additionally, the media has become an important
player on the political landscape and has grown substantially in terms
of the number of outlets and journalists.
These steps toward greater democracy were capped by a major
historical achievement in March 2013, when the democratically elected
civilian government became the first to complete a five-year term and
peacefully transition without military intervention to a newly elected
civilian government, suggesting a more robust and sustained com-
mitment to democratic governance by all institutions.9 Some charge
that the military has refrained from intervening in domestic politics
in large part as a choice, because it still controls national-security
policy. While this is true to a large extent, its choice has been in part
shaped by institutional developments that make interventions costlier,
such as a stronger media, judiciary, and parliament, and these civilian
institutions have begun to assert themselves in some national-security
debates. Thus, while Pakistan as a whole cannot be considered to have
10 T. V. Paul, South Asia’s Weak States: Understanding the Regional Insecurity Predicament,
Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2010.
11 Lieven, 2011, p. 13.
12 The indexed measures of state capacity in Chapter Two identify the Philippines as pos-
sessing high state reach and moderate government effectiveness (safely located in the second
quartile).
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 119
13 Based on data from the IMF, The World Bank, CIA World Factbook, Penn World Table,
and United Nations Development Program, The Rise of the South: Human Progress in a
Diverse World, Human Development Report, New York, 2013.
14 Fund for Peace, “Failed States Index, 2005–2013,” web site.
15 WDI data on tax revenue as a percentage of GDP for 2008. Another model to mea-
sure relative political extraction finds Pakistan near the bottom. See Marina Arbetman-
Rabinowitz et al., “Pakistan Has Lowest Tax to GDP Ratio in the World,” The Nation,
February 18, 2013, and Jennie Matthew, “Report Unmasks Tax Evasion Among Pakistan
Leaders,” Agence France Presse, December 12, 2012.
16 Transparency International, “2012 Corruption Perceptions Index,” website, 2012.
17Syed Rifaat Hussain, “War Against Terrorism, Pakistani Perspective,” IPRI Journal,
Winter 2004.
18 A. F. Aisha Ghaus, Hafiz A. Pasha, and Rafia Ghaus, “Social Development Ranking of
Districts of Pakistan,” The Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 35, No. 4 (Part II), Winter
1996, pp. 593–614.
19 Global Firepower, “Countries Ranked by Military Strength (2013),” web site. The index
is based on 42 measures.
120 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
20Seth G. Jones and C. Christine Fair, Counterinsurgency in Pakistan, Santa Monica, Calif.:
RAND Corporation, MG-982-RC, 2010; International Institute for Strategic Studies, The
Military Balance, London: Routledge, 2013.
21Stephen P. Cohen, The Idea of Pakistan, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press,
2004, p. 266; Hussain, 2004.
22Cohen, 2004, p. 121; Stephen Cohen, The Pakistan Army, Berkeley, Calif.: University of
California Press, 1984.
23 Sameer Lalwani, Pakistani Military Capabilities for a Counterinsurgency Campaign: A Net
Assessment, Washington, D.C.: New America Foundation, Counterterrorism Strategy Initia-
tive Publication, September 2009, pp. 41–46.
24 International Institute for Strategic Studies, 2013, p. 251.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 121
Insurgents
A vast array of insurgent, terrorist, and militant organizations based in
Pakistan have challenged state forces, institutions, or authority at vari-
ous points in time. In addition to these clear challengers to the state,
there are a number of militant organizations that are either ostensibly
neutral or even allied with the GoP. We focus primarily on the stron-
gest insurgent organizations that have directly threatened the state and
have been the targets of counterinsurgency campaigns over the past
decade. These include the Taliban-affiliated TTP and TNSM, as well
as Baloch nationalist insurgents.
Tehrik-i-Taliban Pakistan.25 The TTP insurgency originated in
2001, following the ouster of the Taliban and al Qaeda from Afghan-
istan during the U.S.-led invasion, when a number of foreign fight-
ers took refuge in Pakistan’s northwest. Alongside local militant com-
manders indigenous to the tribal regions, they began to violently assert
their influence, challenging local political orders and attacking GoP
security forces. In response to Pakistan military operations targeting
al Qaeda after 2001 and more-robust operations beginning in 2004,
some local tribal militants and commanders who hosted these foreign
fighters fought alongside them against the state. At first the local com-
manders conducted operations just within FATA, but eventually their
attacks spread across the country.
The nascent Pakistani Taliban eventually formed the basis for the
TTP, which was officially declared in late 2007 to be an umbrella orga-
nization of 40 senior Taliban commanders and Islamist militant move-
ments totaling 40,000 fighters. These diverse movements were united
by a desire to fight a “defensive jihad” against the Pakistan Army’s
incursions in the tribal regions. In July 2007, the Pakistani military’s
25 This account is based on Hasan Askari Rizvi, “Understanding the Insurgency,” Daily
Times, October 5, 2008; Shuja Nawaz, FATA—A Most Dangerous Place: Meeting the Chal-
lenge of Militancy and Terror in the Federally Administered Tribal Areas of Pakistan, Washing-
ton, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies Press, January 2009a; Imtiaz Gul,
The Most Dangerous Place: Pakistan’s Lawless Frontier, New York: Viking, 2011; Syed Saleem
Shahzad, Inside Al-Qaeda and the Taliban: Beyond Bin Laden and 9/11, London: Pluto Press,
2011; and Hassan Abbas, “A Profile of the Tehrik-i-Taliban,” CTC Sentinel, Vol. 1, No. 2,
January 2008, pp. 1–4.
122 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
26Scott Shane, “Insurgents Share a Name, but Pursue Different Goals,” New York Times,
October 23, 2009.
27 M. Ilyas Khan, “Taleban Spread Wings in Pakistan,” BBC News, March 5, 2007; Per-
vaiz Iqbal Cheema, “Challenges Facing a Counter-Militant Campaign,” National Bureau of
Asian Research, NBR Analysis, Vol. 19, No. 3, August 2008, pp. 21–29.
28 Nazir and Gul Bahadur’s groups were considered GoP allies even though there was evi-
dence they may have provided tacit support to bad Taliban elements. See Anand Gopal,
Mansur Khan Mahsud, and Brian Fishman, “The Taliban in North Waziristan,” in Peter
Bergen and Katherine Tiedemann, eds., Talibanistan: Negotiating the Borders Between Terror,
Politics, and Religion, New York: Oxford University Press, 2013, pp. 128–163; Mansur Khan
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 123
The Mehsud tribe came to form the core of the TTP, although it
was allied with a number of militant outfits across FATA, foreign fight-
ers, and even some Punjabi Taliban. Estimates of TTP force strength
have been highly varied due to militant-organization defection, attri-
tion, and the flow of militants between the Afghan and Pakistan the-
aters. However, in 2009, the Pakistani military estimated Mehsud
fighters to number about 10,000, making total estimates of the TTP
at 25,000 seem plausible, with upper-end estimates of 53,000 fight-
ers. Over time, what made the TTP—and specifically the Mehsud
component—so formidable and threatening was its ability to project
power and violence outside of FATA and strike civilian and military
targets in Pakistan’s core urban centers. This was done through suicide
bombings (of which the Mehsud/TTP force was believed to be respon-
sible for about 70 percent) and complex, high-risk attacks, includ-
ing one on the Army’s headquarters.29 This successful conversion of a
“defensive war into an offensive and proactive campaign” beginning in
2007 “represented a major escalation and a serious threat to the coun-
try’s centers of power.”30
Tehrik-e-Nifaz-e-Shariat-e-Mohammadi. The TNSM is a mili-
tant group dedicated to implementing Sharia law in the region of KP
formerly known as the Malakand Division, encompassing Swat, Dir,
Malakand, Chitral, and parts of Buner and Shangla. Unlike the TTP,
the TNSM (led by Mullah Sufi Muhammad) has long-standing roots
in Pakistan dating back more than two decades and stemming from
Pakistan’s major Islamist political party, Jamaat-e-Islami. The TNSM
engaged in major confrontations with the state in 1994 in reaction to a
Supreme Court decision overturning the validity of local tribal courts
and incorporating the region into mainstream Pakistani law. Nominal
Mahsud, “The Taliban in South Waziristan,” in Peter Bergen and Katherine Tiedemann,
eds., Talibanistan: Negotiating the Borders Between Terror, Politics, and Religion, New York:
Oxford University Press, 2013, pp. 164–201.
29 Mahsud, 2013, pp. 179–180.
30 The first quotation is from Gul, 2011, p. 40; the second is from Jerry Meyerle, Unconven-
tional Warfare and Counterinsurgency in Pakistan: A Brief History, Alexandria, Va.: Center for
Naval Analyses, November 2012, p. 30.
124 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
31 Account drawn from Mansoor Akbar Kundi, “Insurgency Factors in Balochistan,” The
Nation, October 20, 2004; Frederic Grare, Balochistan: The State Versus the Nation, Wash-
ington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Carnegie Paper, April, 2013;
Robert G. Wirsing, Baloch Nationalism and the Geopolitics of Energy Resources: The Chang-
ing Context of Separatism in Pakistan, Carlisle, Pa.: Strategic Studies Institute, April 2008;
Human Rights Commission of Pakistan, Conflict in Balochistan, Report of Human Rights
Commission of Pakistan Fact-Finding Mission, December 2005–January 2006; and Alok
Bansal, “Factors Leading to Insurgency in Balochistan,” Small Wars & Insurgencies, Vol. 19,
No. 2, June 2008, pp. 182–200.
126 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Conflict Narrative
Since 2001, the Pakistani government has focused on fighting three
insurgencies: the TTP in FATA, the TNSM in the Swat Valley/
Malakand, and nationalist/separatist militants in Balochistan. Draw-
ing on numerous detailed accounts, we next provide brief accounts of
the conflicts and the campaigns by the GoP and its security forces to
counter them.
FATA
After the fallout of 9/11 and U.S. military operations in Afghanistan,
militants based in FATA who were formerly part of, allied with, or
sympathetic to the Taliban began to assert their dominance over local
power structures and administrative institutions.34 They also resisted
GoP counterterrorism efforts coordinated with U.S. and NATO opera-
tions on the Afghan side of the border to round up these actors, and
they harbored foreign fighters and al Qaeda operatives. In response, the
GoP launched a number of large- and small-scale operations broadly
grouped under the name Operation al Mizan.35 The scope of the cam-
paign from 2002 to 2007 was narrow, with the threat viewed as one
“to be contained, not defeated.”36 Military activity was “sporadic,”
“not sustained over time,” and “incomplete, inconclusive, and at times,
appeared insincere.”37 Following clearing operations, the Army was
“reluctant to maintain a presence” or exert “any effort to control the
area fully.”38
34 Accounts of this case are drawn from Fair and Jones, 2009–2010; Gul, 2011; Nawaz,
2009; Shahzad, 2011; Brian Cloughley, War, Coups, and Terror: Pakistan’s Army in Years
of Turmoil, New York: Skyhorse, 2008; Brian Cloughley, “Insurrection, Terrorism and the
Pakistan Army,” in Usama Butt and N. Elahi, eds., Pakistan’s Quagmire: Security, Strat-
egy, and the Future of the Islamic-Nuclear Nation, London: Continuum International, 2010,
pp. 93–122; Ahmed Rashid, Descent into Chaos, London: Penguin Books, 2008; Carey
Schofield, Inside the Pakistan Army, London: Biteback Publishing, 2011; Sameer Lalwani,
“Pakistan’s Counterinsurgency Strategy,” in Peter Bergen and Katherine Tiedemann, eds.,
Talibanistan: Negotiating the Borders Between Terror, Politics, and Religion, New York: Oxford
University Press, 2013, pp. 202–228; Daniel Markey, Securing Pakistan’s Tribal Belt, Wash-
ington, D.C.: Council on Foreign Relations, Council Special Report No. 36, August 2008;
International Crisis Group, Pakistan’s Tribal Areas: Appeasing the Militants, Islamabad/Brus-
sels, Asia Report No. 125, December 11, 2006b.
35 Schofield, 2011, p. 133; Fair and Jones, 2009–2010, pp. 46–56.
36 Marvin G. Weinbaum, “Hard Choices in Countering Insurgency and Terrorism Along
Pakistan’s North-West Frontier,” Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 63, No. 1, Fall/Winter
2009, p. 75. The term containment is echoed in Meyerle, 2012, p. 29; Ijaz Khan, 2008, p. 14;
Cloughley, 2008, p. 189.
37 Fair and Jones, 2009–2010, p. 76.
38 Haider Ali Hussein Mullick, “Lions and Jackals: Pakistan’s Emerging Counterinsurgency
Strategy,” Foreign Affairs (online), July 15, 2009.
128 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
45 Quotation from Ijaz Khan, 2008, p. 14. Also see Markey, 2008, p. 12; Schofield, 2011,
p. 136; Joshua T. White and Shuja Ali Malik, Governance Reforms in Pakistan’s Tribal Areas:
The Long Road to Nowhere? Washington, D.C: United States Institute of Peace, Peace Brief
No. 135, October 15, 2012, p. 4.
46 David J. Kilcullen, Terrain, Tribes, and Terrorists: Pakistan, 2006–2008, Washington,
D.C.: Brookings Institution, Counterinsurgency and Pakistan Paper Series, No. 3, Septem-
ber 10, 2009, pp. 10–12.
47 Kamran Rasool, “Pakistan’s Perspective on the ‘War on Terror,’” Military Technology,
Vol. 32, No. 11, November 2008, p. 17; Schofield, 2011, p. 136.
130 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 5.1
FATA and Malakand Conflict Deaths per Engagement, 2002–2012
48 Gul, 2011, pp. 55–59; Ejaz Haider, “Intelligent Intelligence,” Daily Times, July 26, 2007;
Ismail Khan, “Militant Leader Threatens to Attack Forces, Dawn, July 30, 2005; Daud
Khattak, “Reviewing Pakistan’s Peace Deals with the Taliban,” CTC Sentinel, September
2012; interview with former U.S. government official, June 2013.
49 Rasool, 2008; Shuja Nawaz, 2009a; Shuja Nawaz, 2011.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 131
50 Shuja Nawaz, 2011; Haider Ali Hussein Mullick, “Recalibrating U.S.-Pakistan Relations,”
The Washington Quarterly, Vol. 35, No. 3, Summer 2012, pp. 93–107; Haider Ali Hussein
Mullick, “Holding Pakistan: The Second Phase of Pakistan’s Counterinsurgency Opera-
tions,” Foreign Affairs (online), March 24, 2010; Markey, 2008.
