0% found this document useful (0 votes)
7 views44 pages

A Skill-specific Dynamic Labour Supply and Labour Demand Framework

This working paper presents a scenario analysis of labor supply and demand dynamics across different skill groups in the six Western Balkan countries (WB6) until 2030. It identifies potential labor shortages and surpluses based on various scenarios, including labor market and education policies, migration flows, and GDP growth. The findings suggest that tailored policy interventions are necessary to address the specific labor market challenges faced by each country in the region.

Uploaded by

vicotis
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
7 views44 pages

A Skill-specific Dynamic Labour Supply and Labour Demand Framework

This working paper presents a scenario analysis of labor supply and demand dynamics across different skill groups in the six Western Balkan countries (WB6) until 2030. It identifies potential labor shortages and surpluses based on various scenarios, including labor market and education policies, migration flows, and GDP growth. The findings suggest that tailored policy interventions are necessary to address the specific labor market challenges faced by each country in the region.

Uploaded by

vicotis
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 44

JUNE 2021

Working Paper 200

A Skill-specific Dynamic Labour


Supply and Labour Demand
Framework:
A Scenario Analysis for the Western Balkan
Countries to 2030
Sandra M. Leitner

Commissioned by

The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies


Wiener Institut für Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche
A Skill-specific Dynamic Labour Supply and
Labour Demand Framework:

A Scenario Analysis for the Western Balkan Countries


to 2030

SANDRA M. LEITNER

Sandra M. Leitner is Economist at The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (wiiw).

This report was commissioned by the European Training Foundation within the research project
'Migration and Human Capital in the Western Balkans' under the contract CON/19/ETF/0028.
Its contents and opinions are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the ETF or any other EU institution.
Abstract

This paper pursues a scenario analysis to shed light on past and potential future labour supply and
labour demand dynamics of different skill groups in the six Western Balkan countries (WB6). It
differentiates between four educational levels (low, medium-general, medium-VET, and high) and looks
at a medium-term projection period until 2030. Starting from a baseline scenario, it examines how
several different scenarios would affect the employment situation of different skill groups. These
scenarios are built on the possible impact which potential labour market policies, education policies,
migration flows and policies as well as GDP growth developments and structural change could have on
‘surplus’ and ‘shortage’ situations of different skill groups. Simulation results of the baseline scenario
show that both labour shortage and excess labour for different skill groups would coexist alongside each
other within the projection period. In all WB6 countries, the low educated (given their low activity rates)
would experience labour shortages either already within or shortly after the projection period. Similarly,
while Med-VETs, Med-GENs and the highly educated would also face labour shortages within or shortly
after the projection period in the majority of WB6 countries, in some of these countries, there would also
be evidence of growing excess labour, such as among Med-VETs in Montenegro and Kosovo, Med-
GENs in Kosovo and the highly educated in Bosnia and Herzegovina and Montenegro. Additional
scenarios point to important country-specific policy options that can help to mitigate these projected
labour market imbalances among different skill groups and, furthermore, contribute to an improved
economic development trajectory for these economies.

Keywords: dynamic labour supply-labour demand model, scenario analysis, skill demand by
educational groups, skill shortages and surplus, net migration flows, Western Balkan countries

JEL classification: J11, J21, J23


Preface

This report forms part of the regional study on ‘Migration dynamics from a human capital perspective in
the Western Balkans’. The study was launched in 2020 by the European Training Foundation (ETF) and
carried out jointly with the Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (wiiw) with the aim of
shedding light on the triangular relationships between human capital formation, labour markets and
migration, and of analysing the role that the malfunctioning of education systems and labour markets
plays in migration.

The report benefited from discussions and comments made by the wiiw (Michael Landesmann and
Hermine Vidovic) and the ETF project team (Ummuhan Bardak, Mirela Gavoci, Mariavittoria Garlappi,
Cristiana Burzio, and Stefano Lasagni). The main data sources used in this report include national
Labour Force Survey data (2010-2019) obtained from the State Statistical Offices of the six Western
Balkan countries, detailed population statistics from Eurostat (including unabridged life tables), United
Nations population and migration statistics, as well as data from the wiiw Annual Database.

The ETF and wiiw would like to thank all State Statistical Offices in the six Western Balkan countries for
their collaboration, which provided the research team with access to the Labour Force Survey database
(2010-2019). This report would not have been possible without their data and contributions.
CONTENTS

1. Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................... 9

2. Data sources .................................................................................................................................................... 12

3. Methodological framework and key characteristics of the baseline scenario ................14

3.1. Labour supply ................................................................................................................................14


3.2. Labour demand ..............................................................................................................................20

4. Scenarios.......................................................................................................................................................... 22

5. Findings ........................................................................................................................................................... 24

5.1. Results of the baseline scenario ....................................................................................................24


5.2. Results of the no migration scenario..............................................................................................25
5.3. Results of the labour market policy scenario .................................................................................25
5.4. Results of the high policy attention to education scenario .............................................................26
5.5. Results of the joint labour market policy and high policy attention to education scenario .............26
5.6. Results of the high GDP growth scenario ......................................................................................26
5.7. Results of the change in economic structure scenario ..................................................................27
5.8. Results of the joint high GDP growth and the change in economic structure scenario .................27
5.9. Results of the development scenario (combining all previous scenarios) .....................................27

6. Summary and conclusion ........................................................................................................................ 37

7. References .......................................................................................................................................................40

8. Annex .................................................................................................................................................................41
TABLES AND FIGURES

Figure 1 / Observed (until and including 2018) and projected skill-specific activity rates 15+ ................. 15
Figure 2 / Observed (until and including 2018) and projected skill composition of the working-age
population 15+ ......................................................................................................................... 17
Figure 3 / Annual net migration flows as calculated with the cohort approach (until and including 2019)
and projected mean net migration flows .................................................................................. 19
Figure 4 / Annual net migration flows as calculated with the cohort approach (until and including 2019)
and projected mean net migration flows as share of the total working age population 15+..... 20
Figure 5 / Observed (until and including 2018) and projected skill-specific employment shares ............. 21
Figure 6 / Labour supply and labour demand – baseline scenario .......................................................... 28
Figure 7 / Labour supply and labour demand – No migration scenario ................................................... 29
Figure 8 / Labour supply and labour demand – Labour market policy scenario ...................................... 30
Figure 9 / Labour supply and labour demand – High policy attention to education scenario ................... 31
Figure 10 / Labour supply and labour demand – Joint labour market policy and high policy attention
to education scenario ............................................................................................................... 32
Figure 11 / Labour supply and labour demand – High GDP growth scenario .......................................... 33
Figure 12 / Labour supply and labour demand – Change in economic structure scenario ...................... 34
Figure 13 / Labour supply and labour demand – Joint high GDP growth and structural change
scenario ................................................................................................................................... 35
Figure 14 / Labour supply and labour demand – Development scenario................................................. 36

Annex

Figure A.1 / Past and future projected skill-specific activity rates by sex ................................................. 41
INTRODUCTION 9
Working Paper 200

1. Introduction

This paper follows Peschner and Fotakis (2013) and Fotakis and Peschner (2015) and pursues a scenario
analysis to shed light on past and potential future labour supply and labour demand dynamics of different
educational/skill groups in the six Western Balkan countries (WB6 – Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Kosovo, Montenegro, North Macedonia and Serbia). In this respect, it helps to identify surplus labour
situations as well as the potential emergence of skill shortages of different educational groups.

