Derman Lectures Summary
Derman Lectures Summary
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 2 of 30
Black-Scholes
S&P 1995
Black-Scholes implied volatilities for equity indices: ( S, t, K, T ) Term structure of strike and expiration, which change with time and market level Always a negative slope w.r.t strike for equity index options What model replaces Black-Scholes?
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 3 of 30
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 4 of 30
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 5 of 30
TO
RE
EXHIBIT 5
PR
0.4 0.2
GA
0
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8
Corr(c0,c1)
IT
IS
IL
LE
0.5
1.5
2.5
3.5
4.5
0.5
1.5
2.5
3.5
4.5
Maturity in Years
Maturity in Years
Lines denote the cross-correlation estimates between the volatility level proxy (c0) and the volatility smirk slope proxy (c1). The left panel measures the correlation based on daily estimates, the right panel measures the correlation based on daily changes of the estimates.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 6 of 30
Short-term implied volatilities are more volatile. This suggests mean reversion or stationarity for the instantaneous volatility of the index.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 7 of 30
Other Markets
VOD Imp Vol (12/27/01)
70% 60% Imp Vol 50% 40% 30% 0.5 0.75 1 Strike/Spot 1.25 1.5 1 Mon 3 Mon 6 Mon 12 Mon
USD/EUR
MXN/USD
JPY/USD
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 8 of 30
Eq.1.1
For a typical move S 10 S&P points the hedging error = 0.8 points
1 S 1 S The P&L earned from perfect hedging is -------- -------------- -------- -------- ( 50 ) = 0.25 points , 2 2 200 S T
which is dwarfed by the error.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 9 of 30
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 10 of 30
Behavioral Causes Crash protection/ Fear of crashes) [Katrina] Out-o- money puts rise relative to at-the-money; so do realized volatilities Expectation of changes in volatility over time Support/resistance levels at various strikes Dealers books tend to be filled by the demand for zero-cost collars
Structural Causes: Violations of Black-Scholes assumptions Inability to hedge continuously Transactions costs Local volatility ( S, t ) ; leverage effect; CEV models Stochastic volatility Jumps/crashes
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 11 of 30
A model is only a model: capture the important features, not all of them.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 12 of 30
The best way to handle valuation in the presence of a smile is to use no model at all. For terminal payoffs:
Any of these payoffs can be exactly duplicated by a linear combination of forwards, bonds, puts and calls with a range of strikes, and hence exactly replicated at a cost known if we know the volatility smile. Replication will hold irrespective of jumps, volatility, etc. -- only problem is counterparty risk. Try to do approximately the same for other exotic options.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 13 of 30
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 14 of 30
S=K
1 -- ( S ) 2 S=K
Local volatilities predict \ the change of implied volatility with stock price, and that local volatility varies twice as fast with spot as implied volatility varies with strike.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 15 of 30
( S, K )
( 80, 100 ) ( 100, 80 )
( 100, 100 )
S = 80 S = 100 K
80
100
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 16 of 30
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 17 of 30
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 18 of 30
p ( S, t, K, T ) = e
r(T t)
2 2
(C ( S, t, K, T ))
K
We can go further than this, and actually find the local volatility ( S, t ) from market prices of options. For zero interest rates and dividends, the local volatility at S T = K can be determined from the derivatives of option prices:
C ( S, t, K, T ) T ( K, T ) --------------------- = -----------------------------------2 2 2 C K 2 K
2
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 19 of 30
Implied and Local Vols at 1 years 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05
spot or strike
60 80 100 120 140
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 20 of 30
Local Volatility
In practice, we dont have a continuous implied volatility surface so we cannot use these relations blindly. Needs more sophisticated methods. Nice approximate harmonic average relation for short expirations due to Roger Lee:
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 21 of 30
Can replicate only if you can trade volatility/options as well as stock. Option prices are risk-neutral, volatility is not -- need market price of risk for volatility. You must hedge with stock and options - difficult! Can one really know the stochastic PDE for volatility? A tall order. (Rebonato). Correlation is even more stochastic than volatility.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 22 of 30
1 C SV = -- [ C BS ( S, K, H ) + C BS ( S, K, L ) ] 2
H L
K C SV = Sf --- SC BS ( S, K, ) S
So
K = g --- S
at the money S K
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 23 of 30
( S, K )
( 100, 80 ) ( 100, 100 ) ( 80, 80 )
S = 100 S = 80 120 K
80
100
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 24 of 30
= ( m )dt + dW r
Su,u Su,d
Heston, etc.
S,
Sd,u Sd,d
V V V 1 V 2 2 1 V 2 V + -qS + rS + ( S, , t ) rV = 0 S + -q + 2 2 S S t 2 S2
Risk neutrality: volatility drift or market price of risk is determined by options prices being riskneutral.
Stanford.Smile.fm October 21, 2006
Page 25 of 30
V =
p ( T ) B S ( S, K, r, T, T )
T
H L
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 26 of 30
=0
Local volatility is the average of all stochastic volatilities at a definite future stock price and time.
strike
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 27 of 30
Jump-Diffusion Models
In fact, not only is volatility stochastic, but more seriously, stock prices move discontinuously. Geometric Brownian motion isnt the right description. Merton: Poisson distribution of unhedgeable but diversifiable jumps.
S+J
S 1- SK
BS
BS
C JD
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 28 of 30
Jump-Diffusion Smiles
Steep realistic short-term smiles from the instantaneous jump.
0.29
0.285 0.28 0.275 0.27 0.265 0.26 0.255 0.25 0.245 0.24 0.235 "0.1" "0.4" "100"
-0.1 -0.1 0 0.05 0.1 Stochastic volatility, in contrast, has difficulty ln(K/S) producing a steep short-term smile because the volatility diffuses, and therefore doesnt change too much initially. The smiles in a stochastic volatility model are more pronounced at longer expirations.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 29 of 30
Practitioners think of options models as interpolating formulas that take you from known prices of liquid securities to the unknown values of illiquid securities: options; convertible bonds.
An exotic option is a mixture of ordinary options. Find a static hedge composed of a portfolio of vanilla options that approximately replicates the payoff or the vega of the exotic options. Then figure out the value of the portfolio of vanilla options in a skewed world.
Stanford.Smile.fm
Page 30 of 30
Summary
There is no right model. The best you can do is pick a model that mimics the most important behavior of the underlyer in your market. Then add perturbations if necessary. Examine the value of an option in a variety of plausible models. Try to be as model independent as possible. There is lots of work to be done on modeling realistic distributions and the options prices they imply.
Stanford.Smile.fm