51 Shuja Nawaz, 2011; Frederick W. Kagan, Reza Jan, and Charlie Szrom, “The War in
Waziristan: Analysis of Operation Rah-e-Nijat: Phase 1 Analysis,” Critical Threats Project,
American Enterprise Institute, Washington, D.C., November 18, 2009; Reza Jan, “Trickling
Home to South Waziristan,” Critical Threats Project, American EnterpriseInstitute, Wash-
ington, D.C., December 13, 2010c; Jamal Hussain, 2012.
132 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
52 Reza Jan, “Daily Tracker: Pakistani Military Operations in Orakzai,” Critical Threats
Project, American Enterprise Institute, Washington, D.C., May 13, 2010a; Reza Jan and Sam
Worby, “Limited Goals, Limited Gains: The Pakistan Army’s Operation in Kurram, Critical
Threats Project, American Enterprise Institute, web site, September 6, 2011; Tayyab Ali Shah,
“Pakistan’s Challenges in Orakzai Agency,” CTC Sentinel, Vol. 3, No. 7, July 2010; Daud
Khan Khattak, “‘Clearing’ Kurram,” Foreign Policy’s AfPak Channel, August 25, 2011;
“PAF Conducted 5,500 Bombing Runs in FATA Since 2008,” Express Tribune, November
14, 2011.
53 Accounts drawn from Schofield, 2011, p. 178; Gul, 2011, pp. 112–119; Lalwani, 2009:
15–17; Christine Fair, “Pakistan Loses Swat to Local Taliban,” Terrorism Focus, Vol. 4,
No. 37, November 13, 2007; Afzal Khan, “Revolt in Pakistan’s NWFP: A Profile of Maulana
Fazlullah of Swat,” Terrorism Focus, Vol. 4, No. 38, November 20, 2007; International Crisis
Group, Pakistan Countering Militancy in PATA, Asia Report No. 242, Islamabad/Brussels,
January 15, 2013; Daud Khan Khattak, The Battle for Pakistan: Militancy and Conflict in
the Swat Valley, Washington, D.C., New America Foundation, Counterterrorism Strategy
Initiative Policy Paper, April 2010; Ahmed Rashid, “Pakistan’s Continued Failure to Adopt
a Counterinsurgency Strategy,” CTC Sentinel, Vol. 2, No. 3, March 2009; Ahmed Rashid,
Pakistan on the Brink: The Future of America, Pakistan, and Afghanistan, New York: Viking,
2012; Reza Jan, “Paradise Regained: Swat One Year On,” Critical Threats Project, American
Enterprise Institute, Washington, D.C., May 25, 2010b.
54 Gul, 2011, p. 118.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 133
55 “Pak Troops Seize Swat Peak, Shut ‘Mullah Radio,’” Times of India, November 28, 2007;
Riaz Khan, “Pakistan Shuts Down 3 Radio Stations,” Associated Press, March 21, 2008;
Richard A. Oppel, Jr., and Pir Zubair Shah, “In Pakistan, Radio Amplifies Terror of Tali-
ban,” New York Times, January 24, 2009.
56Mullick, 2009; Schofield, 2011, pp. 178–181; Syed Saleem Shahzad, 2011, p. 171;
Rahimullah Yusufzai, “Fallen City,” Newsline Magazine, January 3, 2009; interview with
Pakistan military analyst, June 2013; Khattak, 2010, pp. 9–10; Rashid, 2012, p. 141.
134 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
57Mullick, 2009; Khattak, 2010; Mullick, 2010; Shuja Nawaz, “Pakistan’s Summer of
Chaos,” ForeignPolicy, June 17, 2009b; Cloughley, 2010, p. 108; Zahid Hussain and Matthew
Rosenberg, “Pakistani Peace Deal Gives New Clout to Taliban Rebels,” Wall Street Journal,
April 14, 2009.
58Inter-Services Public Relations (Pakistan), “COAS Keynote Address— National Seminar
Deradicalization at Mingora Swat,” ISPR No PR157/2011, July 6, 2011.
59 James Blitz, James Lamont, and Farhan Bokhari, “Swat Outlook ‘Pretty Bleak’ for Paki-
stan,” Financial Times, May 13, 2009; “Pakistan and the Taliban: A Real Offensive or a
Phony War?” The Economist, April 30, 2009.
60 Jeremy R. Hammond, “The Situation in Swat: An Interview with Shahid R. Siddiqi,”
Foreign Policy Journal, July 9, 2009.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 135
Figure 5.1
Insurgent Incidents Over Time in Pakistani Regions, 2007–2013
800
700
Malakand
600 Other FATA
incidents
incidents
500
Number
400
300
NWA SWA
200 incidents incidents
100
0
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
was far better managed than previous military operations.61 One poll
in FATA found that even among the displaced, 52 percent supported
military operations.62
Following the repatriation of the population, the Army adapted
its approach to emphasize population control and protection. Army
forces maintained a sustained presence for years to prevent regrouping
of TNSM cadres, coordinated with locals and village councils, devel-
oped and utilized informant networks to monitor and prevent militant
reinfiltration, rebuilt a 3,700-strong professional police force, armed
and coordinated about 30,000 lashkars in defense of the area, facili-
tated the efforts of reconstruction and development teams, manned
61 Cheema, 2008, p. 27, had proposed this option earlier; Mullick, 2010; Danielle
Kurtzleben, “Pakistan: U.S. to Aid Civilians Fleeing Embattled Swat Valley,” Inter Press Ser-
vice, May 19, 2009; Jan, 2010c; Tara McKelvey, “A Return to Hell in Swat,” Foreign Policy,
March 2, 2011; Omar Warraich, “Refugees Head Home After Army Scatters the Taliban,”
The Independent, August 3, 2009..
62 Naveed Ahmad Shinwari, Understanding FATA: Attitudes Towards Governance, Religion
and Society in Pakistan’s Federally Administered Tribal Areas, Vol. IV, Islamabad: Community
Appraisal and Motivation Program, 2010, p. 57.
136 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
63 Jan, 2010b; Mullick, 2010; Mullick, 2009; Inter-Services Public Relations (Pakistan),
2011; “Pakistan Army Strategy in Question After Attacks,” Dawn.com, October 22, 2012;
interview with Pakistan analyst, 2012.
64 McKelvey, 2011; interviews with Pakistan analysts confirm this, 2012, 2013.
65 Mullick, 2012; McKelvey, 2011; Jan, 2011; “Pakistani Authorities Close Three Radio Sta-
tions for Pro-Taliban Broadcasts,” Associated Press, November 1, 2009; Ajaz Maher, “Paki-
stan’s Army Steps Up Radio Wars,” BBC News, August 14, 2012; “Pakistan Army Strategy
in Question After Attacks,” October 22, 2012; Rina Saeed Khan, “Swat Valley NGO Finds
a Solution to the Assault on Education,” The Guardian, May 10, 2011; Delwar Jan, “Mal-
akand Division on Road to Civilian Control,” The News International, August 8, 2012, p. 98;
Ahmad Hassan, “Operation in Malakand, Waziristan Is No Solution,” Dawn, November
8, 2009; Emmanuel Duparcq, “Swat Rebuilds Year After Pakistan Floods,” Agence France
Presse, July 24, 2011.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 137
Figure 5.2
Manpower and Operational Tempo in the Swat Valley/Malakand Region,
2007–2012
60 60
Manpower
Defensive engagements
50 50
Offensive operations
Manpower (thousands)
Operations/month
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul
2007 2007 2008 2008 2009 2009 2010 2010 2011 2011 2012 2012
SOURCES: Data from Pakistan Institute for Peace studies data; numerous sources
(for manpower).
RAND RR513-5.2
66 Reza Sayah, “Can the Return of Justice Halt the Taliban?” CNN, November 14, 2009;
“Judicial Reform in Swat,” Dawn, March 25, 2010; Rania Abouzeid, “Taliban Gone, Paki-
stan Area Still Wants Islamic Justice,” Time, April 25, 2010; Fazal Khaliq, “Speedy Justice:
Mobile Courts for Swat Announced,” Express Tribune, November 26, 2011; Fazal Khaliq,
“Nizam-e-Adl Regulation: Top Sharia Court Set Up in Swat,” Express Tribune, January 19,
2011a; Fazal Khaliq, “Terrorists Behind Swat Unrest to Face Justice,’” Express Tribune,
138 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Finally, the GoP also began the process of rehabilitating and rein-
tegrating several thousand former TNSM members deemed recon-
cilable. “Socio-psychological” deradicalization was conducted in two
Army-run centers, Mishal and Sabaoon, to reeducate these former mil-
itants and teach them basic vocational skills. More than 1,000 of them
have thus far been reintegrated.67
As of the writing of this report, violence has been reduced sub-
stantially, and Swat is considered by many to be a victory. Despite
having strongly criticized Pakistani counterinsurgency efforts previ-
ously, Ahmed Rashid wrote of these operations:
The war in Swat was the first, and so far the only, time the Paki-
stan Army successfully completed a counterinsurgency cam-
paign according to the book: the militants were killed, captured,
or driven out, the area was secured, the displaced population
returned, their homes were rebuilt, and the civic administration
was revived. The army had finally learned the principles of “clear,
hold, build, and transfer” . . . and could carry them out when it
had the will to do so.68
Balochistan
After nearly 30 years without major conflict, Baloch insurgents
reemerged in late 2004.69 The rebellion was fueled by the construc-
tion of the Gwadar port and the establishment of new Army garrisons,
November 27, 2011c; Fazal Khaliq, “Timely Justice: Community Body Gives Quick Solu-
tions for Small Disputes,” Express Tribune, March 13, 2013.
67 ISPR, 2011; Muhammad Amir Rana, “Swat Deradicalization Model: Prospects for
Rehabilitating Militants,” Conflict and Peace Studies, Vol. 4, No. 2, April-June 2011; Dina
Temple-Raston, “Pakistan’s Ambitious Program to Re-educate Militants,” NPR, April 1,
2013; Taha Siddiqui, “Deradicalizing Boys in Pakistan,” Christian Science Monitor, May 25,
2012; Kristen Seymour, “De-radicalisation: Psychologists’ War Against Militants,” Express
Tribune, July 17, 2011; Rohit Gandhi, “Deradicalization: A Tall Order,” Asia Pacific Defense
Forum, July 1, 2012.
68 Rashid, 2012, pp. 143–144.
69 Kundi, 2004; Grare, 2013; Wirsing, 2008; Bansal, 2008; Malik Siraj Akbar, Refined
Dimensions of Baloch Nationalist Movement, Bloomington, Ind.: Xlibris Corporation, 2011;
International Crisis Group, Pakistan: The Worsening Conflict in Balochstan, Asia Report
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 139
No. 119, Islamabad/Brussels, September 14, 2006a; Center for Research and Security Stud-
ies, Balochistan’s Maze of Violence, Islamabad, Pakistan, 2011.
70 Naveed Ahmad, “Trouble in Pakistan’s Energy-Rich Balochistan,” Zurich, Switzerland:
International Relations and Security Network, January 30, 2006; Khurram Shahzad, “What
Ails Balochistan?” The Nation, February 14, 2005.
71 Force numbers range from 4,500 to 70,000. See Bansal, 2008; Human Rights
Commission of Pakistan, 2005–2006; Akbar, 2011, p. 54; Tim McGirk, “Code of the
Frontier,” Time, January 30, 2005.
140 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
during the Swat campaign, in fact, the GoP is believed to have taken
steps to block NGO relief aid to Baloch IDPs.72
By 2007, some GoP officials believed they had crushed the
insurgency. These actions, however, appear to have further inflamed
it and increased insurgent intensity and activity (see Figure 5.3).
The GoP acknowledged in 2007 that insurgent activity and attacks
had increased, likely attributable to a martyrdom effect.73 Analysts
assessed that the majority of Baloch activists previously in support of
autonomy had been radicalized into the nationalist separatist camp.74
Figure 5.3
The Balochistan Insurgency, 2004–2013
800 1.2
Lethality
700
1.0
600 Attacks
0.8
500
Lethality
Attacks
400 0.6
0 0
2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
SOURCES: Data from Pakistan Institute for Peace studies and Worldwide Incidents
Tracking System.
NOTE: Figures for 2013 through June and estimated/doubled.
RAND RR513-5.3
72 Quotation from Wirsing, 2008, pp. 29–30; Human Rights Commission of Pakistan,
2005–2006, documents 22 killed in Jabbar Pakal, another 43 in Dera Bugti, and 41 from
the Jamhoori Watan Party, as well as 14 summary executions and 16 people missing, totaling
136; International Crisis Group, Pakistan: The Forgotten Conflict in Balochistan, Asia Briefing
No. 69, Islamabad/Brussels, October 22, 2007, p. 6.
73 Wirsing, 2008, pp. 39–40; International Crisis Group, 2006a.
74 Grare, 2013; Akbar, 2011, pp. 54–55.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 141
75 Grare, 2013; Mavish Ahmad, “Balochistan: Middle Class Rebellion,” Dawn, June 5,
2012.
76 M. Ilyas Khan, “Balochistan ‘Troops Numbers Cut,’” BBC News, May 14, 2008; Saeed
Shah, 2012; Siraj Ahmed, “Police Reform in Balochistan,” in Hassan Abbas, ed., Stabilizing
Pakistan Through Police Reform, Independent Commission on Pakistan Police Reform, New
York: Asia Society, July 2012, pp. 113–119.
77 International Crisis Group, 2007, p. 5; Grare, 2013, p. 13.
78 Matthew Green, “Hidden War Embodies Pakistan’s Struggle,” Financial Times, May 25,
2012.
142 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
79 Declan Walsh, “Pakistan’s Secret Dirty War,” The Guardian, March 29, 2011.
80Sohail Khan, “Disband Agencies ‘Death Squads,’ Stop [Military] Action in Balochistan:
SC,” The News, September 12, 2012.
81 Grare, 2013, pp. 15–19. See “We Only Receive Back the Bodies,” The Economist, April 7,
2012.
82 Interview with Pakistani journalist, Washington, D.C., May 2013.
83Ansar Abbasi, “37 Percent Baloch Favour Independence: UK Survey,” The News,
August 13, 2012.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 143
Table 5.2
Regime and Campaign Features of Pakistan Counterinsurgency, 2001–2013
Political Inclusion
The case of Pakistan generally supports predictions of how political
inclusivity and regime type shape counterinsurgency strategy. Given
that Pakistan was a non-democracy for much of this period, we would
expect that on average, it would rely on more-repressive, indiscriminate
military operations with few meaningful measures of political accom-
modation and reconciliation—in other words, strong-state repression
or containment policies, depending on the resources the government
could muster. This prediction generally holds true for the campaigns in
146 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Balochistan and most of the campaigns in FATA and Swat. The GoP
struggled to make credible commitments, relied on a narrow political
constituency, was less accountable to the broader public, and allowed
little civilian input on national-security matters, generally resulting in
the use of indiscriminate force with high civilian casualties and low
prospects for reconciliation. The deals and cease-fires the military
regime did make in FATA prior to the return of civilian rule in 2008
were merely tactical, shallow (involving a narrow subset of militants),
and neither trusted by insurgents nor durable.
