From The Soviet Bloc To The European Union The Economic and Social Transformation of Central and Eastern Europe Since 1973 Ivan T Berend Download
From The Soviet Bloc To The European Union The Economic and Social Transformation of Central and Eastern Europe Since 1973 Ivan T Berend Download
https://ebookbell.com/product/communist-propaganda-at-school-the-
world-of-the-reading-primers-from-the-soviet-bloc-19491989-joanna-
wojdon-29522520
Voices From The Soviet Edge Southern Migrants In Leningrad And Moscow
Jeff Sahadeo
https://ebookbell.com/product/voices-from-the-soviet-edge-southern-
migrants-in-leningrad-and-moscow-jeff-sahadeo-51933924
Voices From The Soviet Edge Southern Migrants In Leningrad And Moscow
Jeff Sahadeo
https://ebookbell.com/product/voices-from-the-soviet-edge-southern-
migrants-in-leningrad-and-moscow-jeff-sahadeo-10480354
Voices From The Soviet Edge Southern Migrants In Leningrad And Moscow
Jeff Sahadeo
https://ebookbell.com/product/voices-from-the-soviet-edge-southern-
migrants-in-leningrad-and-moscow-jeff-sahadeo-81113458
Russian And Soviet History From The Time Of Troubles To The Collapse
Of The Soviet Union Steven A Usitalo
https://ebookbell.com/product/russian-and-soviet-history-from-the-
time-of-troubles-to-the-collapse-of-the-soviet-union-steven-a-
usitalo-33838186
https://ebookbell.com/product/shelter-from-the-holocaust-rethinking-
jewish-survival-in-the-soviet-union-mark-edele-7025202
https://ebookbell.com/product/on-dissidents-and-madness-from-the-
soviet-union-of-leonid-brezhnev-to-the-soviet-union-of-vladimir-putin-
robert-van-voren-2196804
Song From The Land Of Fire Azerbaijanian Mugam In The Soviet And
Postsoviet Periods Inna Naroditskaya
https://ebookbell.com/product/song-from-the-land-of-fire-
azerbaijanian-mugam-in-the-soviet-and-postsoviet-periods-inna-
naroditskaya-32735496
https://ebookbell.com/product/crises-in-the-postsoviet-space-from-the-
dissolution-of-the-soviet-union-to-the-conflict-in-ukraine-1st-
edition-felix-jaitner-editor-38493208
This page intentionally left blank
From the Soviet Bloc to the
European Union
The Soviet Union’s dramatic collapse in 1991 was a pivotal moment in the
complex history of Central and Eastern Europe, and Ivan Berend here offers
a magisterial new account of the dramatic transformation that culminated
in ten former Soviet bloc countries joining the European Union. Taking the
OPEC oil crisis of 1973 as his starting point, he charts the gradual unraveling
of state socialism in Central and Eastern Europe, its ultimate collapse in the
revolutions of 1989, and the economic restructuring and lasting changes in
income, employment, welfare, education, and social structure which followed.
He pays particular attention to the crucial role of the European Union as well
as the social and economic hurdles that continue to face former Soviet bloc
nations as they try to catch up with their Western neighbors. This will be
essential reading for scholars and students of European and economic history,
European politics, and economics.
ivan t. berend
CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS
Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, Singapore, São Paulo
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9780521493659
© Ivan T. Berend 2009
v
vi contents
vii
viii list of figures
Table 1.1 The spread of the telephone in Europe (in thousands) page 15
Table 1.2 Per capita GDP of Central and East Europe as a percentage of
Western European GDP 34
Table 1.3 Comparative GDP growth rates/capita 35
Table 1.4 The growth of GDP/capita compared (1973 = 100) 36
Table 1.5 Regional disparity, GDP/capita (regions as a percentage of the
West), 1950–1998 37
Table 2.1 Industrial output and animal stock in 1993 as a percentage of
1989 74
Table 2.2 Decline of GDP/capita in transforming countries in the early
1990s 77
Table 3.1 Budget commitments of the European Union 2000–2006, in
billion €, 1999 prices 99
Table 4.1 Cumulative inflow of FDI 116
Table 5.1 The service sector in the Central and East European economy,
2005 138
Table 5.2 Total energy consumption/capita in 2004 141
Table 5.3 The role of agriculture in the economy in 2005 145
Table 5.4 Industry’s role in the economy in 2004 154
Table 5.5 Labor productivity, 1990–2007 164
Table 5.6 Gross industrial output, 2003 165
Table 5.7 EU-25’s and Germany’s role in Central and East European
foreign trade in 2004 167
Table 5.8 GDP growth, percentage change from previous year, 1994–2007 169
Table 5.9 GDP growth rates between 1993 and 2003 170
Table 6.1 Decline in consumption in ten transition countries,
1989–1994/95 188
Table 7.1 Unemployment (as a percentage of civil labor force), 1995–2007 208
ix
x list of tables
Box 2.1 The Gdańsk Shipyard – the most Polish factory page 69
Box 3.1 The Albanian “pyramid scheme civil war” 80
Box 4.1 The European Bank of Reconstruction and Development 111
Box 4.2 Central and Eastern Europe: Volkswagen land 125
Box 5.1 A forgotten country: Moldova 150
Box 5.2 The largest minority in Central and Eastern Europe: the Roma 155
Box 6.1 How to become a billionaire in ten years: two rich men in
Hungary 182
Box 6.2 The richest Poles: Jan Kulczyk and Zygmund Solorz-Żak 184
Box 6.3 Homeless people flood Budapest after 1990 191
Box 7.1 Kings knock at Balkan doors 237