A scenario analysis is a tool which examines and evaluates possible events or scenarios that could take
place in the future and identifies the various feasible results or possible outcomes. While it helps decision
makers in devising strategies and thinking about possible future scenarios, it does not predict the future.

The analysis starts with a baseline scenario in which demographic population projections are partly used
from existing sources and partly developed by us; other labour market indicators (such as activity rates,
productivity growth, etc.) are mostly derived from past trends. It then examines how a number of
different scenarios would affect the employment situation of different skill groups: these scenarios are
built on the possible impact which potential labour market policies, education policies, migration flow
scenarios, development policies, GDP growth developments and structural change could have on
‘surplus’ and ‘shortage’ situations with regard to different skill groups. In particular, we examine whether
the different scenarios would lead to different ‘switchover points’ when a ‘surplus’ labour situation
changes into a ‘skill shortage’ situation for particular skill groups, and vice versa, as compared to the
baseline scenario.

The analysis differentiates between four educational levels (based on ISCED 2011): Low (primary or lower
secondary education); Medium-general (Med-GEN = upper secondary general education); Medium-VET
(Med-VET = upper secondary vocational education and training); and High (tertiary education).

The analysis takes a medium-term perspective and looks at a projection period until 2030.

Simulation results of the baseline scenario show that within the projection period 2019-2030 situations of
labour shortage and excess labour for different skill groups would exist in parallel in the six Western
Balkan countries. Particularly, in Albania, North Macedonia and Serbia, all four skill groups would face
labour shortages either already within or shortly after the projection period. Furthermore, in Bosnia and
Herzegovina, while the low-educated and Med-VETs would experience labour shortages within or
shortly after the projection period, the highly educated would be in a situation of excess labour (with
labour market equilibrium for Med-GENs). Similarly, in Montenegro, the low-educated would face labour
shortages within or shortly after the projection period but Med-VETs and the highly educated would face
excess labour (with labour market equilibrium for Med-GENs). Finally, in Kosovo there would be labour
shortages among the low- and the highly educated shortly after the projection period but substantial and
persistent excess labour among the medium educated (i.e. Med-VETs and Med-GENs).
10 INTRODUCTION
Working Paper 200

Additional scenarios point to important country-specific changes and policy options that can help to
mitigate these projected labour market imbalances among different skill groups. The policy scenarios are
explored in a ‘stacked manner’: they serve, at first, to partially address one or the other labour market
imbalances (such as the low activity rates of low educated, or the relevance of projected migration flows for
labour supply), but they then build up to explore policy scenarios which affect the labour demand and
labour supply sides in a way that amount to a structural ‘up-grading’ of the WB economies and which could
also lift overall growth performance as well as their employment absorption capacities. Thus, we
investigate an ‘education scenario’ in which the supply of the higher skill groups is strengthened but, as this
might accentuate excess supply of these groups (which was one of the factors that has led to their high
migration propensity), we then allow for changes on the demand side through structural policies (increasing
the demand for the higher educated) thereby also lifting the GDP growth prospects of WB economies.

We start to explore these scenarios by investigating the possible importance of migration flows over the
period investigated, by contrasting a zero net migration scenario across all educational groups with the
base scenario. Such a scenario would generally have little discernible effect in the majority of WB6
countries, as in these economies projected migration flows do not amount to high shares of the labour
supply in the different skill groups. However, notable exceptions are found in Bosnia and Herzegovina,
North Macedonia and Kosovo. Labour market policies, which aim to increase the activity rates of the
low-educated and Med-VETs, would help to avert projected labour shortages among the low-educated
and Med-VETs in Albania and among Med-VETs in North Macedonia. Conversely, they would
‘overshoot’ and generate excess labour supply among the low-educated and Med-VETs in Bosnia and
Herzegovina and the low-educated in North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo. Education policies, which
put strong emphasis on upgrading the skill mix of the working-age population towards Med-GENs and
the highly educated, would not only exacerbate projected labour shortages among the low-educated and
Med-VETs in all WB6 countries (except Kosovo) but also generate or further exacerbate excess labour
among Med-GENs and the highly educated in all WB6 countries. Joint labour market and education
policies would lead to labour market shortages among the low-educated and Med-VETs in all WB6
countries, except for Bosnia and Herzegovina and Kosovo, where the low-educated would face excess
labour beyond the projection period. By contrast, in all WB6 countries, Med-GENs and the highly
educated would instead experience substantial excess labour. A situation of higher than projected GDP
growth would result in labour shortages in all Western Balkan countries except for Kosovo, where Med-
VETs, and temporarily also the low-educated and Med-GENs, would still experience excess labour.
Structural change (in a direction that would increase the demand for the higher-skilled) would on the one
hand avert actual or imminent labour shortages and, in some cases, further enhance existing excess
labour among the low-educated and Med-VETs; on the other hand, it would lead to labour shortages
among Med-GENs and the highly educated in all WB6 except for Kosovo. Higher GDP growth and
structural change together would lead to moderate labour demand effects among the low-educated and
Med-VETs but would result in significant increases in labour demand among Med-GENs and the highly
educated in all WB6 countries, further aggravating already existing or imminent labour shortages.
Finally, development policies which combine labour market and education policies with the high GDP
growth and structural change scenarios would result in labour shortages among the low-educated (either
within or shortly after the projection period) in Albania, Montenegro and North Macedonia and in excess
labour in Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia and Kosovo. Med-VETs would experience labour shortages
within or shortly after the projection period in all WB6 except for Kosovo. There would also be labour
shortages – either during or shortly after the projection period – among Med-GENs and/or the highly
INTRODUCTION 11
Working Paper 200

educated in Albania, Montenegro, North Macedonia and Serbia but excess labour among Med-GENs
and/or the highly educated in Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro and Kosovo.