Indiscriminate force continued in Balochistan throughout the
insurgency. After the 2008 elections, however, repressive tactics became
less visible. The irrelevance of the Baloch constituency, “a small, politi-
cally weak, recalcitrant, and untrustworthy ethno-tribal minority,”
allowed the GoP to continue with this approach.86 Even when the GoP
did make attempts at political negotiations or reconciliation, its cred-
ibility was undermined by a shortage of dialogue and quick resorts
to force.87 Eventually, even good-faith efforts routinely failed, because
Baloch opposition leaders do not trust the government. Ethnic Baloch
leaders have little role in central-government coalitions or bureaucra-
cies, and the civilian government cannot credibly commit to greater
Baloch autonomy when it cannot even withdraw federal security forces
or hold them accountable for indiscriminate violence.
Civilian casualties in FATA were not particularly high in the
early stages of the conflict, not because of any commitment to the dis-
criminate use of force by the military government, but rather due to
limited state capacity to support coercion and sustained operations.
When the military did conduct major operations, it relied on large-
unit actions, intensive firepower, and “indiscriminate and excessive
force.”88 A number of missteps may have resulted from not involving
civilians—both politicians and the civil bureaucracy—in decisionmak-
ing processes with the potential to disrupt a military’s organizational
89 Barry R. Posen, The Sources of Military Doctrine: France, Britain, and Germany Between
the World Wars, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1984; Colin Jackson, “Defeat in Vic-
tory: Organizational Learning Dysfunction in Counterinsurgency,” unpublished disserta-
tion, Cambridge, Mass.: Massachusetts Institute of Technology, June 2008.
90 Istiaq Ahmad, “Promising Partnership? American Af-Pak Strategy and Pakistan’s
Counterterrorism Response,” in Usama Butt and N. Elahi, eds., Pakistan’s Quagmire: Security,
Strategy, and the Future of the Islamic-Nuclear Nation, London: Continuum International,
2010, pp. 66–67. Interview with Pakistan military official, July 2013.
91 Based on survey data released by Pew Global Attitudes, Gallup, International Republican
Institute, Terror Free Tomorrow, Gilani Research, and World Public Opinion.
148 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Table 5.3
Estimates of Use of Indiscriminate Force in Different Counterinsurgency
Theaters, 2009–2012
ment might also have been hampered and unable to win public support
for costly actions like the mass evacuation of roughly 2 million people
or the follow-on expenditures to repatriate IDPs, maintain security
forces, and rebuild the region. Moreover, under President Musharraf’s
military government, it may have been difficult to distinguish neces-
sary military operations from power grabs, since the military could not
credibly commit to not overreaching—a limitation that may explain
the popular hostility to military operations prior to 2009.92
The elected KP provincial government, now far more accountable
to the general public, took costly actions to accommodate the insur-
gent support base in May 2008 and April 2009. Even though these
deals were insufficient and further military action was required, a GoP
sensitive to its political constituency not only paid lip service to politi-
cal accommodations on the core issues motivating the insurgency—
economic disenfranchisement and the sluggish justice system—it also
implemented judicial-sector reforms and established greater opportuni-
ties for education and vocational training.
92 Ijaz Gilani, Voice of the People: Public Opinion in Pakistan, 2007–2008, Karachi, Paki-
stan: Oxford University Press, 2010.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 149
counterinsurgency model after 2008. The fact that the strategy shifted
to a more discriminate model in the Swat Valley but not in FATA
and Balochistan may have been the result of higher levels of political
enfranchisement and more direct accountability of the government in
KP. Even after the elections in 2008, FATA had no elected representa-
tives and was primarily controlled by the military with little input from
civilians. Moreover, government officials had greater confidence in the
efficacy of investments in public goods and institutional reforms in KP,
where the social and governance infrastructure existed to support and
legitimize them. By contrast, government officials saw little incentive
to invest effort or resources in FATA or Balochistan, where many per-
ceived that “it wouldn’t take.”96 Though improved over the pre-2008
period, political inclusivity in Balochistan is still very low. For the most
part, the now broader central government coalition remains aloof to its
Baloch constituency, and the events in the province remain immune to
transparency by the press, accountability by the judiciary, and civilian
constraints on the security forces.
The Pakistani government’s approach to NWA provides another
departure from its typical policy of containment, albeit of a different
kind. In NWA, short-term cease-fires graduated to informal accommo-
dations as the government came to believe that militant groups in the
region did not directly threaten the Pakistani state or core, at least for
the time being. Given their geographic location on the border, Wazir
tribes were a key political constituency cultivated since the Afghan
jihad of the 1980s, represented well in the military, and potentially
useful as leverage in a future Afghanistan political settlement.97 Larger
military engagements that other counterinsurgency models demanded
might overstretch a military already committed to Swat and SWA,
break this “live-and-let-live” bargain, and invite even greater violence
on the mainland than that suffered between 2007 and 2010. For all
of these reasons, informal accommodation appeared to offer the best
approach.
96 Interview with former U.S. official, June 2013; International Crisis Group, 2006b, pp. 3,
9, 27.
97 Gul, 2011, p. 36; interviews with Pakistan analysts, May–June, 2013.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 151
State Capacity
Pakistan’s weak state capacity throughout the past decade has led it to
generally pursue less-resource-intensive strategies, particularly contain-
ment and, on occasion, informal accommodation, both of which are
more prone to indecisive outcomes and conflict resumption. Even when
the GoP attempted to complement military operations with develop-
ment in FATA and Balochistan, it produced very little return on the
ground due to scarce resources, a lack of focus, and weak institutions
for implementation.98
In six of the eight cases in our Pakistan case study, the GoP pur-
sued a strategy consistent with the predictions of a weak state (see Table
5.1 above). Scarcity led to selective strategies that would mitigate but
not eliminate insurgency. As long as violence remained below a cer-
tain threshold and did not threaten survival, the state could tolerate it.
This approach is consistent with the rationale expressed in Pakistani
Army doctrinal writings. In the 2002 Pakistan Army Green Book, one
author writes:
98 Most development funds in Balochistan get siphoned off by provincial officials. See
Lieven, 2011, p. 364; International Crisis Group, 2006b, p. 10.
99 Ata Ur Rehman, “Responsibilities of Pakistan Army in LIC Environment,” in Pakistan
Army Green Book 2002: Low Intensity Conflict, Rawalpindi, Pakistan: Pakistan Army, 2002,
p. 203.
152 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
100 Interview with development official, August 2013; Muhammad Zubair, “Army Operation
in South Waziristan: The TTP and IDPs,” Daily Times, June 19, 2012.
101 The
distinctiveness of the settled area and its impact on counterinsurgency was described
in numerous conversations with retired Pakistani military officials, including an interview
(December 2009) and a private briefing (April 2011).
154 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
of public goods and services, and the state’s prior presence and legiti-
macy made these viable substitutes for futile, excess violence.
FATA’s and Balochistan’s historically weak capacity and isolation
had acquired a path-dependence due to increasingly prohibitive costs
of development and a set of vested interests in the semiautonomous
nature of these ungoverned spaces.102 Despite its failure to curtail the
Baloch insurgency with negotiation offers, the central government
appears content with containment, “confident it can digest the cur-
rent amount of violence that is taking place.”103 With the exceptions
of NWA and SWA, explained above, this was true for much of FATA
as well.
Military Superiority
While military superiority and manpower has been a focal point for
the counterinsurgency literature, this case study of Pakistan’s recent
counterinsurgency campaigns finds mixed outcomes. Only one case
found a correlation between military superiority (and quality) and the
type of strategy adopted.
Military superiority is no guarantor of classic counterinsur-
gency approaches. In the Swat Valley, a more than threefold increase
in troop levels resulted in an almost prototypical classic counterinsur-
gency strategy involving restraint, population protection, public goods,
accommodation, and a decisive outcome. But when Pakistan’s enor-
mous military capabilities were deployed to the tribal regions of Balo-
chistan from 2005 to 2007 and in SWA in 2009–2010, none of these
processes or outcomes resulted. Though perhaps obvious, the utility of
military superiority is constrained by what a state or military chooses
to actually do with the forces deployed. The case of NWA is most
telling. The Pakistan military is believed to have deployed 40,000
troops in the agency since 2010, but it has generally avoided military
engagements—both major offensives and defensive encounters.
102 Ijaz
Khan, 2008, p. 20; Amina Khan, “FATA: Voice of the Unheard—Path-Dependency
and Why History Matters,” Strategic Studies (Islamabad), Vol. 31, Nos. 1 and 2, Spring 2011,
pp. 40–74.
103 Malik Siraj Akbar, “The Ifs and Buts of Negotiating with Insurgents in Balochistan,” The
Baloch Hal, August 1, 2013.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 155
104 FC are estimated to constitute between 50 and 75 percent of the 40,000 troops in NWA
given the number of regular army divisions based there (Nawaz and Khan, 2013, and inter-
views with Pakistani analysts, August 2013). On NWA strategy, see Syed Talat Hussain,
“Profiling Our North Waziristan Policy,” Express Tribune, October 29, 2012.
156 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Army. Moreover, they comprise nearly all of the FC. By contrast, the
Baloch are very poorly represented in both forces.105 They comprise
1 percent or less of the military, and even in the FC wings specifi-
cally tasked to the province of Balochistan (a force of some 30,000 to
50,000), ethnic Baloch are believed to constitute only 5 percent.106
Unsurprisingly, the Pakistani state was far more sensitive to puni-
tive measures against Pashtuns, because of ethnic and tribal ties and
concern that excessive force against them might threaten the cohe-
sion of a military of which they constitute a high proportion. In the
early years of the Taliban insurgency in FATA, the Pakistani military
faced a strategic risk due to problems of defection, desertion, refusals
to fight, and court-martials among some of its Pashtun officers and
soldiers who refused to conduct military operations against their kin.
Fears arose that continued operations “could split the army, which was
clearly unhappy at the prospect of fighting their own people.”107 With
Pashtuns in its ranks, the GoP also believed it had a better grasp of
Pashtun tribal motives and behavior and a method of managing the
insurgency without risking blowback. This may help to explain the
GoP’s persistence in pursuing peace deals over pure coercion, which
numerous observers described as appeasement.108
105 Ian Talbot, Pakistan: A Modern History, New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1998, p. 252;
Eliot Cohen, 2004, pp. 98, 218; Shuja Nawaz, 2011, p. 44; Cloughley, 2008, p. 187; Feroz
Ahmed, Ethnicity and Politics in Pakistan, Karachi, Pakistan: Oxford University Press, 1998,
pp. 253–254; Ayaz Ahmed Khan, “Balochistan Situation,” The Nation, April 10, 2005;
Shuja Nawaz, Crossed Swords: Pakistan, Its Army, and the Wars Within, Karachi, Pakistan:
Oxford University Press, 2008, p. 570; Tahir Amin, Ethno-National Movements of Pakistan,
Islamabad, Pakistan: Institute of Policy Studies, 1988, p. 174; Sher Baz Khan, “Punjab’s
Dominance in Army Being Reduced: ISPR,” Dawn, September 14, 2007; Hassan Abbas,
“Musharraf Contends with the Pashtun Element in the Pakistani Army,” Terrorism Focus,
Vol. 3, No. 42, November 1, 2006.
106 Author interview with Pakistan analyst, May 2013.
107 ZahidHussain, The Scorpion’s Tail: The Relentless Rise of Islamic Militants in Pakistan—
and How It Threatens America, New York: Free Press, 2010, p. 90; Abbas, 2006; Keller, 2008;
Cloughley, 2008, p. 187.
108 Based on interviews in Islamabad, Pakistan, October 2011; Sohail Habib Tajik, “Analysis
of Peace Agreements with Militants and Lessons for the Future,” Conflict and Peace Studies,
Vol. 4, No. 1, January–March 2011.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 157
109 Interviews with Pakistani political and national security analysts, May 2013.
110 Daniel S. Markey, Securing Pakistan’s Tribal Belt, Washington, D.C.: Council on Foreign
Relations, Council Special Report No. 36, August 2008, p. 117. Funding to bolster the FC
did not begin until 2007. See Markey, 2008, p. 21. The Pakistan counterinsurgency fund was
not initiated until 2009. See Susan B. Epstein and K. Alan Kronstadt, Pakistan: U.S. Foreign
Assistance, Congressional Research Service, R41856, October 4, 2012, p. 20.
158 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
111 Interviewwith former U.S. official, July 2013; also see Markey, 2013, pp. 113, 127, and
Vali Nasr, The Dispensable Nation: American Foreign Policy in Retreat, New York: Doubleday,
2013, p. 69.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 159
Equipment
Equipment from the United States was perhaps the most coveted form
of military assistance, from the Pakistani perspective. While a number
of conventional weapons systems were sold to the GoP for leverage
or access, U.S. provision and sales of lift capability, airpower, ground
mobility, ordinance disposal, and night vision equipment made the
Pakistan military a more competent force for fighting a counterin-
surgency campaign. Beginning in 2007, deliveries of 26 combat and
transport helicopters seemed to correspond with the increasing aggres-
siveness and operational tempo of Pakistani counterinsurgency opera-
112 Paul D. Miller, “How to Exercise U.S. Leverage Over Pakistan,” Washington Quarterly,
Vol. 35, No. 4, Fall 2012.
160 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Intelligence
As early as 2004 and perhaps earlier, a small SOF presence in Waziristan
was deployed to provide support to the Pakistani military, but with-
out mutual interests in operations in FATA, GoP commanders made a
deliberate choice to underutilize these assets. Once the GoP internal-
ized counterinsurgency operations in Swat and FATA as its own and
committed to serious campaigns in 2009, however, the United States
deployed ISR units to support the 11th Corps prior to and during
its operations in SWA and Bajaur, as well as intelligence fusion cells
embedded with the SSG and FC. Much of this support was politically
113 Kilcullen,2009, p. 12; Shuja Nawaz, 2011, pp. 7, 14; SIPRI Arms Transfer Database,
accessed April 1, 2013.
114 Eric Schmitt and Jane Perlez, “U.S. Unit Secretly in Pakistan Lends Ally Support,” New
York Times, February 23, 2009; “PAF Conducted 5,500 Bombing Runs,” 2011; Jamal Hus-
sain, 2012.