Box 7.2 Communists reinventing themselves as nationalists? The case
of Slovakia 241
Box 7.3 Changing the skyline: a new type of urban architecture 250
xi
Preface
xiii
xiv preface
The year 1989 has become known as the annus mirabilis, or miraculous
year. And, indeed, what happened that year was neither predicted nor
believable. It surprised the world. State socialism, which had established its
isolated bridgehead in Russia after the Bolshevik Revolution of 1917, spread
and conquered Central and Eastern Europe after World War II. Besides
the Soviet bloc in the eastern half of Europe, it gradually incorporated
nearly one-third of the world by the 1980s. The Soviet Union emerged
as a superpower with an enormous army and nuclear arsenal. In times
of crisis that threatened the system in other countries, such as the 1953
Berlin revolt, the 1956 Hungarian Revolution, the Prague Spring in 1968,
or the Afghan crisis in 1979, the Soviet military machine did not hesitate
to intervene and “save” socialism. The international military balance of
power during the Cold War decades kept the postwar world order intact
and, as everybody believed, unchangeable. Moreover, in 1975, the Helsinki
Agreement reaffirmed international acceptance and guarantee of the status
quo.
By the late 1980s, however, historical changes had rendered impossible
a brutal military solution to such crises. Not even hardliners risked open
confrontation and the use of force. In situations where force seemed the
ultima ratio, they refrained from using it and capitulated. And, in 1989,
state socialism peacefully collapsed in Poland and Hungary over the course
of a few months, and then throughout Central and Eastern Europe within
six weeks. This process concluded with the collapse of the Soviet Union
itself in 1991. The miracle of peaceful revolution destroyed state socialism
because nobody was ready to defend the regime. The elite prepared to save
its position by giving up power, or at least part of it, through major reforms
and compromises.
The year 1989 thus became a historical landmark of twentieth-century
Europe. In retrospect, the situation offered no alternatives, and the
1
2 from the soviet bloc to the european union
transformation from the late 1980s, as Timothy Garton Ash noted, “pro-
ceeds at break-neck speed with a quiet democratic revolution” or, in his
coinage from the words revolution and reform, “refolution” (Garton Ash,
1989).
What happened in Central and Eastern Europe in 1989 was, however,
not only a break with the postwar socialist past. The countries of the region
followed a different historical path from that of the advanced West in most
parts of the twentieth century: economic nationalism, self-sufficiency from
the 1920s, authoritarian dirigisme during the 1930s and early 1940s, and
later a Soviet-type non-market system with central planning. From the
early 1930s and then during the entire period of the 1950s to the 1980s, the
countries of Central and Eastern Europe belonged to isolationist regional
alliance systems led first by Nazi Germany and then by the Soviet Union.
The unsolvable crisis of the 1970s and 1980s dramatically strengthened
opposition to the state socialist regime and contributed to its collapse.
Moreover, 1989 marked the end of a long revolt, from both the Right and
the Left, against the West. Instead the trend turned to adjustment and
“Joining Europe!” This slogan of 1989 targeted the replacement of the
failed system that was unable to cope with the challenge of globalization.
The countries of the region longed to follow the successful West and
introduce its integrationist open market system. They wanted to be part
of the European Union.
At the same time, the European Union itself experienced slowdown
and crisis beginning in the late 1960s and early 1970s. It sought to regain
its vitality, to reestablish its competitiveness, and to cope with the chal-
lenge of globalization. Western Europe was the only major player in the
rapidly globalizing world system without an economic “backyard.” Latin
America and large parts of Asia became part of the production networks
of the United States and Japan, respectively, and assisted their economic
performance.
After 1989, the European Union was immediately ready to integrate
and incorporate Central and Eastern Europe in order to stabilize peace
on the continent and to build its own nearby production network. To
achieve that, the Union was ready to direct and assist the transformation
of Central and Eastern Europe, and to accept ten ill-prepared, former
communist countries as EU members in the near future. The enlargement
of the Union and the preparation for further enlargement in the Western
Balkans were important for the economic interests of the old member
countries of the European Union. The enlargement strengthened the EU’s
production network and stabilized the continent. The metamorphosis of
Central and Eastern Europe is, therefore, also a chapter of the history
introduction 3
of the European Union. Both East and West became winners through
integration.
Central and Eastern Europe’s transformation was thus determined by the
dual characteristics of the turn of the millennium in Europe: globalization
and the European Union’s response to its challenge.