It thus emerges from these scenario analyses that depending upon starting points (initial labour supply
composition by educational groups), as well as demographic and migration projections and evolving
supply and demand structures associated with different scenarios, different WB economies are faced
with differentiated challenges with regard to labour market excess supply and shortage situations in the
future, and therefore different mixes of policies will have to address these.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 discusses the different data sources while
Section 3 discusses the methodological framework and explains in detail how labour supply and labour
demand are modelled (Sections 3.1 and 3.2, respectively). Section 4 outlines the various scenarios.
Results from the scenario analysis are discussed in Section 5 while Section 6 summarises the key
findings and provides policy recommendations.
12 DATA SOURCES
Working Paper 200

2. Data sources

The data for this analysis are drawn from four different sources: First, the national (micro-level) labour
force surveys (LFS) of each WB6 country for an envisaged period of analysis from 2010 to 2019. Annual
LFS are generally available for the envisaged period of analysis for all WB6 countries except Kosovo,
where annual LFS data are only available for the period 2012 to 2019.

However, some labour force surveys are subject to substantial breaks, such as the ISCED break
between 2013 and 2014 in Montenegro and Serbia or the census break between 2010 and 2011 in
Albania. Furthermore, for Kosovo the labour force surveys between 2012 and 2014 are not fully
comparable owing to methodological changes and specific implementation conditions (see Leitner,
2021). Hence, in view of this, the analysis only uses LFS data for the years following any substantial
data breaks to avoid any break-related biases, namely:

› 2010-2019: Bosnia and Herzegovina, North Macedonia

› 2011-2019: Albania

› 2014-2019: Montenegro, Serbia

› 2015-2019: Kosovo

Since other data used in the analysis (see below) are only available until 2018, we also use annual LFS
data up to 2018 for the projections and we use LFS data for 2019 for the purpose of near-casting.

The analysis is conducted at the more detailed educational attainment level, where ISCED
classifications and labels as reported in each of the yearly LFS datasets are used to construct four
educational/skill groups. Following Leitner (2021), we distinguish the following educational groups:

› ‘Low’ for persons with primary and lower secondary education as their highest educational attainment
level (ISCED 1-2). Persons without any formal education were excluded from the analysis. 1

› ‘Medium’ for persons with upper-secondary or post-secondary education as their highest educational
attainment level (ISCED 3-4); this group is further differentiated by particular education tracks into
medium-general and medium-VET to account for the importance of vocational education and training
in the region:

­ ‘Medium-general’ (Med-GEN) for persons who followed the general upper secondary education
track (i.e. gymnasium/grammar school) and have a diploma from the general upper secondary
track as their highest educational attainment level;

1
Persons without any formal education account for less than 3% of the working-age population aged 15+ in each WB6
country.
DATA SOURCES 13
Working Paper 200

­ ‘Medium-VET’ (Med-VET) for persons who instead followed the vocational secondary track (and
attended 1-2-, 3- or 4-year VET programmes) and hold diplomas from one of the upper-
secondary VET programmes as their highest educational attainment level; and

› ‘High’ for persons with some form of tertiary education as their highest educational attainment level
(ISCED 5 and higher) which encompasses diplomas from higher education, Bachelor and
undergraduate studies (BA), Master’s degree and specialised studies (MA), and doctorate (PhD)
studies.

From the annual national LFS datasets, we extract information on the working-age population 15+, the
active and employed populations as well as net migration, and we further calculate skill-specific activity
rates, employment shares and the skill structure of the working-age population 15+.

Second, the analysis uses data from Eurostat such as its detailed unabridged life tables 2 differentiated
by age and gender as well as its detailed population statistics 3, also differentiated by age and gender.
Eurostat’s life tables are used for projections of the working-age population 15+ and are generally
available until 2018 for all WB6 countries except for Bosnia and Herzegovina. Eurostat’s population
statistics are available until 2019 for all WB6 countries except for Bosnia and Herzegovina. Bosnia’s
population statistics were taken from census information for 2013 from the Agency for Statistics of
Bosnia and Herzegovina (BiHAS). 4 For Albania, Eurostat’s population statistics were incomplete and
only available until the age of 84. The missing information for the age cohort 85+ was taken from the
statistical database of the Albanian Institute of Statistics (INSTAT). 5

Third, the analysis uses data from the United Nations, such as the UN unabridged model life tables 6
(from the ‘Coale-Demeny South’ model) for Bosnia and Herzegovina for which, as mentioned above, no
life tables are available. Furthermore, it uses UN international migrant stock 2019 data 7 which provide
estimates of international migrants by age, sex and origin for 1990, 1995, 2000, 2005, 2010, 2015 and
2019. The estimates are based on official statistics on the foreign-born or foreign population. From UN
international migrant stock 2019 data, net migration flows were calculated between 2010 and 2019 for
North Macedonia to complement net migration data calculated from annual LFS data (for more details
see section 3.1).

Finally, data on real GDP were taken from the wiiw Annual Database (ADB) which generally provides a
broad range of key macroeconomic and structural indicators for several CESEE countries, including all
WB6 countries. Data on real GDP were extracted from the ADB until 2019.

2
Generally, life tables are available in most countries from birth to age 90 years or beyond by single years of age (known
as unabridged life tables). Life tables are used to measure mortality, survivorship, and the life expectancy of a
population at varying ages. Source: demo_mlifetable.
3
Source: demo_pjan.
4
See: http://www.bhas.ba/data/Publikacije/Bilteni/2020/DEM_00_2019_TB_0_HR.pdf.
5
See: http://www.instat.gov.al/en/themes/demography-and-social-indicators/population/#tab2.
6
See https://www.un.org/en/development/desa/population/publications/mortality/model-life-tables.asp.
7
Available at: https://www.un.org/en/development/desa/population/migration/data/estimates2/estimates19.asp.
14 METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO
Working Paper 200

3. Methodological framework and key


characteristics of the baseline scenario

Sections 3.1 and 3.2 outline the underlying methodological framework. They explain how labour supply
and labour demand are modelled and projected into the future by means of trend extrapolation. They
also briefly discuss the key actual and projected determining elements of labour supply and labour
demand which enter and determine the baseline scenario.

3.1. LABOUR SUPPLY

The dynamics of labour supply by educational attainment level/skill group are captured by developments
in the active population and modelled as follows: formally, labour supply in country 𝑐𝑐 of skill type 𝑠𝑠 at
time 𝑡𝑡 (denoted 𝑆𝑆𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ) – i.e. the number of persons of a particular skill type active in the labour market – is
determined by the number of persons of working age in country 𝑐𝑐 with skill level 𝑠𝑠 at time 𝑡𝑡 (𝑁𝑁𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 )
multiplied by the skill-specific activity rate in country 𝑐𝑐 at time 𝑡𝑡 (𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ):

𝑆𝑆𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑁𝑁𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 (1)

The two key determinants of skill-specific labour supply are further specified as follows: The working-age
population 𝑁𝑁𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 in country 𝑐𝑐 of skill type 𝑠𝑠 at time 𝑡𝑡 is the product of the working-age population of skill
type 𝑠𝑠 in country 𝑐𝑐 at time 𝑡𝑡 − 1 and its skill-specific growth rate at time 𝑡𝑡, i.e. 𝑁𝑁𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝑁𝑁𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐−1 (1 + 𝑛𝑛𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ). In
the analysis, the working-age population (of a particular skill type) is defined as those aged 15+.