115 ShujaNawaz, 2011, pp. 7, 10, 14, 21–23; Kilcullen, 2009, pp. 12–13; Kagan, Jan, and
Szrom, 2009; SIPRI Arms Transfer Database, web site, 2013; Riaz Anwar Bashir et al., “Pat-
tern of Combat Casualties in War Against Terror Among Soldiers Wearing Body Armor at
CMH Peshawar,” Pakistan Armed Forces Medical Journal, No. 2, June 2012.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 161
feasible as long as it was kept largely secret from the broader public,
though this eventually proved untenable as relations deteriorated.116
Training
For years, the FC was continually criticized for deficiencies such as
unskilled personnel, poor training, inconsistent leadership, lack of
mobility, outdated weapons, shortage of equipment, a proclivity for
desertion, and compromised loyalties.117 In 2007, the United States
stepped up efforts to improve and expand these forces through finan-
cial assistance for new infrastructure, equipment (including 450 vehi-
cles), and a train-the-trainers program to improve fighting capacity and
morale specifically for counterinsurgency.118
As part of an advise-and-assist mission, U.S. SOF began training
Pakistani trainers in October 2008. The impact of this training, which
a few thousand FC underwent, appears to have been positive, although
it is difficult to estimate with certainty.119 Alongside the training, pay
for the FC was quadrupled, and better officers were introduced by a
more determined leader, Maj. Gen. Tariq Khan, making it difficult to
disentangle the effects of the training from these other factors.120 U.S.
officials involved in the training program argued that it had an imme-
diate effect on the skills, discipline, cohesion, and morale of the FC and
that competition by battalion commanders to have their units trained
offered evidence of its success.121 A former official not involved in the
116 Interview
with former U.S. official, June 2013; Asad Hashim, “Pakistan and the U.S.:
A Too-Close Embrace?” Al Jazeera, June 3, 2011.
117 Abbas, 2007; Ashraf, 2008; “U.S. Begins Training Pakistan Frontier Corps,” Jane’s
Country Risk Daily Report, October 27, 2008.
118 Markey,
2008, p. 21; Anwar Iqbal, “No Operation in North Waziristan, U.S. Told,”
Dawn, March 31, 2010.
119 Estimate based on rate of training described in various accounts, including interviews and
Jeremy Page, “Britain to Train Pakistan’s Frontier Corps Troops in Baluchistan,” The Times,
October 9, 2009.
120 Eric Schmitt and Thom Shankar, Counterstrike: The Untold Story of America’s Secret Cam-
paign Against Al Qaeda, New York: Henry Holt, 2011, pp. 198–200.
121 Interview with former U.S. advisor to the FC, April 2013.
162 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
127 Markey, 2008, pp. 19–20; Markey, 2013, p. 112; Craig Cohen and Derek Chollet, “When
$10 Billion Is Not Enough: Rethinking U.S. Strategy Toward Pakistan,” Washington Quar-
terly, Vol. 30, No. 2, 2007, p. 12.
128 Nancy Birdsall, “Risking the Dog for the Tail,” Newsweek, February 28, 2011; Hassan
Abbas and Shehzad H. Qazi, “Rebellion, Development and Security in Pakistan’s Tribal
Areas,” CTC Sentinel, Vol. 6, No. 6, June 2013; Jane Perlez, “U.S. Aid Plan for Pakistan
Is Foundering,” New York Times, May 1, 2011; interview with former Pakistani official,
July 2013.
164 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
129 Mosharraf Zaidi, “Demystifying Foreign Aid,” The News, December 15, 2010; Nasr,
2013, p. 80; International Crisis Group, Aid and Conflict in Pakistan, Asia Report No. 227,
Brussels/Islamabad, June 27, 2012; Markey, 2013, p. 149; Nancy Birdsall, Wren Elhai, and
Molly Kinder, Beyond Bullets and Bombs: Fixing the U.S. Approach to Development in Paki-
stan, Washington, D.C.: Center for Global Development, June 2011, p. 14.
130 Markey, 2013, pp. 145–150; interview with development official, August 2013.
131 Markey, 2013, p. 144.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 165
the U.S. textile market). The GoP had long pursued trade access—
recognizing some of the inflationary risks and limited downstream
effects of direct aid—to spur economic growth and job creation and
create more stakeholders in U.S.-Pakistan relations.134
Though bolstering political inclusion and state capacity were
daunting tasks, assistance to complement specific counterinsurgency
efforts proved effective. U.S. humanitarian and stabilization aid consis-
tently remained popular among Pakistanis. Such aid not only cushioned
the impact of natural disasters, it also helped to ameliorate the civilian
impact of military operations that produced millions of IDPs, such as
those in Swat. By spring 2013, about one-third of the EPPA’s disbursed
$3.2 billion had been spent on emergency relief. These funds tended to
be dispersed quickly to address immediate needs and encountered few
bureaucratic obstacles.135 Moreover, the Swat experience later revealed
that more-robust and sustained military operations could produce fer-
tile ground for development and governance assistance to be effective.
Assistance provided after major combat operations in Swat seemed to
have a greater economic impact than aid deployed to conflict-affected
regions, and it was often matched by local entrepreneurs, confident in
the future, making capital investments. Recently, U.S. efforts in more-
stable parts of the northwest to facilitate the provision of some public
goods on a local level have seemed to be positively influencing local
attitudes and confidence in government.136
134 Birdsall,
Elhai, and Kinder, 2011; Nicolas Brulliard, “Pakistan Textile Exports: Call for
Wider Lifting of U.S. Tariffs Intensifies,” Washington Post, December 24, 2010; Kalbe Ali,
“U.S. Withdraws ROZs Offer,” Dawn, November 10, 2012.
135 Kurtzleben,2009; interview with former Pakistani official, August 2013; Alan Gelb and
Caroline Decker, “Direct Payments to Pakistan’s Flood Victims: A Smart Option for U.S.
Assistance,” The Hill, November 8, 2010; Umer Nangiana, “NA Question Hour: Pakistan
Received $3.2B Under Kerry-Lugar-Berman Act,” Express Tribune, March 7, 2013; Pew
Research Center, 2013; William S. Murphy, Review of USAID’s Internally Displaced Persons
Program in Pakistan, Washington, D.C.: Office of Inspector General, Review Report No.
5-391-10-001-S, June 28, 2010.
136 “GrowthProjections: Washington to Help Revive Tourism in Swat, Olson,” Express Tri-
bune, March 15, 2013; interview with development official citing private survey data, August
2013.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 167
137 Cohen and Chollet, 2007; Miller, 2012; Stephen Krasner, “Talking Tough to Pakistan,”
Foreign Affairs, Vol. 91, No. 1, January–February 2012, pp. 87–96.
138 SyedTalat Hussain, 2012; “Not Allies: Eight Dead as TTP, Haqqani Network Clash
in North Waziristan,” Express Tribune, April 19, 2012; Tahir Khan, “Rival Groups Launch
Operations Against Pakistan Taliban in Mohmand,” Express Tribune, June 26, 2013.
139 Interviews and discussions with numerous retired Pakistani officials and analysts.
168 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
140 JavedHussain, “The Hornet’s Nest,” The News International, January 19, 2011; Shem-
rez Nauman Afzal, “North Waziristan: The Death Trap,” Lahore, Pakistan: Spearhead
Research, December 29, 2010; interviews in Pakistan, October 2011.
141 These included numerous public-pressure campaigns by leading U.S. officials, including
threats to lead independent incursions into Pakistan in 2007, after elected civilian leaders
contemplated negotiations in the spring of 2008 and 2009, surrounding visits by U.S. offi-
cials in fall 2009, after the failed Times Square bombing in May 2010, or through Adm.
Mullen’s September 2011 testimony linking Pakistan’s Inter-Services Intelligence to the
Haqqani network.
142 Jane Perlez and Helene Cooper, “Signaling Tension, Pakistan Shuts NATO Route,” New
York Times, September 30, 2010; Miller, 2012.
143 Interview with former U.S. official, June 2013; Markey, 2013, pp. 105–135. “Impressions
of Waziristan, January 25, 2005,” National Security Archive, declassified cable, Electronic
Briefing Book No 325, September 13, 2010.
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 169
144 Deputy to the Special Representative for Afghanistan and Pakistan Daniel Feldman,
“Testimony Before South Asia Subcommittee, House Foreign Affairs Committee,” transcript,
April 5, 2011; Gen. David Petraeus, “Hearing to Receive Testimony on the Situation in
Afghanistan,” testimony before Senate Armed Services Committee, March 15, 2011; Adm.
Mike Mullen, transcript of speech delivered to Washington Institute for Near East Policy,
January 7, 2010.
145 Nasr, 2013, p. 94; Epstein and Kronstadt, 2012; interview with former U.S. national
security official, June 13, 2013; interview with Pakistani military official, July 2013.
146 Sartaj Aziz, “The Economic Cost of Extremism,” in Usama Butt and N. Elahi, eds.,
Pakistan’s Quagmire: Security, Strategy, and the Future of the Islamic-Nuclear Nation, London:
Continuum International, 2010, pp. 75–92. Some U.S. officials acknowledged this problem.
In reference to the $5 billion he helped raise through the Friends of Democratic Pakistan
donor community, Richard Holbrooke stated that “Pakistan needs $50 billion, not $5 bil-
lion.” General Petraeus also recognized this and said, “You get what you pay for. We have
not paid for much of anything in Pakistan.” See Nasr, 2013, p. 80; interview with Pakistani
military official, July 2013.
170 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Conclusion
The case study of Pakistan offers further support for the theory and
empirical analysis presented in Chapters Two and Three. There is broad
support for the contention that political inclusion and state capacity
influence a state’s general choices of counterinsurgency strategy in
terms of the level of discriminate violence, provision of public goods,
and openness to reconciliation. At a more nuanced level, when coun-
terinsurgency campaigns are broken down over time and space, the
predictions still hold: Regions with higher levels of political inclusion,
institutional integration, and state capacity prior to conflict are more
likely to exhibit counterinsurgency campaigns that look like the clas-
sic counterinsurgency model. Subnational conditions, in other words,
may explain much of the variation in counterinsurgency approaches
that cannot be explained by the properties of the state at the macro
level.
Since these subnational conditions are also important determi-
nants of conflict onset, counterinsurgency will take place more fre-
quently in these weak areas, leading states to more frequently adopt
strategies of containment or informal accommodation. The type of
competitive state-building the classic counterinsurgency model envi-
sions assumes that a state can impose its writ on these “ungoverned”
spaces. Generating the local architecture and tools necessary to imple-
ment this approach in a sustained manner may be infeasible, however,
due to local resistance and excessive costs, as has been the case for the
Pakistani government in FATA. In these areas, governments may have
to settle for second-best strategies like informal accommodation and
Counterinsurgency in Pakistan 171
173
174 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
1 On the United States’ attempts to enforce liberalizing reforms on El Salvador, see, for
instance, Watts et al., 2012; Mark Peceny, “Two Paths to the Promotion of Democracy
During U.S. Military Interventions,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 39, 1995, pp. 371–
401; Thomas Carothers, In the Name of Democracy: U.S. Policy Toward Latin America in the
Reagan Years, Berkeley, Calif.: University of California Press, 1993, especially Ch. 1.
176 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
larly if the partner regime would be at high risk of defeat without U.S.
assistance, threats to withdraw that assistance should be highly per-
suasive. The problem is that U.S. credibility and the reputations of key
U.S. actors become intertwined with the fate of the partner regime.
Withdrawing U.S. support for a partner might lead to the partner’s
defeat, which would be seen as a blow to the United States’ global
reputation for supporting its allies and would impose domestic political
costs on those decisionmakers who had initially supported the partner
regime.6 In fact, several observers have posited what might be called
the “leverage dilemma”: the greater the U.S. commitment to a partner
regime, the less leverage it has over the partner.7 South Vietnam, Iraq,
and Afghanistan are cited as the paradigmatic examples.
Stated in such linear terms, the leverage dilemma is almost cer-
tainly wrong: Taken to its extreme, it implies that the United States
would have maximum leverage when it supplied no assistance what-
soever to the partner regime. Nonetheless, studies of development
assistance do suggest that a donor’s ability to exercise leverage over an
aid recipient is significantly weakened if the recipient is critical to the
donor’s national interests.8
Sierra Leone provides a useful example of the potential and limits
of conditionality. In 2007, the incumbent Sierra Leonean People’s Party
(SLPP) lost largely free and fair elections. The SLPP had given every
6 One of the earliest and most influential arguments to this effect was Blaufarb’s (1977).
One of the best case studies on the domestic political consequences of such failures remains
Leslie H. Gelb and Richard K. Betts, The Irony of Vietnam: The System Worked, Washington,
D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1979. On “audience costs” more generally, see James Fearon,
“Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes,” American
Political Science Review, Vol. 88, No. 3, September 1994, pp. 577–592, and Michael Tomz,
“Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations: An Experimental Approach,” Interna-
tional Organization, Vol. 61, No. 4, Autumn 2007, pp. 821–840.
7 See, for instance, Shafer, 1988. For a more recent example, see Hammes, 2012.
8 See, for instance, Axel Dreher, Jan-Egbert Sturm, and James Raymond Vreeland, “Devel-
opment Aid and International Politics: Does Membership on the UN Security Council
Influence World Bank Decisions?” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 88, No. 1, 2009,
pp. 1–18, and Axel Dreher, Jan-Egbert Sturm, and James Raymond Vreeland, “Global Horse
Trading: IMF Loans for Votes in the United Nations Security Council,” European Economic
Review, Vol. 53, No. 7, 2009, pp. 742–757.
Managing Troubled Partnerships 179
9 Jimmy D. Kandeh, “Rogue Incumbents, Donor Assistance, and Sierra Leone’s Second
Post-Conflict Elections of 2007,” Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol. 46, No. 4, 2008.
10 See, for instance, Peter Blunt and Mark Turner, “Decentralization, Democracy, and
Development in a Post-Conflict Society: Commune Councils in Cambodia,” Public Admin-
istration and Development, Vol. 25, 2005, pp. 84–85; Ben D’Exelle, “Excluded Again:
Village Politics at the Aid Interface,” Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 45, No. 9,
180 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
challenges donor nations face in monitoring the effects of their aid are
even more pronounced in conflict environments, where their person-
nel often operate under severe mobility restrictions. This dynamic was
observed in both of the case studies in this report and can be seen
even in heavy-footprint theaters such as Afghanistan, where the United
States possessed many more transportation assets and capabilities for
personnel protection than is the case in light-footprint interventions.
October 2009, pp. 1453–1471; Richard Fanthorpe, “On the Limits of Liberal Peace: Chiefs
and Democratic Decentralization in Post-War Sierra Leone,” African Affairs, Vol. 105, No.