The first chapter of the region’s transformation was essentially complete
by the time ten of its countries were accepted to the EU in the new anni
mirabiles of 2004 and 2007. The countries adjusted to the requirements
of the West, abolished their dictatorial regimes and their state-owned,
non-market systems, and rushed to introduce parliamentary democracy
and free market economies. They abandoned gradualism, took risks, and
made serious mistakes on an uncharted road, but in a decade and a half
successfully changed their situation. The social cost was dear, and social
pain, increased poverty, and income disparity affected wide layers of their
societies. Even demographic trends worsened. The social shock, caused
partly by the change of systems, but even more by radically changed values
and culture, is not yet over and characterizes both winners and losers alike
in these societies. It renders the political situation fragile, and it opens
the door to the sort of populist-nationalist fundamentalism which spread
through the region in the early 1990s, especially in the Balkans, and then
reemerged again in Poland, Slovakia, and Hungary as late as 2006 and
2007.
A significant contribution to the rapid transformation of the region
was the European Union’s insistence on compliance with its legal and
institutional requirements (acquis communautaire), combined with more
financial assistance than was received under the postwar Marshall Plan,
and an even higher amount of direct investments. The EU offered its
markets and modernized the telecommunications and banking systems
of the transforming countries. Central and Eastern Europe adjusted to
the requirements of the free market and became an important part of the
production network of old EU countries. An old dream came true, although
the countries of Central and East European region are not yet equal partners
in the formerly exclusive European club, and the new members often
consider themselves second-class citizens in Europe.
The Central and East European income level, as a consequence of its
different historical past, is much lower – from one-half to one-quarter of
that of the established members of the European Union – and the region’s
economy is highly dependent on the West and Western investments. The
social patterns of the new and prospective Union member countries also
carry the heavy burden of an unfortunate past. The region consequently
has a subordinate position in globalization. Will they break through and in
4 from the soviet bloc to the european union
time become prosperous equals? Will they achieve European Union levels
in terms of such basics as income level, labor productivity, infrastructure,
consumption, and modern social-occupational structures and attitudes?
Successful transformation does not mean merely full adjustment to the
market system and the requirements of the European Union. In a broader
sense it also requires adjustment to modern Western values and behavioral
patterns, and achievement of advanced income levels similar to those in the
West. Catching up with the EU-15 in this broader sense is a long historical
march that requires a competitive economy based on domestic innova-
tion, appropriate social and educational institutions, advanced domestic
banking and the availability of venture capital, and a wide array of small-
and medium-sized companies. Only the very first steps have been taken to
establish all of that, and only in a handful of countries.
The process, however, has already begun. If it succeeds, Central and
Eastern Europe will organically incorporate into a larger entity: Europe.
The caravan of Central and Eastern Europe is on the move. The possibility
of catching up with the West, which has motivated these countries from
the early nineteenth century, has become a realistic goal for the first time
in history, though it will be neither a quick nor an easy one to achieve.
A positive outcome will require generations and is not a given or even
evident at this stage of development. The door is wide open. Some of the
countries will enter. Others will not, or will cross the threshold only much
later.
This book covers the area of Central and Eastern Europe. At this
point, I need to clarify what I mean by that.1 The eastern half of the
European continent, often called Eastern Europe, Central Europe, or
Central and Eastern Europe, has a huge variety of definitions. Without
summarizing a century-long debate and the various interpretations of
the region from Leopold von Ranke ([1824] 1909) to Jenő Szűcs (1983),
I am going to discuss the region that in earlier centuries was located
between the German, Russian, and Ottoman empires, and which interwar
German authors called Zwischen Europa, or “in-between Europe.” History
in this zone began half a millennium later than in the Western Carolingian
Empire; Christendom conquered most of it in the ninth and tenth cen-
turies, but this zone remained the frontier of Christian-feudal Europe for
centuries, open to “barbaric” attacks from the East (N. Berend, 2001;
1 I use the terms Southern Europe and Mediterranean Europe interchangeably to mean Greece,
Italy, Portugal, and Spain, while Western Europe means Austria, Belgium, Britain, Denmark,
Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Liechtenstein, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway,
Sweden, and Switzerland.
introduction 5
2007). Unlike the western half of the continent, the region remained
agrarian until World War II. Nation building remained unfinished, and
borders and state formations have changed right up to the present, as
multiethnic states divide and split apart. Most of the countries of the
region belonged to huge multiethnic empires for up to five centuries, and
they remained ethnically mixed, politically authoritarian, and oppressive
against minorities.
In many ways, however, and in spite of important similarities, this
region is different from the “East par excellence,” as Szűcs (1983) called
Russia. It is difficult to generalize about the various countries because they
belonged to three empires in the middle of the nineteenth century, formed
ten states in the interwar decades, and comprise seventeen countries today.
One can differentiate between two distinct subregions, Central Europe
and the Balkans, which exhibit significant differences. They, nevertheless,
were and are characterized by basic similarities. All of them lost indepen-
dence between the late fourteenth and eighteenth centuries and became
incorporated into huge neighboring empires and, after regaining inde-
pendence, they all formed part of the Nazi German Lebensraum and then
the Soviet bloc in the twentieth century. Nowadays, they are all equally
countries “in transformation.” The historical trajectories of Central and
Eastern Europe thus differ significantly from the West and, in many senses,
from neighboring Russia and Turkey, as well (I. Berend, 2005).