The activity rate 𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 is defined as the ratio of the number of active persons aged 15+ (employed and
unemployed) in country 𝑐𝑐 of skill type 𝑠𝑠 at time 𝑡𝑡 and the corresponding population aged 15+. It is
assumed to follow its longer-term trend and is projected into the future by means of annualised skill-
specific growth rates of the past 5 to 10 years (depending on data availability), defined as 𝑎𝑎𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 =
(𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ⁄𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 )(1/𝑛𝑛) − 1. 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 refers to the first year data are available (which differs across WB6
countries – see section 2 for a discussion) and 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸 to the last year data are available which is also the
starting point of the simulation. Hence, the skill-specific activity rate 𝑎𝑎𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 evolves as follows 𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 =
𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐−1 (1 + 𝑎𝑎𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ). After substituting both elements into equation (1), labour supply 𝑆𝑆𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 in country 𝑐𝑐 with skill
level 𝑠𝑠 at time 𝑡𝑡 is specified as follows:

𝑆𝑆𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝐴𝐴𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐−1 (1 + 𝑎𝑎𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 )𝑁𝑁𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐−1 (1 + 𝑛𝑛𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ) (2)

Figure 1 depicts observed and future projected skill-specific activity rates (labour force in % of the
working-age population 15+ of the respective skill group) for all WB6 countries (gender-differentiated
skill-specific activity rates are presented in Figure A.1 in the Annex) that are used in the baseline
scenario. It points to a clear ordering, irrespective of country considered: until 2018, activity rates were
always highest among the highly educated, followed by those with Med-VET and Med-GEN as their
highest level of education. By contrast, the low educated were always the bottom of the class. In this
METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO 15
Working Paper 200

context, Albania stands out since, compared to the other countries in the region, activity rates of all
educational groups were high. This is related to the high female employment rate (mainly in the large
agricultural sector) and the large informal sector in Albania.

Furthermore, projections foresee that activity rates of the low educated (following previous trends) will
continue to fall until 2030 in all WB6 countries except for Montenegro and Serbia, where slight increases
are to be expected. Projections also foresee a further fall in activity rates of those with Med-VET as their
highest level of education in Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina and North Macedonia and either an
increase or no change at all in the remaining WB6 countries. As concerns those with either Med-GEN or
high as their highest level of education, activity rates are projected to increase in the majority of WB6
countries (except for Albania and partly also for Montenegro). Moreover, except for Albania and Bosnia
and Herzegovina, projections foresee that the activity rates of the highly educated will exceed 80% at
some point over the period to 2030.

Figure 1 / Observed (until and including 2018) and projected skill-specific activity rates 15+

Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

As concerns projections of the working-age population 15+, information for each educational attainment
group is necessary. However, this data is not readily available from official sources (such as the EU, UN
or OECD which all only develop projections for the entire (working-age) population). Hence, in view of
this data gap, differentiated projections of the working-age population 15+ were developed in the course
of the analysis.

For this purpose, the cohort component population projection method is used which projects separately
for each birth cohort the components of population change, namely future births (fertility), deaths
(mortality), and net migration. In the analysis, we use one-year age cohorts and project one-year time
intervals.
16 METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO
Working Paper 200

Fertility

Since we take 2018 as the starting point of the simulation (some data are only available until 2018 – see
section 2 for more information), persons who will become part of the working-age population 15+ in the
next 12 years (i.e. until the end of the projection horizon – 2030) are already alive. Hence, there is no
need to project future fertility.

Mortality

To model future mortality, we take a standard approach and use country-specific unabridged life tables
to calculate annual survival rates. Survival rates are used to calculate the number of people who will be
alive at a future date in time. From the unabridged life tables, we use information on the total number of
person-years in the stationary population for each age interval (𝐿𝐿𝑥𝑥 ) to calculate 1-year survival rates 8 as
follows: 𝑠𝑠𝑥𝑥+1 = 𝐿𝐿𝑥𝑥+1 ⁄𝐿𝐿𝑥𝑥 where 𝑥𝑥 refers to the age interval. Since the survival rates in the WB6 countries
are quite stable between 2010 and 2018, we only use the survival rate for 2018 – the last year before
the beginning of the projection horizon. The survival rate of 2018, together with information on the sex-
specific age-composition of the population in 2018, is used to calculate the future ‘surviving’ working-age
population 15+.

This approach was feasible for all WB6 countries but Bosnia and Herzegovina. In particular, for Bosnia
and Herzegovina information on the sex-specific age-composition of the population is only available for
the year 2013 – in which a census was conducted. Furthermore, as there are no life tables for Bosnia
and Herzegovina, the detailed (age-specific) UN model life tables were used. The future Bosnian
‘surviving’ working-age population was then calculated based on detailed information on the sex-specific
age-composition of the population in 2013.

However, this approach only provides an estimate of the total working-age population 15+ which is not
differentiated by skill level. Hence, to get such a differentiation, the actual and projected working-age
population 15+ is further split into the four skill groups by means of the past and future projected skill
composition of the working-age population 15+. In this context, annualised growth rates of skill shares
(in the total working-age population 15+) between 2010 and 2018 (depending on data availability) were
used to project the skill composition of the working-age population 15+ into the future. Since the sum of
projected skill shares sometimes slightly deviated from 100%, an additional correction procedure was
applied to guarantee that the four projected skill shares always add up to 100%.

8
The survival rate of a particular age cohort into the next age cohort.
METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO 17
Working Paper 200

Figure 2 / Observed (until and including 2018) and projected skill composition of the
working-age population 15+

Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

Figure 2 depicts the observed and projected skill composition of the working-age population 15+ (as
used in the baseline scenario). For the period until 2018, it points to similar patterns in Bosnia and
Herzegovina, Montenegro and Serbia, where the group of Med-VETs dominates (with around 50%),
followed by the low educated, the highly educated, and, finally, the group of Med-GENs as the smallest
group. In North Macedonia, the group of Med-VETs and the low educated are largest with around 40%
each, followed by the highly educated and Med-GENs. By contrast, in Albania, the low educated are by
far the largest group (with between 50% and 60%), followed by the group of Med-GENs and the highly
educated. Unlike in all other WB6 countries, Med-VETs are a very small group, accounting for only
around 10% of the working-age population 15+. Similarly, in Kosovo, the skill composition of the
working-age population is also strongly skewed towards the low educated, who account for around 40%
of the working-age population 15+, followed by the Med-VETs and Med-GENs, who account for between
20% to 30%. By contrast, with only around 10%, the highly educated represent the smallest group.