418, 2006, p. 40; and Harry G. West and Scott Kloeck-Jenson, “Betwixt and Between: ‘Tra-
ditional Authority’ and Democratic Decentralization in Post-War Mozambique,” African
Affairs, Vol. 98, No. 393, 1999, pp. 455–484.
Managing Troubled Partnerships 181
Lant Pritchett and his colleagues estimated how long it would take the
worst-rated countries of the world to reach a level of state effectiveness
equivalent to that of middle-ranked developing countries—countries
such as Algeria, Tanzania, and Guatemala—on a variety of governance
indicators. The results are sobering. If the 20 worst-rated countries con-
tinued to reform at their current pace, most of them would never reach
the current quality of governance of middle-ranked developing coun-
tries, because their recent performance has been negative. Even if the
worst-ranked countries experienced a miraculous change and started
to reform as rapidly as the 20 fastest-reforming countries in the world,
most would still require approximately 15 years to reach the middle
tier of developing-country state effectiveness, and some would require
three decades. If the bar were raised so that the goal were to become
as effective as the 75th percentile of developing countries, most of the
20 worst-rated countries would require approximately 25 years to reach
the goal, even if they consistently implemented reforms as rapidly as
the top 20 fastest-reforming countries in the world.11
The results are somewhat more encouraging if we look more nar-
rowly at building the military capabilities of partner nations. U.S.
advisors from among conventional forces, SOF, and contractors have
experienced considerable success in improving partner nations’ tacti-
cal capabilities in the short term. The case studies in this report pro-
vide evidence of such improvements in the Philippines and Pakistan,
and similar gains have been observed among the troop-contributing
countries to the African Union Mission in Somalia (AMISOM) and
elsewhere.12
Even here, however, there are important limits to the degree of
change that can be effected. While tactical skills such as marksman-
ship can be imparted relatively easily, operational-level skills are much
more challenging. Developing-country militaries frequently struggle
with logistics and sustainment, intelligence fusion and analysis, and
Policy Implications
Is it possible to make “bad” counterinsurgents better? The evidence
assembled here and in our case studies suggests that it is extremely
difficult to transform partner nations during the course of a conflict.
Change typically comes slowly, and attempting to use external aid to
leverage reform efforts has a poor overall record of success. Despite
these findings, the literature on development assistance and interna-
tional diplomacy suggests at least three ways in which conditionality
policies are appropriate and, indeed, critical components of an overall
partnership strategy.
First, aid conditionality is necessary to “sterilize” the negative
effects of foreign assistance. Many observers warn that foreign assis-
tance provides regimes with an independent source of income and
patronage, making them less reliant on—and thus less responsive to—
their own populations.15 In this sense, foreign aid is potentially much
like oil or other natural-resource rents that have been shown to have
highly corrosive effects on developing countries’ governance. Unlike
oil, however, aid is typically administered with a number of condi-
tions intended to limit the ability of recipient regimes to divert these
resources for private gain.16 Even if conditionality cannot be used to
reform the recipient regime as a whole, it may at least be used to reduce
the negative effects of the rents that can be derived from aid.
15 See, for instance, Nicolas van de Walle, African Economies and the Politics of Permanent
Crisis, 1979–1999, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001.
16 Paul Collier, “Is Aid Oil? An Analysis of Whether Africa Can Absorb More Aid,” World
Development, Vol. 34, No. 9, 2006, pp. 1482–1497.
184 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
The research presented here has indicated that the United States can
easily partner with relatively inclusive, higher-capacity regimes such
as those in the Philippines and Colombia. Particularly where those
regimes lack needed military capabilities, the United States can offer
critical assistance. With regimes that are inclusive but lack capacity,
the United States still has substantial options—albeit at reduced odds
of success. In such cases, the United States should strongly consider
whether informal accommodation would meet minimal U.S. security
goals.
The more-challenging circumstances are those in which the
regime is not inclusive, especially when it lacks both political inclusion
and state capacity. The odds of success are not favorable in such situa-
tions, and the risks of abusive behavior by the regimes are substantial.
If the United States still believes it must partner with such regimes
19 The recently released Presidential Decision Directive on Security Sector Assistance issues
similar guidance for routine security assistance: “[The Department of] State will report on
the development of a set of notional triggers to prompt the United States Government to
consider initiating, restructuring, pausing, terminating, or reinstituting SSA programming
for use by policymakers and planners. Circumstances warranting such an interagency review
may include . . . SSA partners that are pursuing activities counter to U.S. policy, security
interests or United States Government SSA goals; partner change of government or other
landmark changes in political circumstances; or programs that fail to meet short-term aims
(in 2–3 years).” See “Implementation of Security Sector Assistance (SSA) Presidential Deci-
sion Directive (PDD),” Washington, D.C.: The White House, undated, pp. 5–6.
186 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
despite the challenges, there are a number of rules of thumb that can
be used to guide policy.
General Principles
Counterinsurgency is perhaps the most context-dependent activity in
which militaries engage. Consequently, no universal set of policy pre-
scriptions is possible. At least three principles, however, can be dis-
cerned from the case studies in this report and the broader literature on
counterinsurgency and development to guide U.S. partnerships with
problematic partners.
Alignment of interests. Where U.S. and partner-nation interests
fundamentally diverge, there is little hope of a productive partnership
to combat an insurgency within the partner nation. The United States’
leverage and information are insufficient to effectively use conditional-
ity to overcome such gulfs. Examples of fundamental divergences in
interests include cases in which the partner nation does not perceive
an insurgent group as a threat (and may even regard it as a partner
for fighting proxy conflicts, as has sometimes been the case in Paki-
stan) and cases in which the United States demands the elimination of
ungoverned spaces over which the partner nation lacks the resources
to assert effective control. Less fundamental differences in goals can
be managed, as the Philippines case demonstrated. Even so, such rela-
tionships entail risk—particularly the risk that the partner nation will
use military capabilities developed with U.S. assistance for purposes
that the United States opposes. In such cases, it is important that the
United States make clear and stand by its redlines.
Pushing on open doors. Conditionality can reasonably be used
to enforce redlines, to press for a limited number of important but nar-
rowly scoped reforms, or to take advantage of specific moments in time
when more wide-ranging political change is possible. In most cases,
U.S. efforts to reform the partner nation should focus on finding areas
of agreement, potentially helping to convene the networks of actors
in the partner nation that can implement changes, and then provid-
ing the necessary resources and technical expertise. U.S. support to
AFP operations in the Sulu Archipelago, as described in Chapter Four,
is one such example of a narrowly targeted, intensive collaboration.
Managing Troubled Partnerships 187
20 See, for instance, Merilee S. Grindle, “Good Enough Governance: Poverty Reduction and
Reform in Developing Countries,” Governance, Vol. 17, No. 4, October 2004, pp. 525–548;
Verena Fritz, Kai Kaiser, and Brian Levy, Problem-Driven Governance and Political Economy
Analysis, Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2009; Matt Andrews, The Limits of Institutional
Reform in Development: Changing Rules for Realistic Solutions, New York: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press, 2013; and Thomas Carothers and Diane de Gramont, Development Aid Confronts
Politics: The Almost Revolution, Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace, 2013.
188 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
dozen years, and the Philippines case study in this report highlighted
the critical role the United States is likely to play in sustaining AFP
capabilities for years to come. Decisionmakers should carefully weigh
their ability to make such long-term commitments, particularly where
partner nations are problematic. With the memories of the 9/11 attacks
fading and public attention no longer monopolized by the wars in Iraq
and Afghanistan, decisionmakers should expect more critical scrutiny
of these light-footprint engagements. The example of El Salvador in the
1980s is instructive: The U.S. Congress became increasingly critical of
U.S. support to the Salvadoran regime, drastically cutting the Reagan
administration’s requests for aid to its ally despite the fact that the com-
munist insurgency had battled the regime to a draw. Had the Cold
War not ended, the level at which the United States could have main-
tained its support is unclear. Particularly where potential U.S. partners
prove abusive or use violence indiscriminately, sustaining partnerships
long enough to see significant changes in partner counterinsurgency
behavior may be untenable.
Bounded Accommodation
Because only a minority of conflicts now end in outright military vic-
tory and the proportion decided by defeat on the battlefield has been
steadily declining since World War II, the need to reach political
accommodation with at least that portion of the opposition that can be
accommodated without compromising core interests of the counterin-
surgent appears to be increasing. Unfortunately, such accommodation
is difficult for regimes characterized by low levels of political inclusion.
What can the United States do to facilitate such bounded accom-
modation? Depending on the precise circumstances, a number of
instruments are available.
Bolstering the credibility of regime commitments. Democra-
cies sometimes seek to implement accommodative solutions to insur-
gencies but lack the resources necessary to follow through on all of
their promises. In such cases, foreign assistance can be critical in help-
ing the counterinsurgent regime make good on its commitments, as
the case of the Philippines illustrated. In other cases, even autocratic
governments are willing to cut deals that would give rebels important
Managing Troubled Partnerships 189
21 See, for instance, Barbara F. Walter, Committing to Peace: The Successful Settlement of
Civil Wars, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2001, and Virginia Page Fortna, Does
Peacekeeping Work? Shaping Belligerents’ Choices After Civil War, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press, 2008.
22 Philippe le Billon, “Buying Peace or Fueling War: The Role of Corruption in Armed Con-
flicts,” Journal of International Development, Vol. 15, 2003, p. 420.
23 Galula, 2006 [1964], especially pp. 89–92.
24See, for instance, Paul Jackson and Zoe Scott, Local Government in Post-Conflict Environ-
ments, Oslo: United Nations Development Program, 2007.
25 Identifying the precise circumstances in which local governance is likely to exert positive
effects is a complicated exercise. One such attempt is Kristin M. Bakke and Erik Wibbels,
190 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Regulated Violence
Accepting that the United States usually has only limited influence in
light-footprint partnerships and that success is a long-term prospect
implies an important corollary: The United States must undertake pol-
“Diversity, Disparity, and Civil Conflict in Federal States,” World Politics, Vol. 59, October
2006, pp. 1–50.
26 For a review of the social science literature on this subject, see Stephen Watts, “Political
Dilemmas of Stabilization and Reconstruction,” in Paul K. Davis, ed., Dilemmas of Interven-
tion: Social Science for Stabilization and Reconstruction, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corpo-
ration, MG-1119-OSD, 2011.
27 As pointed out in Chapter Four, for example, there were many limitations on the Philip-
pines’ democratic transition. Democratically elected administrations did not consistently
adopt the counterinsurgency practices expected of more politically inclusive regimes for
nearly two decades after the country’s initial democratic transition.
Managing Troubled Partnerships 191
icies to mitigate the risk that its partners will use violence indiscrimi-
nately or otherwise engage in large-scale abuses while receiving U.S.
military aid. Clearly such a policy is in line with American values, but
it is also in line with U.S. interests. As discussed in Chapter Two, the
discriminate use of violence is an important predictor of counterinsur-
gent success. It is also often necessary in order for the United States
and other Western democracies to sustain their assistance to a counter-
insurgent regime and sometimes to developing-nation partners more
generally. The example of increasing Congressional opposition to aid
for El Salvador in the 1980s has already been mentioned. Even more
starkly, French popular reaction against the French government’s sup-
port of the Habyarimana regime in Rwanda after the 1994 genocide
was a significant factor in France’s retrenchment from its military com-
mitments in sub-Saharan Africa.28
How can the United States mitigate the risk of abuses by partner
nations’ security forces? The communication of clear and credible red-
lines, as discussed above, is probably the most important thing that the
United States can do. Beyond such threats to terminate aid, the United
States can also undertake a number of actions in the course of its secu-
rity assistance.
Improving civil-military relations. As the case of the Philip-
pines shows, even relatively promising regimes can have their counter-
insurgency strategies undone by poor civil-military relations. Strong
democratic oversight is typically associated with more-professional,
higher-quality militaries, while many autocratic regimes suffer from
problems of leadership and capability traceable to a heavy reliance on
patronage networks, the need to prevent coups, and similar patholo-
gies.29 Militaries also often prove unwilling to accommodate even the
reconcilable opposition, insisting on outright military defeat of rebels,
28 Xavier Renou, “A New French Policy for Africa?” Journal of Contemporary African Studies,
Vol. 20, No. 1, 2002, pp. 5–27.
29 See, for instance, Byman, 2006; Herbert M. Howe, Ambiguous Order: Military Forces in
African States, Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2001.
192 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
30 See, for instance, David D. Laitin and Drew A. Harker, “Military Rule and National
Secession: Nigeria and Ethiopia,” in Morris Janowitz, ed., Civil-Military Relations: Regional
Perspectives, Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1981.
31See, for instance, Gen. Carter Ham, testimony before the U.S. Senate Armed Services
Committee, March 7, 2013.
32 For critical examinations, see Goode, 2009–2010, pp. 45–57; Thiel, 2011.
Managing Troubled Partnerships 193
33On this point, see also Howe, 2001; Andre Le Sage, “Africa’s Irregular Security Threats:
Challenges for U.S. Engagement,” Strategic Forum, No. 255, May 2010, p. 8.
34 See also Herbst, 2004.
35 The United States’ commitment to security-sector reform is expressed in the U.S. govern-
ment’s policy document, “Security Sector Reform,” February 2009. Some elements of risk-
identification and risk-mitigation strategy are embedded in the recent “Presidential Decision
Directive on Security Sector Assistance” (undated), but the details remain to be worked out.
194 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Coding Notes
Dependent Variables
Acceptable Decisive Outcome
An acceptable decisive outcome is one in which the government either
wins an outright military victory or is able to negotiate a formal peace
agreement following a military stalemate. Our coding of military vic-
tory was derived from a version of the dataset in Connable and Libicki
(2010), updated with data from Watts et al. (2012). Coding of nego-
tiated settlements was derived from the data in Doyle and Sambanis
(2006), updated through 2008 primarily using histories from the
Europa World Plus online database, supplemented with additional
source material where necessary (e.g., Watts et al., 2012).
Mass Killings
Our indicator of indiscriminate violence was derived from data on
intentional government killings of civilians assembled by Ulfelder and
Valentino (2008).1
Ulfelder and Valentino’s instances of mass killings do not match
up perfectly with the civil-wars list defined by Doyle and Sambanis
that we used for our sample of cases. Consequently, we had to choose
1 Data from Ulfelder and Valentino were updated through 2010 through email correspon-
dence with the authors. Specifically, two new cases of mass killings were added: Sri Lanka
(from January 15, 2009, to May 19, 2009), with between 3,000 and 20,000 intentional
civilian deaths, and Côte d’Ivoire (from December 1, 2010, to April 11, 2011), with between
1,500 and 3,000 deaths.
195
196 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
between Ulfelder and Valentino’s year ranges for mass killings and
Doyle and Sambanis’ civil-war lengths to calculate an average value for
mass killings per year. We chose Ulfelder and Valentino’s year ranges
because mass killings associated with a civil war could have taken place
prior to the start date coded using Doyle and Sambanis’ procedures.