This is a region which has existed as a historical unit for a millennium,
but it might begin to disappear as a distinguishable entity if the transfor-
mation successfully continues, and if the countries of the area prove able
to rise to the level of the West in the space of one or two generations.
chapter 1
The collapse of a regime always has more than one cause. In my interpreta-
tion, however, among the various international and domestic factors that
led to the collapse of state socialism in Central and Eastern Europe, basic
economic facts were primary. Accordingly, we must first unravel, out of
the numberless threads that make up the fabric of history, the dramatic
changes in economic processes brought about by the shock to the world
economy caused by the oil crisis of 1973.
The economic base of state socialism was visibly undermined from the
1970s on, accelerating its collapse. For a full understanding of this process,
it is important to give a relatively detailed explanation of the international
economic situation, the Western reaction to a changing economic world,
and the Eastern inability to adjust to it. These developments are not only
the main factors in the collapse of socialism, but also explain the require-
ments and trends of postcommunist transformation. This is, therefore,
the proper point of departure for analyzing the two crucially important
decades around the turn of the century.
The year 1973 was indeed the beginning of a new chapter of greater
European economic history, which, in the case of Central and Eastern
Europe, led to the collapse of their state socialist regimes. It should be
noted, however, that this chronological division is also somewhat artificial.
As I explain below, the slowdown in economic growth and productivity
in the region and around the world had been unfolding gradually over a
longer period of time. Moreover, major political and economic crises had
hit the Soviet bloc countries quite a few times already before. Neverthe-
less, I still begin with the politically motivated oil crisis of 1973, which
made dramatically manifest this development’s gradually accumulating
limitations and emerging predicament.
6
the economic factors in the collapse of state socialism 7
The West
In the fall of 1973, the seemingly “endless” postwar prosperity in Europe
came to an abrupt halt. As many contemporaries speculated, the sud-
den change might have been accidental, generated by a political drama –
namely, the October 1973 Yom Kippur War in the Near East – followed by
the boycott decision of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Coun-
tries (OPEC). Crude oil prices soared from $2.70 per barrel in 1973 to
$9.76 by 1974. Another political drama, the Iranian Revolution of 1979,
generated a second “oil crisis” in 1979–80, and, taken as a whole, oil prices
increased tenfold. This new development eroded the hope and prospect of
adjustment.
From that time, nothing worked as usual. Economic growth stopped,
prices and unemployment sharply increased, and Keynesian demand-side
economics – according to which additional demand, and strengthening the
purchasing power of the population through job creation and state invest-
ments, could enable governments to cope with economic crisis – became
unable to cure the stagnation and decline any longer. In fact, it generated
even higher inflation. The Philips curve, the classic “law” describing the
inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment, i.e., increasing
inflation decreases unemployment and vice versa, also stopped working as
inflation and unemployment rose together. What followed was a sudden
slowing down and decline accompanied by high inflation and unemploy-
ment. This odd pairing of stagnation and inflation led to the introduction
of a new economic term: stagflation.
Why did Keynesian economics, which worked for roughly forty years,
fail? Why did all the usual economic trends suddenly change? Was it the
mysterious long-term Kondratiev cycle that has its 20- to 25-year upturn
and then 20- to 25-year downturn, one following the other since the late
eighteenth century? Was it the cycle’s downturn which had arrived like a
German train, right on schedule, following the postwar quarter-century
of high prosperity? We have several more exact explanations, including a
role for an overheated, exceptional boom, which gradually compromised
itself. As Andrea Boltho stated:
The year 1973 represented a watershed . . . a very sudden break with the past,
but the trend towards a deteriorating performance had already set in earlier. In
a way, the success of the 1950s and 1960s had laid the preconditions for at least
some of the failures of the 1970s. (Boltho, 1982: 28)
8 from the soviet bloc to the european union
Herman Van der Wee also underlines the close connection between the
high prosperity and its end by noting that the gross capital stock per
employee in France, Germany, the Netherlands, and Britain went from
$78,440 to $208,211 between 1950 and 1973 (in 1990 values):
The price of energy and raw materials increased significantly before the oil
crisis, and by as much as 63% in 1972–73, while the rate of inflation in
Germany reached 7% in that year. The economy became overheated and
industrial output in the advanced West increased by 10% that year.
A quarter-century of excessive growth and skyrocketing consumption
led to the saturation of consumer goods markets. As part of this trend,
exports also became more difficult, and their growth slowed. Mass pro-
duction, a key factor of prosperity, became less and less sustainable. Robert
Brenner commented: “The advanced capitalist world entered into a crisis
well before the end of 1973, experiencing falling profitability, especially in
manufacturing and increased rate of inflation” (1998: 138). For example,
between 1965 and 1973 the aggregate manufacturing profitability of the
seven wealthiest countries of the world declined by 25 percent.
In reality, the change in 1973 was not abrupt, and it was assisted by
non-economic factors, among them mistaken policy interventions, which
confused the usual trends. Clouds began gathering during the boom years.