Furthermore, projections foresee that except for Kosovo, the share of the low educated will continue to
decrease until 2030 in all other WB6 countries, particularly in Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina and
North Macedonia. In return, the shares of the remaining educational groups are projected to increase or
remain constant. Projections foresee that the increase in the share of the highly educated is most
pronounced in Albania. Compared with all WB6 countries, Kosovo, whose projections are based on a
relatively short period, stands out: while the share of the low educated is projected to further increase
and reach almost 50% until 2030, the remaining educational groups are all projected to fall until 2030,
albeit at a slow pace. The share of the smallest group of the highly educated is projected to fall below
10% until 2030.
18 METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO
Working Paper 200

Net migration

Migration is measured in terms of net migration, defined as the difference between immigration and
emigration. However, since there are no official statistics which report immigration and emigration by
educational attainment of migrants, data on net migration by educational attainment are taken from the
results of the cohort approach (see Leitner, 2021).

This approach uses national Labour Force Survey (LFS) data, whose rotating sample design does not
allow the same person to be tracked over time but whose stratification and weighting scheme allows the
identification of representative groups (age cohorts) that can be followed over time. In view of zero
fertility and in the absence of (substantial) mortality among the sub-population of interest (i.e. those aged
15 to 39), differences in the size and skills composition of an age cohort between two consecutive years
give a good approximation of the extent and skill composition of (cohort-specific) net migration in a year.
This is a reasonable assumption for the sub-population of interest (15-39), which is characterised by
zero fertility and little mortality. In terms of skill composition, it differentiates between the four educational
levels: Low, Medium-general, Medium-VET, and High. Generally, this approach is applied to the six
Western Balkan countries and the period 2010-2019. However, because of various substantial breaks in
the LFS data (as discussed in section 2 above), shorter periods were used in some WB6 countries
(2011-2019 for Albania, 2014-2019 for Serbia and Montenegro, and 2015-2018 for Kosovo) (for more
information, see Leitner 2021).

However, since net migration flows as estimated by the cohort approach are very volatile and available
for only a relatively short period, a trends-extrapolation approach could not be applied to determine
future net migration flows. Instead, we calculated skill-specific averages of annual net migration (as
calculated from the cohort approach) between 2010 and 2019 (depending on data availability) which we
used to approximate future (constant) skill-specific net migration flows.

This approach was feasible for all WB6 countries but North Macedonia, for which estimates from the
cohort approach were substantially lower than figures from other sources, such as the United Nations.
This discrepancy is related to the fact that there had been no census since 2002 in North Macedonia so
that emigration dynamics which have taken place since then are neglected and not reflected in the LFS
data, which uses the 2002 Population and Housing Census as a sampling frame. However, while the
cohort approach underestimates the true extent of net migration, it is still informative in terms of the
general migration structure by skill level. In view of this, we use UN migrant stock data, and calculate net
migration flows for the period 2010-2019 and then apply the skill structure of net migration from the
cohort approach to split the overall net migration flow into skill-specific net migration flows.

Figure 3 depicts yearly skill-specific net migration flows as calculated with the cohort approach, as well
as projected (constant) net migration flows for the projection period that were used in the baseline
scenario. It points to rather erratic patterns with periods of net immigration following periods of net
emigration in quick succession. In Albania, net migration flows of Med-GENs (during the first 5 years)
and the low educated (for the whole period) are particularly erratic and are related to two key events.
First, the global financial crisis of 2008 which led to a substantial economic depression in Greece and
Italy – the two key destination countries of Albanian migrants – and initiated a wave of mass return
migration, particularly among the low educated. Second, the mass emigration in 2015 of Albanians
METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO 19
Working Paper 200

seeking asylum in the EU and the subsequent return (by order) of unsuccessful asylum applicants in the
following years.

Furthermore, projected (mean) net migration flows vary considerably across WB6 countries. In Albania
and Bosnia and Herzegovina, projections foresee net emigration across all educational groups, without
exception. However, while projected net emigration is highest among the highly educated in Albania, it is
highest among the group of Med-VETs in Bosnia and Herzegovina. In Kosovo, projections foresee net
emigration among all educational groups – except for the group of Med-VETs – which is highest among
the group of Med-GENs. In all three countries, projections foresee net emigration among the highly
educated which is indicative of continued brain drain. However, the extent of brain drain varies across
countries. In the remaining WB6 countries, projected net migration patterns foresee net immigration
among the highly educated (i.e. brain gain). Projections also foresee net immigration among the group of
Med-VETs in Montenegro and North Macedonia and among the low educated in Serbia. By contrast, the
remaining educational groups are projected to experience further net emigration.

Figure 3 / Annual net migration flows as calculated with the cohort approach (until and
including 2019) and projected mean net migration flows

Note: For Kosovo the 2019 LFS data were not used in the cohort approach, as they appeared peculiar.
Source: Leitner (2021).

To provide a better idea of the extent of net migration in the WB6 countries, net migration numbers
should be considered in relation to the size of the population. Hence, Figure 4 depicts yearly skill-
specific net migration flows expressed as a share of the total working-age population 15+. It generally
highlights that until 2019 the shares of either net immigration or net emigration were relatively low and in
the range of -2% and +2% at most as in the case of Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina and Kosovo. In
the remaining WB6 countries, the share of net migration was even lower.

Furthermore, projected (constant) mean net migration flows also account for only a small share.
20 METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO
Working Paper 200

Figure 4 / Annual net migration flows as calculated with the cohort approach (until and
including 2019) and projected mean net migration flows as share of the total working age
population 15+

Note: For Kosovo the 2019 LFS data were not used in the cohort approach, as they appeared peculiar.
Source: Leitner (2021).

3.2. LABOUR DEMAND

Following Stehrer and Leitner (2019), labour demand dynamics are captured by and analysed in terms
of the implied employment growth rate, defined as the difference between (real) GDP growth and labour
∆𝐸𝐸 ∆𝑌𝑌 ΔΦ
productivity growth (defined as real GDP per employed person), or formally 𝑡𝑡 = 𝑡𝑡 − 𝑡𝑡 where 𝐸𝐸
𝐸𝐸𝑡𝑡 𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡 Φ𝑡𝑡

denotes employment, 𝑌𝑌 refers to real GDP and Φ to labour productivity. Expressed in annual growth
rates this becomes

𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝑦𝑦𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 − 𝜑𝜑𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 (3)

To model trends in the implied employment growth rate, the difference in the trend growth rates of GDP
and of labour productivity is used, each calculated as means over the whole period 2010-2018. This,
however, only gives an average implied employment growth rate of total employment 𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐 . To obtain skill-
specific employment levels 𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , the following two-step approach is taken: first, the average implied
employment growth rate is used to project total employment into the future as follows: 𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑡𝑡−1 (1 +
𝑒𝑒𝑐𝑐 ); second, past as well as future projected total employment levels are then multiplied by the
𝐸𝐸
respective past and projected skill-specific employment shares 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸ℎ𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 as follows
𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐

𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = 𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸ℎ𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 (4)

As concerns future skill-specific employment shares 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸ℎ𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , a linear trend model is applied and
annualised growth rates of employment shares of the past 5-10 years (depending on data availability)
are used to model their future evolution.
METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK AND KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO 21
Working Paper 200

Figure 5 shows the observed and projected employment shares by educational group that are used in
the baseline scenario. It points to a similar employment structure in Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Montenegro, North Macedonia and Serbia before 2018 with high employment shares among the group
of Med-VETs, followed by the highly educated, the low educated and, finally, the group of Med-GENs. At
around 60%, the employment shares were highest among the group of Med-VETs in Bosnia and
Herzegovina, Montenegro and Serbia. In Kosovo, employment shares are also highest among the group
of Med-VETs, followed by the highly educated, the group of Med-GENs and, finally, the low educated.
By contrast, Albania was characterised by a different employment structure which was dominated by the
low educated, followed by the group of Med-GENs and the highly educated. With only around 10%, the
employment share was lowest among the group of Med-VETs.

By and large, projections foresee a shift in the employment structure from the low educated and the
group of Med-VETs to the group of Med-GENs and the highly educated. This particular structural shift is
foreseen for all WB6 countries except for Montenegro. Projections for Montenegro, which are based on
a relatively short period, foresee a reverse shift until 2030, from the highly educated to the low educated
(with essentially no shifts among the remaining educational groups). Projections foresee that this low-to-
high structural shift will be most pronounced in Albania.

Figure 5 / Observed (until and including 2018) and projected skill-specific employment
shares

Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.
22 SCENARIOS
Working Paper 200

4. Scenarios

To shed light on potential future developments of labour supply and labour demand for each educational
attainment level and the role played by currently observable trends and potential future labour market
policies, education and training policies, migration flows and policies, likely GDP growth developments
as well as structural shifts in labour demand, we specify and analyse different scenarios.

In this context, the baseline scenario is the benchmark scenario based on extrapolations of past trends.
The remaining alternative scenarios are variants thereof and provide information about changes in the
results which stem from the variation in a single selected element of the model. However, alternative
scenarios are not specified with regard to their plausibility – i.e. how likely they are to be implemented –
but as possible reactions to emerging challenges in the labour market in terms of labour shortages and
surplus labour as projected in the baseline scenario for different educational groups which give rise to
possible opportunities for policy intervention. This is instructive and helpful as different potential policy
options can be identified which help to mitigate country and skill-specific labour market issues.
Furthermore, the magnitude of projected changes (on top of what is projected in the baseline scenario)
are intentionally kept small as large changes are very unrealistic in this short projection period.

At the time of writing, the COVID-19 pandemic has already lasted for almost a year and has had severe
impacts on societies, economies and labour markets. According to the World Bank (2020) all countries
in the Western Balkans have entered into partly deep recessions but are expected to gradually recover
in 2021 and 2022, with medium term growth expected to return to pre-crisis levels as the pandemic is
brought under control. Hence, in view of this positive medium-term outlook, no explicit COVID-19
scenario is built. Instead, it is assumed that the COVID-19 crisis is of a temporary nature and that the
Western Balkan countries will quickly return to their relatively high pre-crisis growth trajectories, which
makes a pessimistic growth scenario less likely and relevant.

In particular, the following scenarios are specified:

› Baseline scenario: extrapolation of past trends.

› No migration scenario: zero net migration for all educational groups.

› Labour market (‘activation’) policy scenario: increase in the (otherwise low or falling – see Figure 1
above) activity rates of the low educated over the projection period and constant activity rates (at the
2018 level) of Med-VETs in the case of falling activity rates. We take into account country-specific
situations in the design of this scenario: a moderate increase in the activity rate of the low educated by
5ppts in Albania (where activity rates of the low-educated are already relatively high), an increase in
the activity rate of the low-educated to the pre-projection level of 20% in Bosnia and Herzegovina and
Kosovo and to 40% in the three most economically advanced WB6 countries Montenegro, North
Macedonia and Serbia. And constant (instead of otherwise falling) activity rates of Med-VETs in
Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina and North Macedonia.
SCENARIOS 23
Working Paper 200

› High policy attention to education scenario: strong and active role of the state in upgrading the skill
mix of the working-age population 15+ which translates into a reduction in the skill shares of the low
educated and Med-VETs and a parallel increase in the skill shares of Med-GENs and the highly
educated over the projection period. We again take the country-specific structure into account:
reduction in the skill shares of the low-educated and Med-VETs of 15ppts in total in Albania,
Montenegro and North Macedonia, of 12ppts in Serbia, and of only 10ppts in Bosnia and Herzegovina
and Kosovo, where in view of the comparatively low level of economic development, a stronger
education policy intervention is less likely. Skill shares were reduced most in those skill groups which
account for the largest share of the working-age population 15+, namely the low-educated in Albania
and North Macedonia and Med-VETs in Montenegro. Due to similar skill shares in the pre-projection
period and similar projected skill share changes over the projection period, the skill shares of the low-
educated and Med-VETs were reduced to the same extent in Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia and
Kosovo.

› Joint labour market policy and high policy attention to education scenario: combination of both
scenarios (as defined above) to shed light on the overall effect of both supply-side policy interventions
together which, in isolation, address labour shortages either among the low-educated and Med-VETs
or among Med-GENs and the highly educated.

› High GDP growth scenario: future GDP growth is 1ppt higher than average GDP growth of the past 5
years (at a constant labour productivity growth rate).

› Structural change scenario: shift in labour demand from the low-educated and Med-VETs to more
educated groups, which could be due to skill-biased technical change and/or changes in the structure
of the economy towards activities requiring more advanced skills. Reduction in the employment shares
of the low-educated and Med-VETs by 10ppts in total over the projection period in all WB6 countries
and increase by 5ppts each over the projection period among Med-GENs and the highly educated.
Employment shares were reduced the most in those skill groups which had the largest potential for
structural change (i.e. the highest projected employment shares): hence, in all WB6 countries except
Albania, employment shares of Med-VETs were reduced the most, while in Albania employment
shares of the low-educated were reduced the most.

› Joint high GDP growth and structural change scenario: combination of both scenarios (as defined
above) which takes into account that higher growth and structural change are intertwined and ideally
occur together.

› Development scenario: this scenario combines four scenarios into one joint scenario, namely the
labour market policy intervention scenario, the high policy attention to education scenario, the high
GDP growth scenario, and the structural change scenario. It shows the overall net effect from all four
scenarios which would emerge if a country embarked on an improved economic development
trajectory which comes in the form of higher GDP growth and structural shifts in labour demand
towards more advanced skills.
24 FINDINGS
Working Paper 200

5. Findings

In what follows, simulation results of the various scenarios for labour supply (captured by developments
in the active population) and labour demand (captured by developments in the employed population) for
each of the four educational groups are presented and discussed, using levels of labour supply and
labour demand in 2018 as starting points (which is indicated by the vertical red line in each figure) for
projections until 2030.