We then matched the civil wars in Doyle and Sambanis and the mass-
killing incidents in Ulfelder and Valentino based on approximate year
and event type. In cases where a mass-killings record spanned multiple
civil wars, we assumed that the mass killings were even across the civil
wars. As discussed in Chapter Two, Ulfelder and Valentino also rely
on a lower threshold of violence to code a case as an instance of mass
killings. We selected as our break point an average of 2,000 or more
intentional killings of civilians for each year of the civil war, with the
number of such killings determined by the average of Ulfelder and
Valentino’s high-end and low-end estimates. Ulfelder and Valentino’s
data were collected for the period from 1945 to 2006; if a civil war
was either ongoing or continued after 2006, we used 2006 as the latest
year in the mass-killings calculation.2 In cases where a mass-killings
incident was not reported for a country during the period of a civil war
(as determined using start and end dates from Doyle and Sambanis’
dataset), the civil war was coded as a case of no indiscriminate violence
by government forces.
Independent Variables
Government Effectiveness
The government effectiveness variable from the World Bank’s WGI
provided one of our two indicators of state capacity. According to the
WGI source document, “Government Effectiveness captures percep-
tions of the quality of public services, the quality of the civil service
and the degree of its independence from political pressures, the quality
of policy formulation and implementation, and the credibility of the
2 The exception is Sri Lanka, 2003–2009, for which we had updated data.
Coding Notes 197
State Reach
Our second indicator of state capacity is Holtermann’s state-reach vari-
able.4 Data for this variable are available from 1989 to 2006 and are
on a scale of 0 to 1. As with government effectiveness, because of miss-
ing data, we had to use each country’s average values for all years from
1989 to 2006 rather than using only those years in which the country
was affected by insurgency. Countries with average state-reach scores
greater than or equal to the index’s midpoint of 0.5 are considered
to have high state reach, and countries with average state-reach scores
lower than 0.5 are considered to have low state reach.
our break point the midpoint of the Freedom House scale; thus, if the
average Freedom House score over the course of a civil war was less
than or equal to 4, the country was considered to possess high political
inclusivity; if the average Freedom House score was greater than 4, the
country was considered to possess low political inclusivity.
Force-to-Force Ratios
Force-to-force ratios were calculated as the ratio of government to insur-
gent forces. For data on insurgent forces, we used the Peace Research
Institute Oslo (PRIO) Non-State Actors dataset, Version 3.3.6 We cal-
culated the number of rebels per year using the dataset’s best estimate.
If there were multiple insurgent groups in a given country correspond-
ing to the same civil war in the Doyle and Sambanis dataset, we used
the sum of all insurgent groups. Since the PRIO dataset uses conflict
years as its unit of analysis, whereas our study examines conflicts as a
whole, we used the average number of insurgents over the length of
the conflict. Data on government forces were derived from the World
Bank’s WDI. This variable is entitled Armed Forces Personnel, Total
and consists of active duty military personnel, including paramilitary
forces if the training, organization, equipment, and control suggest
they may be used to support or replace regular military forces. The
original source of the data is the International Institute for Strategic
Studies’ The Military Balance. The indicator begins in 1989. If the indi-
cator was not available for a certain country year, it was omitted from
the average. To determine the extent of government military superior-
ity, we took the ratio of the government troop estimate over this period
of time to the rebel estimate, with a 10:1 ratio used as the break point
between countries scoring high and low.
Force-to-Population Ratios
Force-to-population ratios were calculated as the ratio of a country’s
government military forces to its inhabitants. As with force-to-force
6 For details, see David E. Cunningham, Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, and Idean Salehyan,
“Codebook for the Non–State Actor Data,” Peace Research Institute Oslo Centre for the
Study of Civil War, version 3.3, January 24, 2012.
Coding Notes 199
ratios, data on government forces were derived from the World Bank’s
WDI. This variable is entitled Armed Forces Personnel, Total and con-
sists of active duty military personnel, including paramilitary forces if
the training, organization, equipment, and control suggest they may be
used to support or replace regular military forces. The original source of
the data is the International Institute for Strategic Studies’ The Military
Balance. The indicator begins in 1989. If the indicator was not avail-
able for a certain country year, it was omitted from the average. Data
on countries’ total populations were also found in the WDI. Using
this ratio, we created two binary variables based on two different break
points: average force-to-population ratios of 5:1,000 and 10:1,000. We
used both break points in separate cross-tabulations of the relationship
between military superiority and the outcomes of interest.
Bibliography
201
202 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Averch, Harvey, and John Koehler, The Huk Rebellion in the Philippines:
Quantitative Approaches, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, RM-6254,
1970. As of December 9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/research_memoranda/RM6254.html
Aziz, Sartaj, “The Economic Cost of Extremism,” in Usama Butt and N. Elahi,
eds., Pakistan’s Quagmire: Security, Strategy, and the Future of the Islamic-Nuclear
Nation, London: Continuum International, 2010, pp. 75–92.
Bacevitch, A. J., James D. Hallums, Richard H. White, and Thomas F. Young,
American Military Policy in Small Wars: The Case of El Salvador, Institute for
Foreign Policy Analysis, Washington, D.C.: Pergamon-Brassey’s, 1988.
Baker, Bruce, “Policing Post-Conflict Societies: Helping Out the State,” Policing
and Society, Vol. 19, No. 4, 2009, pp. 329–332.
Bakke, Kristin M., and Erik Wibbels, “Diversity, Disparity, and Civil Conflict in
Federal States,” World Politics, Vol. 59, October 2006, pp. 1–50.
Banlaoi, Rommel C., “The Sources of the Abu Sayyaf’s Resilience in the Southern
Philippines,” CTC Sentinel, Vol. 3, No. 5, May 2010, pp. 17–19.
Bansal, Alok, “Factors Leading to Insurgency in Balochistan,” Small Wars &
Insurgencies, Vol. 19, No. 2, June 2008, pp. 182–200.
Bashir, Riaz Anwar, Shahzad Ahmad Qasmi, Muhammad Yasin, and Sahibzada
Nasir Mansoor, “Pattern of Combat Casualties in War Against Terror Among
Soldiers Wearing Body Armor at CMH Peshawar,” Pakistan Armed Forces Medical
Journal, No. 2, June 2012.
Bates, Robert H., Prosperity and Violence: The Political Economy of Development,
New York: W. W. Norton, 2001.
Bello, Walden, “Edging Toward the Quagmire: The United States and the
Philippine Crisis,” World Policy Journal, Vol. 3, No. 1, Winter 1985–1986, p. 31.
Bennett, Huw, “The Reluctant Pupil? Britain’s Army and Learning in Counter-
Insurgency,” Royal United Services Institute, 2009. As of November 5, 2009:
http://www.rusi.org/analysis/commentary/ref%3AC4AD22F8DF284C/#.
UulGg2RDtOE
Berman, Eli, Jacob N. Shapiro, and Joseph H. Felter, “Can Hearts and Minds
Be Bought? The Economics of Counterinsurgency in Iraq,” Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 119, No. 4, August 2011, pp. 766–819.
Birdsall, Nancy, “Risking the Dog for the Tail,” Newsweek, February 28, 2011.
Birdsall, Nancy, Wren Elhai, and Molly Kinder, Beyond Bullets and Bombs: Fixing
the U.S. Approach to Development in Pakistan, Washington, D.C.: Center for
Global Development, June 2011, p. 14.
Blaufarb, Douglas S., The Counterinsurgency Era: U.S. Doctrine and Performance,
1950 to the Present, New York: The Free Press, 1977.
204 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Blitz, James, James Lamont, and Farhan Bokhari, “Swat Outlook ‘Pretty Bleak’
for Pakistan,” Financial Times, May 13, 2009.
Blunt, Peter, and Mark Turner, “Decentralization, Democracy, and Development
in a Post-Conflict Society: Commune Councils in Cambodia,” Public
Administration and Development, Vol. 25, 2005, pp. 84–85.
Bonner, Raymond, Waltzing with a Dictator: The Marcoses and the Making of
Foreign Policy, New York: New York Times Books, 1987, pp. 204–225.
Boot, Max, and Richard Bennett, “Treading Softly in the Philippines,” The Weekly
Standard, Vol. 14, No. 16, January 5–12, 2009.
Briscoe, Carolyn H., “Balikatan Exercise Spearheaded ARSOF Operations in the
Philippines,” Special Warfare, Vol. 17, No. 1, September 2004, p. 16.
Brulliard, Nicolas, “Pakistan Textile Exports: Call for Wider Lifting of U.S.
Tariffs Intensifies,” Washington Post, December 24, 2010.
Byman, Daniel L., “Friends Like These: Counterinsurgency and the War on
Terrorism,” International Security, Vol. 31, No. 2, Fall 2006, pp. 79–115.
Caouette, Dominique, Persevering Revolutionaries: Armed Struggle in the 21st
Century, Exploring the Revolution of the Communist Party of the Philippines,
dissertation, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University, 2004, pp. 483, 488.
Caringal, Sharon Advincula, “The Impact of U.S. Military Assistance on the
Communist and Secessionist Conundrum in the Philippines,” International
Journal of Arts and Sciences, Vol. 3, No. 15, 2010, p. 437.
Carothers, Thomas, In the Name of Democracy: U.S. Policy Toward Latin America
in the Reagan Years, Berkeley, Calif.: University of California Press, 1993, esp.
Chap. 1.
Carothers, Thomas, and Diane de Gramont, Development Aid Confronts Politics:
The Almost Revolution, Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace, 2013.
Center for Research and Security Studies, Balochistan’s Maze of Violence,
Islamabad, Pakistan, 2011.
Chapman, William, Inside the Philippine Revolution: The New People’s Army and Its
Struggle for Power, 1st ed., New York: W. W. Norton, 1987.
Cheema, Pervaiz Iqbal, “Challenges Facing a Counter-Militant Campaign in
Pakistan’s FATA,” National Bureau of Asian Research, NBR Analysis, Vol. 19,
No. 3, August 2008, pp. 21–29.
Clapham, Christopher, “The Global-Local Politics of State Decay,” in Robert I.
Rotberg, ed., When States Fail: Causes and Consequences, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press, 2004.
Bibliography 205
Cloughley, Brian, War, Coups, and Terror: Pakistan’s Army in Years of Turmoil,
New York: Skyhorse, 2008.
———, “Insurrection, Terrorism and the Pakistan Army,” in Usama Butt and
N. Elahi, eds., Pakistan’s Quagmire: Security, Strategy, and the Future of the Islamic-
Nuclear Nation, London: Continuum International, 2010, pp. 93–122.
Cohen, Stephen P., The Idea of Pakistan, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution
Press, 2004.
Cohen, Craig, and Derek Chollet, “When $10 Billion Is Not Enough: Rethinking
U.S. Strategy Toward Pakistan,” Washington Quarterly, Vol. 30, No. 2, 2007,
p. 12.
Cohen, Eliot, “To COIN or Not?” transcript from a roundtable discussion
co-sponsored by Foreign Policy and the RAND Corporation, March 18, 2013.
Cohen, Stephen, The Pakistan Army, Berkeley, Calif.: University of California
Press, 1984.
Colaresi, Michael, and Sabine C. Carey, “To Kill or to Protect: Security Forces,
Domestic Institutions, and Genocide,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 52,
No. 1, February 2008, pp. 39–67.
Collier, Paul, “Is Aid Oil? An Analysis of Whether Africa Can Absorb More Aid,”
World Development, Vol. 34, No. 9, 2006, pp. 1482–1497.
Collier, Paul, V. L. Elliott, Havard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol,
and Nicholas Sambanis, Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Policy
Development, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank and Oxford University Press,
2003, Chap. 1.
Connable, Ben, and Martin C. Libicki, How Insurgencies End, Santa Monica,
Calif.: RAND Corporation, MG-965-MCIA, 2010, pp. 186–187. As of December
9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG965.html
Correlates of War Project, “National Material Capabilities Data (v. 4.0),” June
2010. As of July 1, 2013:
http://www.correlatesofwar.org/COW2%20Data/Capabilities/NMC_v4_0.csv
Cunningham, David E., Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, and Idean Salehyan,
“Codebook for the Non–State Actor Data,” Peace Research Institute Oslo Centre
for the Study of Civil War, version 3.3, January 24, 2012. As of August 14, 2013:
http://privatewww.essex.ac.uk/~ksg/data/NSAEX_codebook.pdf
Dahl, Robert A., Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition, New Haven, Conn.: Yale
University Press, 1972.
Davenport, Christian, State Repression and the Domestic Democratic Peace, New
York: Cambridge University Press, 2007a.
206 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
———, “State Repression and Political Order,” Annual Review of Political Science,
Vol. 10, 2007b, pp. 1–23.
De Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, George W. Downs, Alastair Smith, and Feryal Marie
Cherif, “Thinking Inside the Box: A Closer Look at Democracy and Human
Rights,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 49, 2005, pp. 439–457.
De Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, and Alastair Smith, “Leader Survival, Revolutions,
and the Nature of Government Finance,” American Journal of Political Science,
Vol. 54, No. 4, October 2010, pp. 936–950.
Devesa, Roy T., An Assessment of the Philippine Counterinsurgency Operational
Methodology, master’s thesis, Fort Leavenworth, Kans.: U.S. Army Command and
General Staff College, 2005, pp. 40–41.
D’Exelle, Ben, “Excluded Again: Village Politics at the Aid Interface,” Journal of
Development Studies, Vol. 45, No. 9, October 2009, pp. 1453–1471.
Dixon, Paul, “‘Hearts and Minds’? British Counter-Insurgency from Malaya to
Iraq,” Journal of Strategic Studies, Vol. 32, No. 3, 2009, pp. 353–381.
Doran, Michael Scott, “Somebody Else’s Civil War,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 81,
No. 1, January-February 2002, pp. 22–42.
Downes, Alexander B., “Desperate Times, Desperate Measures: The Causes of
Civilian Victimization in War,” International Security, Vol. 30, No. 4, Spring
2006, pp. 152–195.
Downs, George W., “The Lessons of Disengagement,” in Ariel E. Levite,
Bruce W. Jentleson, and Larry Berman, eds., Foreign Military Intervention: The
Dynamics of Protracted Conflict, New York: Columbia University Press, 1992.
Doyle, Michael W., and Nicholas Sambanis, Making War and Building Peace,
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2006.
Dreher, Axel, Jan-Egbert Sturm, and James Raymond Vreeland, “Development
Aid and International Politics: Does Membership on the UN Security Council
Influence World Bank Decisions?” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 88,
No. 1, 2009, pp. 1–18.