From the late 1960s, labor markets changed and, especially around 1968,
led to the end of corporative cooperation between employers and employ-
ees, a major stabilizing factor in the postwar period. In Michael Piore and
Charles Sabel’s explanation, both the workers’ environment and their atti-
tudes changed. Virtually full employment, the need for a reserve which
can enter and leave the market, and a shortage of labor that initiated
immigration strengthened the position of employees. The transformation
of the labor environment went hand in hand with a generation change:
“a new generation matured in the postwar prosperity, without memories
of the Great Depression . . . the freedom from such constraints encour-
aged protest.” Collective self-restraint, the authors continue, disappeared.
In France, wages were indexed to cost of living. The Italian Statuto dei
the economic factors in the collapse of state socialism 9
As early as the mid-1960s, it was evident that a slowdown of growth did not
bring about any appreciable slowdown in price rises . . . The rise in oil prices at
the end of 1973 only hastened a phenomenon that was already emerging more
and more clearly. (Caron, 1979: 322)
not just inflation but the business cycle grew increasingly volatile . . . With
the commitment to par values removed, agents had no reason to regard an
10 from the soviet bloc to the european union
acceleration of inflation as temporary. When governments stimulated demand
in the effort to offset a recession, this provoked compensating wage increases;
aggregate demand policies therefore elicited inflation rather than stabilizing
output. (Eichengreen, [1994] 1996: 61)
There is little evidence of any general slowing down in the rate of growth . . . [It]
is a strong presumption that the gross domestic product of the OECD area may
again double in the next decade and a half. (OECD, 1974: 166)
the . . . long cycle is associated with the replacement and expansion of basic capital
goods, and with the radical regrouping of, and changes in society’s productive
forces. (Kondratiev, [1922] 1984: 94–97)
and products to conquer larger markets and achieve greater profits. Extra-
economic factors, such as wars and political upheavals, also contribute to
this process. These fluctuations are thoroughly international and hit all
countries except those that are entirely isolated from the world economy.
What happened in the 1970s clearly fits into this interpretational frame-
work. Those branches of industry that had developed the fastest during
the postwar prosperity now suffered the most. The coal, iron, and steel
industries, shipbuilding, and other sectors were downsized substantially,
and some, such as the Swedish shipbuilding industry, were briefly on the
verge of closing altogether. The Belgian mining industry declined by half
between 1970 and 1979, and construction fell by one-third. Between 1970
and 1980, the share contributed to the gross value added of total industry
by traditional industries – construction and building materials, iron and
steel, traditional engineering, wood, paper, textiles, and clothing – declined
in Germany by 40%. Small wonder that investments, which increased by
6.4% annually between 1960 and 1973, dropped to 1.8% between 1975
and 1979. By 1979, the German manufacturing labor force, counted in
work-hours, had dropped 20% below the 1970 levels.
The structural crisis of the world economy hit Western Europe especially
hard because of its arrival at a turning point in its postwar development.
Western Europe’s postwar economic miracle had certain peculiar factors:
during the early postwar years, and until these countries reached their
potential levels of output in the early 1950s, their economies were charac-
terized by high growth rates typical in reconstruction periods after major
turmoil such as war or depression (Jánossy, 1971).
During the later 1950s and 1960s, the region profited highly from its
extensive development model, based on an increase in the factors of pro-
duction: “brute force” capital accumulation, restructuring the labor force
by shifting from lower-productivity agriculture to higher-productivity
industries, and increasing the labor force by an average 1 percent per
annum. Additionally, using the existing stock of technological knowledge,
mostly transferred from the United States, bolstered this trend.
Western Europe also profited from its inherited institutions including,
among others, its advanced banking system. The postwar development
was also embedded in newly created institutions after the war: partly in
Bretton Woods, which fixed international exchange rates and created a
stable financial environment, but mostly by building up corporative social
partnerships (Sozialpartnerschaften), agreements between labor unions
and employers, which made possible wage and price moderation. Keyne-
sian regulated markets, state assistance, and integrating national markets
also played an important role.
14 from the soviet bloc to the european union
The formation of the Single Market led to the rationalization and consolidation
of industries previously fragmented along national lines. It made it attractive
for extra-European producers . . . The EU attracted 21 percent of Japanese FDI
[foreign direct investment] outflows in the late 1980s . . . The proportion of US
FDI destined for Europe rose from 39 to 45 percent, while intra-European Union
FDI as a share of total EU FDI outflows rose from 31 to 51 percent. (Eichengreen,
2007: 346)
The integration process was initiated by six countries in the 1950s, but
the community became permanently enlarged after 1973. In that year,
three countries – Britain, Ireland, and Denmark – joined the founding
six, and during the 1980s, after the collapse of authoritarian dictatorships
in Southern Europe, Greece, Portugal, and Spain were accepted. By the
mid-1990s, Sweden, Finland, and Austria had joined, bringing European
Union membership to fifteen.