5.1. RESULTS OF THE BASELINE SCENARIO

Figure 6 presents simulation results of the baseline scenario and shows that situations of labour
shortage and excess labour for different educational groups would coexist alongside each other over the
projection period (2019-2030) in the WB6. In particular, in several of the WB6 countries, labour
shortages would soon emerge, especially in the group of the low-educated and Med-VETs. In Albania
and Serbia, the low-educated would experience labour shortages towards the end of the projection
period. Due to the relatively stable projected supply of and the strong increase in the demand for the
low-educated, Montenegro would relatively soon experience a situation of labour shortage among the
low-educated. Furthermore, in Bosnia and Herzegovina and North Macedonia labour shortages of the
low-educated are also imminent and very likely to occur shortly after the projection horizon. Similarly,
Kosovo is also heading towards a situation of labour shortage among the low-educated, but this will only
materialise some time after 2030.

Furthermore, results suggest that labour shortages would also emerge among the group of Med-VETs,
especially in Albania, North Macedonia and Serbia which would however only materialise towards the
end of the projection period. Similarly, labour shortages among Med-VETs are also imminent in Bosnia
and Herzegovina and are likely to emerge shortly after 2030. By contrast, Med-VETs in Montenegro and
Kosovo would continue to experience non-negligible excess labour beyond the projection period.

The situation is more differentiated among Med-GENs and the highly educated. In Serbia, Med-GENs
would already face labour shortages towards the end of the projection period while they would do so
only shortly after the projection period in Albania and North Macedonia. By contrast, in Kosovo, similar to
Med-VETs, excess labour among Med-GENs would persist beyond the projection period. In Bosnia and
Herzegovina and Montenegro, the supply of and the demand for Med-GENs would be well aligned and
in a state of equilibrium.

Moreover, simulation results show that the highly educated would face labour shortages towards the end
of the projection period in Albania and North Macedonia and shortly after the projection period in Serbia
and Kosovo. By contrast, excess labour would continue to grow and persist beyond the projection period
in Bosnia and Herzegovina and Montenegro.
FINDINGS 25
Working Paper 200

5.2. RESULTS OF THE NO MIGRATION SCENARIO

Simulation results of the no migration scenario show little visible effects in the majority of WB6 countries
(see Figure 7). This is related to the fact that even though net migration flows by educational group – as
calculated and projected from the cohort approach – are sizeable in absolute terms, they only make up a
small share of the total working-age population 15+ (see Figure 5 above).

There are some exceptions to this, however. Particularly, in view of the substantial net emigration
among the group of Med-VETs in Bosnia and Herzegovina, zero net migration would help to alleviate the
imminent labour shortage and somewhat delay the date when the labour shortage is projected to occur
under the baseline scenario. Similarly, no net migration would also be beneficial for the low-educated in
North Macedonia and push the date when the labour shortage is projected to arise (following the
baseline scenario) further back. A situation of labour shortage would still occur shortly after 2030 though.

Furthermore, the comparatively high net migration flows among the group of Med-GENs and the highly
educated also have a visible effect in Kosovo and North Macedonia. Because of the more substantial
net emigration among Med-GENs (in both countries) and among the highly educated (in Kosovo only),
zero net migration would lead to an increase in the active population and either further enhance excess
labour supply (as in the case of Med-GENs in Kosovo) or help to somewhat delay the date when the
labour shortage occurs (as in the case of Med-GENs in North Macedonia and of the highly educated in
Kosovo). Conversely, under the zero migration scenario, the high estimated net immigration among the
highly-educated in North Macedonia would result in a substantial fall in their active population and
immediately cause labour shortages right at the beginning of the projection period.

5.3. RESULTS OF THE LABOUR MARKET POLICY SCENARIO

Simulation results of the labour market policy scenario show that the labour supply among the low-
educated and, where relevant, among Med-VETs would increase in response to an increase in their
activity rates (see Figure 8). For Albania, this would alleviate the labour market shortage of the low-
educated and delay the date when the labour shortage occurs. However, a labour shortage situation
would still arise shortly after the projection period which suggests that a stronger labour market policy
intervention is needed to avert any labour shortages in the longer run. In Bosnia and Herzegovina, North
Macedonia and Serbia, the labour shortage situation as projected by the baseline scenario would be
averted altogether and instead a situation of excess labour would emerge. Furthermore, in Kosovo, an
increase in the activity rate of the low-educated to the pre-projection period would significantly increase
their labour supply and create a situation of substantial excess labour. By contrast, in Montenegro, the
labour supply effect among the low-educated would be too insubstantial to alleviate their projected
labour shortage which suggests that a much stronger increase in their activity rate would be needed to
avert the imminent labour shortage.

Furthermore, the labour market situation of the group of Med-VETs would also improve. Particularly,
labour shortages – as projected by the baseline scenario – would be averted altogether in Albania and
postponed to the early 2030s in North Macedonia. By contrast, in Bosnia and Herzegovina, the labour
shortage situation as projected by the baseline scenario would be averted altogether and instead, a
situation of substantial and persistent excess labour would emerge.
26 FINDINGS
Working Paper 200

5.4. RESULTS OF THE HIGH POLICY ATTENTION TO EDUCATION SCENARIO

Figure 9 presents simulation results of the high policy attention to education scenario which assumes a
strong role of the state in upgrading the skill mix of the working-age population towards Med-GENs and
the highly educated. It shows that in all six Western Balkan countries except Kosovo projected labour
shortages among the low-educated and Med-VETs under the baseline scenario would further intensify.
In Kosovo, this policy would help to significantly lower the substantial excess labour among Med-VETs
but to also create a situation of labour shortage among the low-educated much earlier than under the
baseline scenario.

By contrast, in the majority of Western Balkan countries, labour shortages among Med-GENs and the
highly educated as projected by the baseline scenario would disappear and turn into excess labour. In
some WB6 countries, however, excess labour as projected by the baseline scenario would further
intensify in this context, such as among Med-GENs in Kosovo and the highly educated in Bosnia and
Herzegovina and Montenegro.

5.5. RESULTS OF THE JOINT LABOUR MARKET POLICY AND HIGH POLICY
ATTENTION TO EDUCATION SCENARIO

Figure 10 depicts simulation results of the joint labour market policy and high policy attention to
education scenario. It shows that the labour market situation of the low-educated and Med-VETs as
projected by the baseline scenario would further deteriorate and that in all WB6 countries labour
shortages would already emerge during the projection period. The only exceptions are the low-educated
in Bosnia and Herzegovina and Kosovo who would face excess labour beyond the projection period. In
Kosovo, excess labour among the low-educated would be particularly pronounced.