———, “Global Horse Trading: IMF Loans for Votes in the United Nations
Security Council,” European Economic Review, Vol. 53, No. 7, 2009, pp. 742–757.
Duparcq, Emmanuel, “Swat Rebuilds Year After Pakistan Floods,” Agence France
Presse, July 24, 2011.
Eck, Kristine, and Lisa Hultman, “One-Sided Violence Against Civilians in War:
Insights from New Fatality Data,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 44, No. 2, 2007,
pp. 233–246.
Bibliography 207
Englebert, Pierre, and James Ron, “Primary Commodities and War: Congo-
Brazzaville’s Ambivalent Resource Curse,” Comparative Politics, Vol. 37, No. 1,
October 2004, pp. 61–81.
Englebert, Pierre, and Denis M. Tull, “Postconflict Reconstruction in Africa:
Flawed Ideas About Failed States,” International Security, Vol. 32, No. 4, 2008,
pp. 106–139.
Epstein, Susan B., and K. Alan Kronstadt, Pakistan: U.S. Foreign Assistance,
Washington, D.C.: Congressional Research Service, R41856, October 4, 2012.
Esperon, Hermogenes C., Jr., “Perspective from the Military,” Digest: A Forum for
Security and Defense Issues, Office of Strategic and Special Studies, Armed Forces of
the Philippines, 2006, p. 5.
Fair, Christine, “Pakistan Loses Swat to Local Taliban,” Terrorism Focus, Vol. 4,
No. 37, November 13, 2007.
Fair, C. Christine, and Seth G. Jones, “Pakistan’s War Within,” Survival, Vol. 51,
No. 6, December 2009–January 2010.
Fanthorpe, Richard, “On the Limits of Liberal Peace: Chiefs and Democratic
Decentralization in Post-War Sierra Leone,” African Affairs, Vol. 105, No. 418,
2006, p. 40.
Farris, Stuart, Joint Special Operations Task Force–Philippines, Fort Leavenworth,
Kans.: U.S. Army Command and General Staff College, School of Advanced
Military Studies, 2009, pp. 22–23.
Fearon, James D., “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of
International Disputes,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 88, No. 3,
September 1994, pp. 577–592.
———, “Rationalist Explanations for War,” International Organization, Vol. 49,
No. 3, Summer 1995, pp. 379–414.
———, “Why Do Some Civil Wars Last So Much Longer than Others?” Journal
of Peace Research, Vol. 41, No. 3, 2004, pp. 275–301.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin, “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War,”
American Political Science Review, Vol. 97, No. 1, February 2003.
Feldman, Daniel F., “Testimony Before the House Foreign Affairs Committee,
Subcommittee on the Middle East and South Asia,” transcript, April 5, 2011. As
of August 21, 2013:
http://archives.republicans.foreignaffairs.house.gov/112/fel040511.pdf
Felter, Joseph H., Taking Guns to a Knife Fight: Effective Military Support to COIN,
Carlisle, Pa.: U.S. Army War College, 2008, pp. 9–10.
Fielding, David, and Anja Shortland, “The Dynamics of Terror During the
Peruvian Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 49, No. 6, 2012, pp. 847–862.
208 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Fontaine, Roger W., “The Philippines: After Aquino,” Asian Affairs: An American
Review, Vol. 19, No. 3, Fall 1992, pp. 171–172.
Fortna, Virginia Page, “Scraps of Paper? Agreements and the Durability of Peace,”
International Organization, Vol. 57, No. 2, Spring 2003, pp. 337–372.
———, Does Peacekeeping Work? Shaping Belligerents’ Choices After Civil War,
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2008.
Freedom House, Freedom in the World, Washington, D.C., 2013. As of June 25,
2013:
http://www.freedomhouse.org/report-types/freedom-world
Freier, Nathan, “The New Theology: Building Partner Capacity,” Small Wars
Journal, May 27, 2010.
Fritz, Verena Fritz, Kai Kaiser, and Brian Levy, Problem-Driven Governance and
Political Economy Analysis, Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2009.
Fund for Peace, “Failed States Index, 2005–2013,” web site. As of August 8, 2013:
http://www.global.fundforpeace.org/index.php
Galula, David, Counterinsurgency Warfare: Theory and Practice, Westport, Conn.:
Praeger Security International, 2006 [1964].
Gandhi, Rohit, “Deradicalization: A Tall Order,” Asia Pacific Defense Forum,
July 1, 2012.
Gelb, Alan, and Caroline Decker, “Direct Payments to Pakistan’s Flood Victims:
A Smart Option for U.S. Assistance,” The Hill, November 8, 2010.
Gelb, Leslie H., and Richard K. Betts, The Irony of Vietnam: The System Worked,
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1979.
Gettleman, Jeffrey, Mark Mazzetti, and Eric Schmitt, “U.S. Relies on Contractors
in Somalia Conflict,” New York Times, August 10, 2011, p. A1.
Ghaus, A. F. Aisha, Hafiz A. Pasha, and Rafia Ghaus, “Social Development
Ranking of Districts of Pakistan,” The Pakistan Development Review,” Vol. 35,
No. 4 (Part II), Winter 1996, pp. 593–614.
Gilani, Ijaz, Voice of the People: Public Opinion in Pakistan, 2007–2008, Karachi,
Pakistan: Oxford University Press, 2010.
Gilani Research Foundation, Perceptions on Kerry-Lugar Bill: Gilani Poll/Gallup
Pakistan, Islamabad, October, 14, 2009.
Gishkori, Zahid, “Violence Is on the Rise in Balochistan: Report,” Express Tribune,
January 3, 2013.
Global Firepower, “Countries Ranked by Military Strength (2013),” GFP Power
Index, web site, 2006–2013. As of August 8, 2013:
http://www.globalfirepower.com/countries-listing.asp
Bibliography 209
Kilcullen, David J., The Accidental Guerrilla: Fighting Small Wars in the Midst of a
Big One, New York: Oxford University Press, 2009.
———, Terrain, Tribes, and Terrorists: Pakistan, 2006–2008, Washington,
D.C.: Brookings Institution, Counterinsurgency and Pakistan Paper Series No. 3,
September 10, 2009, pp. 10–12.
King, Gary, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba, Designing Social Inquiry:
Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press, 1994.
Kline, William E., The Fall of Marcos: A Problem in U.S. Foreign Policymaking,
Washington, D.C.: Institute for the Study of Diplomacy, Georgetown University
School of Foreign Service, 1992, pp. 18–19.
Kocher, Matthew Adam, Thomas B. Pepinsky, and Stathis N. Kalyvas, “Aerial
Bombing and Counterinsurgency in the Vietnam War,” American Journal of
Political Science, Vol. 55, No. 2, April 2011, pp. 201–218.
Krasner, Stephen, “Talking Tough to Pakistan,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 91, No. 1,
January–February 2012, pp. 87–96.
Kundi, Mansoor Akbar, “Insurgency Factors in Balochistan,” The Nation,
October 20, 2004.
Kurtzleben, Danielle, “Pakistan: U.S. to Aid Civilians Fleeing Embattled Swat
Valley,” Inter Press Service, May 19, 2009.
Lacina, Bethany, and Nils Petter Gleditsch, “Monitoring Trends in Global
Combat: A New Dataset of Battle Deaths,” European Journal of Population,
Vol. 21, Nos. 2–3, 2005, pp. 145–166.
Laitin, David D., and Drew A. Harker, “Military Rule and National Secession:
Nigeria and Ethiopia,” in Morris Janowitz, ed., Civil-Military Relations: Regional
Perspectives, Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1981.
Lalwani, Sameer, Pakistani Military Capabilities for a Counterinsurgency Campaign:
A Net Assessment, Washington, D.C.: New America Foundation, Counterterrorism
Strategy Initiative Publication, September 2009, pp. 41–46.
———, “Pakistan’s Counterinsurgency Strategy,” in Peter Bergen and Katherine
Tiedemann, eds., Talibanistan: Negotiating the Borders Between Terror, Politics, and
Religion, New York: Oxford University Press, 2013, pp. 202–228.
Lambert, Geoffrey, Larry Lewis, and Sarah Sewall, “Operation Enduring
Freedom–Philippines: Civilian Harm and the Indirect Approach,” Prism,
Vol. 3, No. 4, September 2012, pp. 117–135.
Le Billon, Philippe, “Buying Peace or Fueling War: The Role of Corruption in
Armed Conflicts,” Journal of International Development, Vol. 15, 2003, p. 420.
216 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Leites, Nathan, and Charles Wolf, Jr., Rebellion and Authority, Chicago: Markham
Publishing Company, 1970.
Le Sage, Andre, “Africa’s Irregular Security Threats: Challenges for U.S.
Engagement,” Strategic Forum, No. 255, May 2010, p. 8.
Levi, Margaret, Of Rule and Revenue, Berkeley, Calif.: University of California
Press, 1988.
Levite, Ariel E., Bruce W. Jentleson, and Larry Berman, eds., Foreign Military
Intervention: The Dynamics of Protracted Conflict, New York: Columbia University
Press, 1992.
Lieven, Anatol, Pakistan: A Hard Country, London: Allen Lane, 2011.
Lum, Thomas, The Republic of the Philippines and U.S. Interests, Washington, D.C.:
Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress, April 2012, p. 14.
Lyall, Jason, “Does Indiscriminate Violence Incite Insurgent Attacks? Evidence
from Chechnya,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 53, No. 3, June 2009,
pp. 331–362.
———, “Are Coethnics More Effective Counterinsurgents? Evidence from
the Second Chechen War,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 104, No. 1,
February 2010a, pp. 1–20.
———, “Do Democracies Make Inferior Counterinsurgents? Reassessing
Democracy’s Impact on War Outcomes and Duration,” International
Organization, Vol. 64, Winter 2010b, pp. 167–92.
Maher, Aijaz, “Pakistan’s Army Steps Up Radio Wars,” BBC News, August 14,
2012. As of August 22, 2013:
http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-asia-18766713
Mahsud, Mansur Khan, “The Taliban in South Waziristan,” in Peter Bergen and
Katherine Tiedemann, eds., Talibanistan: Negotiating the Borders Between Terror,
Politics, and Religion, New York: Oxford University Press, 2013, pp. 164–201.
Markey, Daniel S., Securing Pakistan’s Tribal Belt, Washington, D.C.: Council on
Foreign Relations, Council Special Report No. 36, August 2008.
———, No Exit from Pakistan: America’s Tortured Relationship with Islamabad,
New York: Cambridge University Press, 2013, pp. 113, 127.
Mason, T. David, and Dale A. Krane, “The Political Economy of Death Squads:
Toward a Theory of the Impact of State-Sanctioned Terror,” International Studies
Quarterly, Vol. 33, No. 2, June 1989, pp. 175–198.
Matthew, Jennie, “Report Unmasks Tax Evasion Among Pakistan Leaders,”
Agence France Presse, December 12, 2012. As of August 22, 2013:
http://www.google.com/hostednews/afp/article/ALeqM5hrQ4phi5cnJlb9g0_0pQ
YLGiDZwQ?docId=CNG.1f5230b87c34eb7ef95150ba96d4cfb3.131
Bibliography 217
Nawaz, Amna, and Waj S. Khan, “A Rare Glimpse Inside Pakistan’s Ground Zero
for Terrorists,” NBC News, March 4, 2013. As of August 22, 2013:
http://worldnews.nbcnews.com/_news/2013/03/04/17177391-a-rare-glimpse-
inside-pakistans-ground-zero-for-terrorists?lite
Nawaz, Shuja, Crossed Swords: Pakistan, Its Army, and the Wars Within, Karachi,
Pakistan: Oxford University Press, 2008, p. 570.
———, FATA—A Most Dangerous Place: Meeting the Challenge of Militancy and
Terror in the Federally Administered Tribal Areas of Pakistan, Washington, D.C.:
Center for Strategic and International Studies Press, January 2009a.
———, “Pakistan’s Summer of Chaos,” Foreign Policy, June 17, 2009b. As of
August 22, 2013:
http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2009/06/16/pakistans_summer_of_chaos
———, Learning by Doing: The Pakistan Army’s Experience with
Counterinsurgency, Washington, D.C.: Atlantic Council, February 2011.
“New People’s Army,” START Terrorist Organization Profiles database, web site,
University of Maryland, College Park, Md., undated. As of July 15, 2013:
http://www.start.umd.edu/start/data_collections/tops/terrorist_organization_
profile.asp?id=203
Nissenbaum, Dion, “In Former Taliban Sanctuary, an Eerie Silence Takes Over,”
Wall Street Journal, January 26, 2013.
Nixon, Richard, “Address to the Nation on the War in Vietnam,” November 3,
1969, P-691101.
“Not Allies: Eight Dead as TTP, Haqqani Network Clash in North Waziristan,”
Express Tribune, April 19, 2012.
OECD Development Assistance Committee, Handbook on Security Sector Reform,
Paris: OECD, 2007.
Office of the Deputy Chief for Intelligence, J2, Armed Forces of the Philippines,
AFP-Philippine National Police Year-End Order of Battle Validation Report, Quezon
City, Philippines: AFP General Headquarters, January 2004, Annex IA.
Oppel, Richard A., Jr., and Pir Zubair Shah, “In Pakistan, Radio Amplifies Terror
of Taliban,” New York Times, January 24, 2009.
“PAF Conducted 5,500 Bombing Runs in FATA Since 2008,” Express Tribune,
November 14, 2011.
Page, Jeremy, “Britain to Train Pakistan’s Frontier Corps Troops in Baluchistan,”
The Times, October 9, 2009.
“Pak Troops Seize Swat Peak, Shut ‘Mullah Radio,’” Times of India, November 28,
2007.
Bibliography 219
“Pakistan and the Taliban: A Real Offensive or a Phony War?” The Economist,
April 30, 2009.
“Pakistan Army Strategy in Question After Attacks,” Dawn.com, October 22,
2012.
“Pakistan Has Lowest Tax to GDP Ratio in the World,” The Nation, February 18,
2013. As of August 21, 2013:
http://www.nation.com.pk/pakistan-news-newspaper-daily-english-online/
business/18-Feb-2013/pakistan-has-lowest-tax-to-gdp-ratio-in-world
“Pakistani Authorities Close Three Radio Stations for Pro-Taliban Broadcasts,”
Associated Press, November 1, 2009.
“Pashto-Language TV Station [Khyber TV] Interviews Pakistan’s President
Musharraf,” BBC Monitoring South Asia, May 21, 2006.