The European Union launched a deliberate cohesion policy to assist the
less-developed regions, which received significant contributions to help
them draw level with the others. A massive catching-up process emerged
in the Mediterranean countries and Ireland. As regards technology and
20 from the soviet bloc to the european union
The East
The impact of the oil crisis and the structural crisis which emerged hit the
entire world economy. Following the pattern of the 1870s–’80s as well as
the 1930s, the peripheries were most affected. The unique phenomenon
of the 1930s, when the Great Depression failed to influence the isolated
Soviet Union, was not repeated during the 1970s and 1980s. The Soviet
bloc countries were no longer isolated from the world. Half or more
of the foreign trade of Poland, Romania, Hungary, and Czechoslovakia
was trade with free market economies. State socialist Yugoslavia, which
did not belong to the Soviet bloc, was even more tightly integrated into
the world economy. The relatively small or medium-sized countries were
strongly dependent on foreign trade. In the mid-1970s, exports made up
nearly half of the Hungarian GDP, and from one-fifth to one-quarter of the
Polish, Yugoslav, and Romanian GDPs. The international decline of the old
leading sectors, as elsewhere in the world, rendered some export products
unmarketable, and brought sharply reduced prices for most of the others.
The effect on Central and Eastern Europe was exaggerated because of
the structural policy of the industrialization drive of the 1950s and ’60s.
The command economies built up traditional coal, iron, steel, and heavy
engineering branches as their leading sectors, based on technology that was
obsolete even then. During the 1960s, they added basic, heavy chemical
industries but not the corresponding processing branches. With a delay of
one hundred years, Central and Eastern Europe built its own Manchesters
and “Black Countries” in Katowice and Dunaujváros, in the infamous
the economic factors in the collapse of state socialism 21
The centrally planned economies of Eastern Europe were able, initially at least,
to perform tolerably well. The institutions of the command economy had several
22 from the soviet bloc to the european union
limitations . . . but they were best suited to the circumstances of catch-up growth.
(Eichengreen, 2007: 5)
growth strategies. Other countries of the Soviet bloc did not even initiate
a new orientation in their economic strategy.
The crisis after 1973 made the failure of the economy manifest in most of
the countries. The conservative regimes, however, continued the traditional
ideologically determined Soviet policy. Hungary was almost alone in its
open recognition of the need for a change of model during the late 1970s.
Let me quote from my own lecture at the May 1977 General Assembly
meeting of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences:
[S]o long as the classical system can be sustained . . . it has a degree of stability
and robustness, whereas the system undergoing the contortions of reform is
inherently unstable . . . The reform destroys the coherence of the classical system
and proves incapable of establishing a new order in its place . . . [N]owhere has
it been able to survive lastingly. (Kornai, 1992: 571, 573)
7,000
6,000
5,000
4,000
3,000 kWh/capita
2,000
1,000
0
West Central Romania Bosnia
and
Eastern
Europe
90
79
80
70
60
50
40
28
30
20
7.4
10
0
USA European Central and
Union Eastern Europe
were often out of order and it took hours to get a dial tone (Ehrlich and
Révész, 1991: 83). As late as 1987, Moscow could not receive more than six
long-distance calls simultaneously, while long-distance calls to other parts
of the country had to go through Moscow (Mastanduno, 1992: 1).
The computer age, heralded in 1974 with the appearance of the personal
computer, did not arrive in Central and Eastern Europe. The ratio of
personal computers, between 5 and 50 per 1,000 people, reached only
about 5% to 20% of the Western level. The number of fax machines in the
early 1990s reached only 1 to 8 per 1,000 inhabitants, and only 5 percent
of the fax machines used in Europe were in Central and Eastern Europe.
The service revolution, which dramatically increased the division of
labor and labor productivity, also stopped at the borders of the region.
While service employment increased to roughly 60 percent of the active
population in the West by 1980, in Central and Eastern Europe two-thirds
of the population were blue-collar workers and farmers.
Why did technological and structural renewal lag in the region? To
answer this question, one must first consider the causes and prime movers
of the permanent renewal of technology. Technological changes, explains
Schumpeter, are inherent in a capitalist market economy and competitive
market environment. In his interpretation, innovations are
The central figure in this process, the hero who must overcome the diffi-
culties of changing practice, is the entrepreneur. Innovation is a genuine
characteristic of competitive capitalism, which “not only never is but never
can be stationary”;
The fundamental impulse that sets and keeps the capitalist engine in motion
comes from the new consumers’ goods, the new methods of production or trans-
portation, the new markets, the forms of industrial organization that capitalist
enterprise creates. [The new combination] revolutionizes the economic struc-
ture from within, incessantly destroying the old one, incessantly creating a new
one. This process of Creative Destruction is the essential fact about capitalism.
(Schumpeter, 1976: 82–83)
but simply to have the resources available for investment is not a guarantee of
development. Resources must be matched by the opportunity to use them . . . the
social capacity to assimilate advanced technology. (Solow, 1966: 480)
the area would be able to receive and adopt modern technology. The
main obstacles for technology transfer were not internal, but external
factors, such as the American-initiated and -controlled ban on the export
of modern technology to Soviet bloc countries.
The policy of banning exports to the Soviet bloc was instituted with
the beginning of the Cold War. The United States had introduced manda-
tory licensing of exports already in 1947. In September 1948 negotia-
tions began with Britain and France, and in 1949 the Organisation for
European Economic Co-operation took over coordination of export con-
trol. In November of that year the Coordinating Committee for Multilateral
Export Controls (CoCom) was established. Operations began on January
1, 1950, and all NATO member countries, plus West Germany, Canada,
and later Portugal, Japan, Greece, and Turkey, became part of it. CoCom
had weekly meetings with the participation of middle-level officials. The
US State Department and US Department of Defense were always repre-
sented, while the other countries sent representatives from their ministries
of commerce. The basis of control and banning was established by the
United States Export Control Act (1949) and then the Battle Act (1951),
which empowered the president to block exports of “any articles, materials,
or supplies, including technical data.” CoCom operations and information
were classified during the first period and decisions never made public. In
1952, the CoCom list contained 400 major categories, and later on about
150,000–200,000 items were on the list, which was periodically reviewed
and updated.
During the 1970s and 1980s, all telecommunications technology,
biotechnology, computer technology including software, and cutting-edge
new technology was on the list, and their sales were banned. In 1982,
President Reagan’s Executive Order 12356 prohibited foreign researchers
and graduate students from certain areas of research and training and
sought to “classify the product and dissemination of on-campus scientific
work.” The Department of Defense required several scientific conference
organizers to withdraw papers on sensitive subjects and to exclude non-US
citizens from certain presentations (McDaniel, 1993: 112–13).
The CoCom policy, the first export ban during peacetime in history,
despite periods of relaxation during the 1960s and part of the 1970s, suc-
cessfully prevented technology transfer to the Soviet bloc. In July 1974, a few
months after the oil shock, a task force was established under the chairman-
ship of J. Fred Bucy, the executive vice-president of Texas Instruments, and
it presented its final report, the Bucy Report, in February 1976. It became a
guideline for further export control and significantly strengthened restric-
tions in the face of a new technological-communications revolution. It
30 from the soviet bloc to the european union
European allies argued that trade in these technologies was badly needed for
the modernization of the transforming economies of the former socialist
countries.
Lacking their own industrial R&D capacity and thwarted in their
attempts at achieving technology transfer, Central and East European
countries were cornered and unable to restructure their economies. The
obsolete economic branches and export sectors were preserved. As a clear
indicator of technological stagnation, labor productivity also stagnated
during the post-1973 decades. Labor productivity in the region was tra-
ditionally low. In 1950, it only just reached the pre-World War I Western
level. Between 1950 and 1973, labor productivity doubled, and even tre-
bled, in some of these countries, but one worker-hour still produced only
$5–6 of GDP, which hardly changed until the 1980s. In the Soviet Union,
the productivity level declined by 14 percent and dropped to roughly one-
fifth of the Western level, which by that time had already reached $25–28.
Moreover, Spain, Portugal, and Greece, with a productivity level similar to
that of Central and Eastern Europe in 1950, and about $10 in 1973, also
increased their productivity level to $20/hour by the early 1990s. Stagnating
labor productivity in the East was contrasted by rapidly rising productivity
in the West and South of Europe.
Lenin’s prophecy was turned upside down. After the Bolshevik revolu-
tion, he declared in his Immediate Task of the Soviet Government (1918)
that “the fundamental task of creating a social system superior to capi-
talism . . . [is] raising the productivity of labour” (Lenin, 1974: 415). Cap-
italism proved to be superior and defeated state socialism in the labor
productivity race.
Productivity was not even a main concern in state socialist Central
and Eastern Europe, since it formed a self-sufficient economic bloc. Most
export items of countries in the region were sold in the isolated market of
the Council of Mutual Economic Aid (CMEA, or Comecon), established in
1949. This market was safe and had been highly protected since the 1950s.
The non-competitive market, characterized by permanent shortages and
fixed state-managed trade agreements, served to defend the economy of
the Soviet bloc and had nothing to do with real markets and market
demand. Until the early 1970s, Comecon trade comprised two-thirds to
three-quarters of trade conducted by member countries. Trade with free
market countries was marginal.
However, as the troubled Comecon market became less able to offer the
required goods, more socialist countries had to look to the Western free
markets. In turn, they had also to sell on the competitive markets. From
the late 1970s and during the 1980s, with two or three exceptions, most
32 from the soviet bloc to the european union
of these countries had about a 50–50 split in Comecon versus free market
trade. Their non-competitive economy was challenged. It proved unable
to adjust, with tragic consequences.
Although it was not immediately evident what kinds of changes were
transforming the world economy, the bureaucratic and centralized man-
agement system was itself an additional obstacle to adjustment. Lack of
market influence and entrepreneurial interest played a crucial role in the
extremely slow reaction of the socialist governments to the changing inter-
national economic environment. Even the government of reform-oriented
Hungary stated
that the crisis disrupting the capitalist world economy would leave Hungary and
other socialist countries unaffected – that it could be halted at the frontier. Quite
a long time passed before it was realized that the factors behind the crisis were
not temporary or rooted in political sanctions. (I. Berend, 1990: 232–33)
Most of the countries simply waited, without taking any action, and lost at
least five years before they understood the need for a response. The Polish
reaction was more detrimental than no action at all. The administration
of Edward Gierek after 1970 attempted to overcome economic troubles
through a policy of accelerated economic growth via hyperinvestments.