Paul, Christopher, Colin P. Clarke, and Beth Grill, Victory Has a Thousand Fathers:
Sources of Success in Counterinsurgency, Santa Monica, Calif: RAND Corporation,
MG-964-OSD, 2010. As of December 9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG964.html
Paul, Christopher, Colin P. Clarke, Beth Grill, and Molly Dunigan, Paths
to Victory: Lessons from Modern Insurgencies, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND
Corporation, RR-291/1-OSD, 2013. As of December 9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/research_reports/RR291z1.html
Paul, T. V., ed., South Asia’s Weak States: Understanding the Regional Insecurity
Predicament, Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2010.
Peceny, Mark, “Two Paths to the Promotion of Democracy During U.S. Military
Interventions,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 39, 1995, pp. 371–401.
Pena, Leonardo I., Finding the Missing Link to a Successful Philippine
Counterinsurgency Strategy, master’s thesis, Monterey, Calif.: Naval Postgraduate
School, 2007, pp. 43–44.
“Performance of the Parliamentary Committee on National Security, March 16,
2012 – March 15, 2013,” Pakistan Institute of Legislative Development and
Transparency, March 2013, p. 13.
Perlez, Jane, “U.S. Aid Plan for Pakistan Is Foundering,” New York Times,
May 1, 2011.
Perlez, Jane, and Helene Cooper, “Signaling Tension, Pakistan Shuts NATO
Route,” New York Times, September 30, 2010.
Petraeus, David H., “Hearing to Receive Testimony on the Situation in
Afghanistan,” transcript, testimony before the Senate Armed Services Committee,
Washington, D.C., March 15, 2011.
220 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Pew Research Center, “On Eve of Elections, a Dismal Public Mood in Pakistan,”
Pew Global Attitudes Project, Washington, D.C., web site, May 7,
2013. As of August 22, 2013: http://www.pewglobal.org/2013/05/07/
on-eve-of-elections-a-dismal-public-mood-in-pakistan/
Philippines National Statistics Office, Census 2000: Philippines, Population and
Housing Characteristics, Manila: Republic of the Philippines, National Statistics
Office, 2003.
Posen, Barry R., The Sources of Military Doctrine: France, Britain, and Germany
Between the World Wars, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1984.
Pritchett, Lant, Michael Woolcock, and Matt Andrews, Capability Traps? The
Mechanisms of Persistent Implementation Failure, Washington, D.C.: Center for
Global Development, Working Paper 234, December 2010.
Quimpo, Nathan Gilbert, The U.S. and the Southern Philippines’ Quagmire,
Murdoch, Western Australia: Asia Research Centre, Murdoch University, July
2007, p. 4.
Quinlivan, James T., “Force Requirements in Stability Operations,” Parameters:
U.S. Army War College Quarterly, Vol. 25, No. 4, Winter 1995-1996, pp. 59–69.
Rabasa, Angel, Steven Boraz, Peter Chalk, Kim Cragin, Theodore W. Karasik,
Jennifer D. P. Moroney, Kevin A. O’Brien, and John E. Peters, Ungoverned
Territories: Understanding and Reducing Terrorism Risks, Santa Monica, Calif:
RAND Corporation, MG-561-AF, 2007. As of December 9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG561.html
Rana, Muhammad Amir, “Swat Deradicalization Model: Prospects for
Rehabilitating Militants,” Conflict and Peace Studies, Vol. 4, No. 2, April–June
2011.
Rashid, Ahmed, Descent into Chaos, London: Penguin Books, 2008.
———, “Pakistan’s Continued Failure to Adopt a Counterinsurgency Strategy,”
CTC Sentinel, Vol. 2, No. 3, March 2009.
———, Pakistan on the Brink: The Future of America, Pakistan, and Afghanistan,
New York: Viking, 2012.
Rasool, Kamran, “Pakistan’s Perspective on the ‘War on Terror,’” Military
Technology, Vol. 32, No. 11, November 2008, p. 17.
Ratner, Ely, “Reaping What You Sow: Democratic Transitions and Foreign Policy
Realignment,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 53, No. 3, June 2009,
pp. 390–418.
Rehman, Ata Ur, “Responsibilities of Pakistan Army in LIC Environment,” in
Pakistan Army Green Book 2002: Low Intensity Conflict, Rawalpindi, Pakistan:
Pakistan Army, 2002, p. 203.
Bibliography 221
Renou, Xavier, “A New French Policy for Africa?” Journal of Contemporary African
Studies, Vol. 20, No. 1, 2002, pp. 5–27.
Republic of the Philippines Commission on Population, “Population Statistics,”
web site, 2013. As of July 5, 2013:
http://www.popcom.gov.ph/popstat.php
Ressa, Maria, Seeds of Terror: An Eyewitness Account of Al-Qaeda’s Newest Center of
Operations in Southeast Asia, New York: Simon and Schuster, 2004.
Ricks, Thomas E., “More Salvadors, Fewer Vietnams,” The Best Defense, February
19, 2013.
Rizvi, Hasan Askari, “Understanding the Insurgency,” Daily Times, October 5,
2008.
Robinson, Linda, “The Future of Special Operations,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 91,
No. 6, November-December 2012.
Rocamora, Joel, “Discontent in the Philippines,” World Policy Journal, Vol. 8,
No. 4, Fall 1991, pp. 636–637.
Rotberg, Robert I., “The Failure and Collapse of Nation-States: Breakdown,
Prevention, and Repair,” in Robert I. Rotberg, ed., When States Fail: Causes and
Consequences, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2004.
Rummel, R. J., “Democracy, Power, Genocide, and Mass Murder,” Journal of
Conflict Resolution, Vol. 39, No. 1, March 1995, pp. 3–26.
Saleem, Ishrat, What Pakistan’s Democratic Future Holds for the United States,
Washington, D.C.: Middle East Institute, May 9, 2013. As of August 8, 2013:
http://www.mei.edu/content/
what-pakistan%E2%80%99s-democratic-future-holds-united-states
Santana, Rebecca, “Pakistan Army Tries to Win Over Local Population in War-
Torn Tribal Region,” Associated Press, April 10, 2013.
Santos, Paz Verdades M., “The Communist Front: Protracted People’s War and
Counter-insurgency in the Philippines (Overview),” in Soliman M. Santos, Jr., and
Paz Verdades M. Santos, eds., Primed and Purposeful: Armed Groups and Human
Security Efforts in the Philippines, Geneva: Small Arms Survey, 2005,
pp. 17–32.
Santos, Soliman, “Evolution of the Armed Conflict on the Communist Front,” in
Philippine Human Development Report 2005: Peace, Human Security and Human
Development in the Philippines, 2nd ed., Quezon City: Human Development
Network Foundation, 2005, pp. 84–89. As of August 21, 2013:
http://www.hdn.org.ph/wp-content/uploads/2005_PHDR/2005%20Evolution_
Communist_Conflict.pdf
222 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Sayah, Reza, “Can the Return of Justice Halt the Taliban?” CNN, November 14,
2009. As of August 22, 2013:
http://www.cnn.com/2009/WORLD/asiapcf/11/14/pakistan.swat.justice/
Scanzillo, Thomas M., and Edward M. Lopacienski, “Influence Warfare: How
the Joint Special Operations Task Force–Philippines Maximizes Effects to Create
Long-Term Stability,” Center for the Study of Irregular Warfare and Armed
Groups, February 2011.
Schmitt, Eric, and Jane Perlez, “U.S. Unit Secretly in Pakistan Lends Ally
Support,” New York Times, February 23, 2009.
Schmitt, Eric, and Thom Shankar, Counterstrike: The Untold Story of America’s
Secret Campaign Against Al Qaeda, New York: Henry Holt, 2011, pp. 198–200.
Schofield, Carey, Inside the Pakistan Army, London: Biteback Publishing, 2011.
Schultz, Kenneth A., Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy, New York: Cambridge
University Press, 2001.
Schwarz, Benjamin C., American Counterinsurgency Doctrine and El Salvador:
The Frustrations of Reform and the Illusions of Nation Building, Santa Monica,
Calif.: RAND Corporation, R-4042-USDP, 1991. As of December 8, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/reports/R4042.html
Seymour, Kristen, “De-radicalisation: Psychologists’ War Against Militants,”
Express Tribune, July 17, 2011.
Shafer, D. Michael, Deadly Paradigms: The Failure of U.S. Counterinsurgency Policy,
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988.
Shah, Saeed, “Why Pakistan Supports the Haqqani Network: Fear for Its Own
Security,” McClatchy News, September 28, 2011.
———, “In Remote Baluchistan, Pakistan Fights Shadowy War,” McClatchy
News, March 29, 2012.
———, “In Historic First, Pakistan’s Civilian Government Completes Its Term
Without a Coup,” McClatchy News, March 16, 2013.
Shah, Tayyab Ali, “Pakistan’s Challenges in Orakzai Agency,” CTC Sentinel,
Vol. 3, No. 7, July 2010.
Shahzad, Khurram, “What Ails Balochistan?” The Nation, February 14, 2005.
Shahzad, Syed Saleem, Inside Al-Qaeda and the Taliban: Beyond Bin Laden and
9/11, London: Pluto Press, 2011.
Shane, Scott, “Insurgents Share a Name, but Pursue Different Goals,” The New
York Times, October 23, 2009.
Sheehan, Michael A., Crush the Cell: How to Defeat Terrorism Without Defeating
Ourselves, New York: Random House, 2009, pp. 123.
Bibliography 223
Walter, Barbara F., “The Critical Barrier to Civil War Settlement,” International
Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3, Summer 1997.
———, Committing to Peace: The Successful Settlement of Civil Wars, Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2001.
Warraich, Omar, “Refugees Head Home After Army Scatters the Taliban,” The
Independent, August 3, 2009.
———, “Two Cheers for Pakistani Democracy: A Sobering Milestone,” Time,
March 18, 2013. As of August 21, 2013:
http://world.time.com/2013/03/18/
two-cheers-for-pakistani-democracy-a-sobering-milestone/
Watts, Stephen, “Political Dilemmas of Stabilization and Reconstruction,” in
Paul K. Davis, ed., Dilemmas of Intervention: Social Science for Stabilization and
Reconstruction, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, MG-1119-OSD, 2011.
As of December 9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG1119.html
Watts, Stephen, Caroline Baxter, Molly Dunigan, and Christopher Rizzi, The Uses
and Limits of Small-Scale Military Interventions, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND
Corporation, MG-1226-RC, 2012. As of December 9, 2013:
http://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG1226.html
“We Only Receive Back the Bodies,” The Economist, April 7, 2012.
Weinbaum, Marvin G., “Hard Choices in Countering Insurgency and Terrorism
Along Pakistan’s North-West Frontier,” Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 63,
No. 1, Fall/Winter 2009, p. 75.
West, Harry G., and Scott Kloeck-Jenson, “Betwixt and Between: ‘Traditional
Authority’ and Democratic Decentralization in Post-War Mozambique,” African
Affairs, Vol. 98, No. 393, 1999, pp. 455–484.
White, Joshua T., and Shuja Ali Malik, Governance Reforms in Pakistan’s Tribal
Areas: The Long Road to Nowhere? Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of
Peace, Peace Brief No. 135, October 15, 2012, p. 4.
Wilson, Gregory, “Anatomy of a Successful COIN Operation: OEF-Philippines
and the Indirect Approach,” Military Review, November-December 2006,
pp. 2–12.
Wirsing, Robert G., Baloch Nationalism and the Geopolitics of Energy Resources:
The Changing Context of Separatism in Pakistan, Carlisle, Pa.: Strategic Studies
Institute, April 2008.
Wisler, Dominique, and Ihekwoaba D. Onwudiwe, “Community Policing in
Comparison,” Police Quarterly, Vol. 11, No. 4, pp. 427–446.
Wolfowitz, Paul, and Michael O’Hanlon, “Plan Afghanistan,” Foreign Policy,
October 28, 2011.
226 Countering Others’ Insurgencies
Wood, Reed M., Jacob D. Kathman, and Stephen E. Gent, “Armed Intervention
and Civilian Victimization in Intrastate Conflicts,” Journal of Peace Research,
Vol. 49, No. 5, 2012, pp. 647–660.
The World Bank, Fragile States: Good Practice in Country Assistance Strategies,
Washington, D.C., 2005, p. 3.
———, World Development Indicators (WDI) dataset. As of March 11, 2013:
http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators
Yong, Tan Tai, The Garrison State: The Military, Government and Society in
Colonial Punjab, 1849–1947, New Delhi, India: Sage Publications, 2005.
Youssef, Nancy A., “Pentagon Rethinking Value of Major Counterinsurgencies,”
McClatchy News, May 12, 2010.
Yusufzai, Rahimullah, “Fallen City,” Newsline Magazine, January 3, 2009.
———, “Fazlullah in Afghanistan,” The News, December 1, 2012.
Zafar, Mohammad, “Balochistan Conundrum: Hearings Spotlight ‘Crumbling’
Khuzdar Situation,” Express Tribune, October 11, 2012.
———, “Stabilising Balochistan: Government to Talk to Insurgent Groups After
Eid, Says CM,” Express Tribune, July 30, 2013.
Zahra-Malik, Mehreen, “Pakistan Army Battles Legacy of Mistrust in Taliban
Heartland,” Reuters, February 3, 2013.
Zaidi, Mosharraf, “Demystifying Foreign Aid,” The International News, December
15, 2010.
Zanger, Sabine C., “A Global Analysis of the Effect of Political Regime Changes
on Life Integrity Violations, 1977–93,” Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 37, No. 2,
2000, pp. 213–233.
Zubair, Muhammad, “Army Operation in South Waziristan: The TTP and IDPs,”
Daily Times, June 19, 2012.
This study examines the counterinsurgency strategies and practices adopted
by threatened regimes and the conditions under which U.S. “small-footprint”
partnerships are likely to help these governments succeed. The report’s findings
are derived from a mixed-method research design incorporating both quantitative
and qualitative analysis. Simple statistical analyses are applied to a dataset
of counterinsurgencies that have terminated since the end of the Cold War
(72 in all), and more in-depth analyses are provided of two recent cases of
U.S. partnerships with counterinsurgent regimes, in the Philippines and Pakistan.
The quantitative analysis finds that the cases of small-footprint U.S. operations that
are commonly touted as “success stories” all occurred in countries approximating
a best-case scenario. Only one insurgency in eight occurred in such best-case
countries; the sizable majority have taken place in worst-case conditions. In these
worst-case environments, counterinsurgent regimes are typically unsuccessful in
their efforts to suppress or contain rebellion, and they often employ violence
indiscriminately. The case studies of the Philippines and Pakistan largely reinforce
the findings of the quantitative analysis. They also highlight the challenges
the United States faces in attempting to influence partner regimes to fight
counterinsurgencies in the manner that the United States would prefer. The study
concludes with policy recommendations for managing troubled partnerships.
www.rand.org $37.95
RR-513-SRF