During the first half of the 1970s, investments increased by 133%, and
in 1975 Polish GNP increased by 29%. However, this took place without
structural changes or technological renewal. In other words, Poland fur-
ther expanded the obsolete, outdated industrial sectors of its overheated
economy. The country, formerly an energy exporter, became an energy
importer by the end of the 1970s (I. Berend, 1996: 229).
The effect of delayed and often mistaken reactions was exacerbated due
in part to the erosion of Comecon trade. Lack of adjustment led to a rapid
deterioration in the terms of trade, the countries’ ratio of export to import
prices. During the first five years after 1973, the Central and East European
countries suffered growing trade deficits because of a 10% to 20% decline
in the terms of trade. By 1985, countries which were heavily dependent
on imported energy suffered a 26% to 32% decline in terms of trade. In
other words, these countries had to boost exports by at least one-fifth,
and sometimes one-third, in exchange for the same amount of imports
(United Nations, 1990). One should also not forget that a decline in terms
of trade, a growing gap between rising import prices and lagging export
prices, already characterized the entire state socialist period: Hungary, for
example, had a 50 percent terms-of-trade loss between 1938 and 1989.
Since Comecon member countries followed the traditional/ideological
extensive fast-growth policy, they were trapped by ever-increasing trade
Other documents randomly have
different content
CHAPTER XII.
* * * * *
I began this story on the sea, and I desire to end it on the sea;
and though another yarn, which should embrace my arrival at
Glasgow, my introduction to Mary's aunt, my visit to Leamington, my
marriage, and divers other circumstances of an equally personal
nature, could easily be spun to follow this—yet the title of this story
must limit the compass of it, and with the "Wreck of the Grosvenor"
my tale should have had an end.
And yet I should be doing but poor justice to the faithful and
beautiful nature of my dear wife, if I did not tell you that the plans
which she had unfolded to me, and which I have made to appear as
though they only concerned myself, included the boatswain and the
poor steward. For both a provision was contemplated which I knew
her too well to doubt that she had the power to make, or that she
would forget: a provision that, on the one hand, would bring the
boatswain alongside of us even in our own home, and make him
independent of his calling, which, to say the least, considering the
many years he had been to sea, had served him but ill, and still
offered him but a very scurvy outlook; whilst, on the other hand, it
would enable the steward to support himself and his wife and child,
without in the smallest degree taxing those unfortunate brains which
we could only hope the shipwreck had not irreparably damaged.
Thus much, and this bit of a yarn is spun.
And now I ask myself, is it worth the telling? Well, however it
goes as a piece of work, it may teach a lesson: that good sailors
may be made bad, and bad sailors may be made outrageous, and
harmless men may be converted into criminals by the meanness of
shipowners. Every man knows, thanks to one earnest, eloquent, and
indefatigable voice that has been raised among us, what this country
thinks of the rascals who send rotten ships to sea. And it is worth
while to acquaint people with another kind of rottenness that is
likewise sent to sea, which in its way is as bad as rotten timbers—a
rottenness which is even less excusable, inasmuch as it costs but a
trifling sum of money to remedy, than rotten hulls:
I mean rotten food.
Sailors have not many champions, because I think their troubles
and wrongs are not understood. You must live and suffer their lives
to know their lives. Go aloft with them, man the pumps with them,
eat their biscuit and their pork, and drink their water with them;
lodge with crimps along with them; be of their nature, and
experience their shore-going temptations, the harpies in trousers
and petticoats who prey upon them, who drug them and strip them.
And however deficient a man may be in those qualifications of
mind which go to the making of popular novels, I hope no person
will charge such a writer with impertinence for drawing a quill on
behalf of a race of men to whom Britain owes the greatest part of
her wealth and prosperity, who brave death, who combat the
elements, who lead in numerous instances the lives of mongrel
dogs, who submit, with few murmurs that ever reach the shore-
going ear, to privations which blanch the cheek to read, that our
tables and our homes may be abundantly furnished, our banking
balances large, and our national importance supreme.
THE END.
Punctuation and spelling were made consistent when a predominant preference was
found in the three volumes of this novel, or to remedy simple typographical errors;
otherwise they were not changed.
Dialect and other non-standard spellings have not been changed.
Spaces before the contraction "'ll" (for "will") have been retained. Such spacing was
inconsistent in this volume
Ambiguous hyphens at the ends of lines have been retained.
Page 107: "gauge" was misprinted as "guage".
Page 180: "so that speaking one of these vessels" was printed that way.
Page 213: "never was there less bombast" was misprinted as "their"; changed here.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK THE WRECK OF
THE GROSVENOR, VOLUME 3 OF 3 ***
Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the
terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or
expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or
a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original
“Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must
include the full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in
paragraph 1.E.1.
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.F.
1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
ebookbell.com