By contrast, in all WB6 countries, Med-GENs and the highly educated would instead experience
substantial excess labour.

5.6. RESULTS OF THE HIGH GDP GROWTH SCENARIO

Simulation results of the high GDP growth scenario highlight that higher projected future growth would
result in an increase in labour demand among all educational groups but to varying degrees (see Figure
11). Therefore, in contrast to the baseline scenario which projects labour shortages mainly among the
low-educated and Med-VETs until 2030, the six Western Balkan countries would experience labour
shortages among almost all educational groups until 2030.

Notable exceptions can be found in Montenegro and Kosovo. In Montenegro, both Med-VETs and the
highly educated would instead face labour shortages shortly after 2030. In Kosovo, apart from the highly
educated (where a labour shortage would emerge earlier), there would still be excess labour mainly
among Med-VETs but temporarily also among the low-educated and Med-GENs.
FINDINGS 27
Working Paper 200

5.7. RESULTS OF THE CHANGE IN ECONOMIC STRUCTURE SCENARIO

Simulation results of the change in economic structure scenario which assumes a shift in labour demand
from the low-educated and Med-VETs to Med-GENs and the highly educated are depicted in Figure 12
below. It highlights that, except for the low-educated in Montenegro who would still soon face a labour
shortage, situations of actual or imminent labour shortage among the low- educated and Med-VETs as
projected by the baseline scenario would be averted. Instead, in some WB6 countries situations of
excess supply would emerge such as among the low-educated in Albania, North Macedonia, Serbia and
Kosovo or among Med-VETs in Albania, Montenegro and Kosovo.

By contrast, Med-GENs and the highly educated would experience labour shortages in all Western
Balkan countries except for Kosovo. In Kosovo, this shift in labour demand would help to greatly reduce
excess labour supply within the projection period.

5.8. RESULTS OF THE JOINT HIGH GDP GROWTH AND THE CHANGE IN
ECONOMIC STRUCTURE SCENARIO

Simulation results of the joint high GDP growth and structural change scenario are shown in Figure 13
below. It points to a sizeable increase in labour demand among Med-GENs and the highly educated in all
WB6 countries, aggravating existing or imminent labour shortages. In fact, in all WB6 countries, Med-GENs
and the highly educated would face partly substantial labour shortages during the projection period.

Conversely, labour demand effects are rather moderate among the low-educated and Med-VETs and,
wherever more substantial, would either lead to or exacerbate excess labour. This is the case for the low-
educated in Albania, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo and for Med-VETs in Montenegro and Kosovo.

5.9. RESULTS OF THE DEVELOPMENT SCENARIO (COMBINING ALL


PREVIOUS SCENARIOS)

Simulation results of the development scenario point to important changes (see Figure 14). In particular,
while the low-educated in Albania, Montenegro and North Macedonia would still face labour shortages
either within or shortly after the projection period, those in Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia and Kosovo
would experience excess labour. Labour shortages of the low-educated are moderate in Bosnia and
Herzegovina and Serbia, but substantial in Kosovo.

Similarly, there would be labour shortages among Med-VETs in Albania, Montenegro, North Macedonia and
Serbia within the projection period and in Bosnia and Herzegovina sometime after the projection period. By
contrast, in Kosovo, Med-VETs (like the low-educated) would face high and persistent excess labour.

The strong increase in labour demand – which in many cases exceeds the more moderate increase in
labour supply – would also result in labour shortages among Med-GENs and the highly educated in
many WB6 countries. Specifically, there would be labour shortages – either during or shortly after the
projection period – among both Med-GENs and the highly educated in Albania, North Macedonia and
Serbia and among Med-GENs only in Montenegro. However, there would also be excess labour, such
as among Med-GENs and the highly educated in Bosnia and Herzegovina and Kosovo and the highly
educated in Montenegro.
28
Figure 6 / Labour supply and labour demand – baseline scenario

Working Paper 200


Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand. Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary
education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on
ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

FINDINGS
FINDINGS
Figure 7 / Labour supply and labour demand – No migration scenario

Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and active population (baseline) refers to labour supply under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

Working Paper 200

29
30
Figure 8 / Labour supply and labour demand – Labour market policy scenario

Working Paper 200


Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and active population (baseline) refers to labour supply under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

FINDINGS
FINDINGS
Figure 9 / Labour supply and labour demand – High policy attention to education scenario

Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and active population (baseline) refers to labour supply under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

Working Paper 200

31
32
Figure 10 / Labour supply and labour demand – Joint labour market policy and high policy attention to education scenario

Working Paper 200


Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and active population (baseline) refers to labour supply under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

FINDINGS
FINDINGS
Figure 11 / Labour supply and labour demand – High GDP growth scenario

Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and employed population (baseline) refers to labour demand under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

Working Paper 200

33
34
Figure 12 / Labour supply and labour demand – Change in economic structure scenario

Working Paper 200


Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and employed population (baseline) refers to labour demand under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

FINDINGS
FINDINGS
Figure 13 / Labour supply and labour demand – Joint high GDP growth and structural change scenario

Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand, and employed population (baseline) refers to labour demand under the baseline scenario.
Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper
secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

Working Paper 200

35
36
Figure 14 / Labour supply and labour demand – Development scenario

Working Paper 200


Note: Active population refers to labour supply, employed population refers to labour demand. Active population (baseline) refers to labour supply and employed population (baseline) to
labour demand under the baseline scenario. Educational levels are divided into four categories: Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general (upper secondary general
education/gymnasium), Medium-VET (upper secondary vocational education and training), and High (tertiary education), based on ISCED. Projections start in 2019.
Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

FINDINGS
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION 37
Working Paper 200

6. Summary and conclusion

This paper pursues a scenario analysis to shed light on the potential future developments of labour
supply and labour demand for different skill groups in the six Western Balkan countries. It differentiates
between four educational levels, namely Low (primary or lower secondary education), Medium-general
(upper secondary general education), Medium-VET (upper secondary vocational education and
training), and High (tertiary education). It takes a medium-term perspective and looks at a projection
period until 2030.

Simulation results of the baseline scenario, which rest on the extrapolation of past trends, show that
within the projection period (2019-2030), situations of labour shortage and excess labour for different
educational groups would coexist alongside each other in the WB6. In particular, in all WB6 countries,
the low educated would experience a situation of labour shortage either already within the projection
period or shortly after. The main factor here is the very low activity rates of the low-educated in the
Western Balkans. Furthermore, in Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, North Macedonia and Serbia, the
group of Med-VETs would also face labour shortages within or shortly after the projection period but
would continue to experience substantial excess labour supply beyond the projection period in
Montenegro and Kosovo. Similarly, Med-GENs would face labour shortages towards the end of or
shortly after the projection period in Albania, North Macedonia and Serbia but persistent excess labour
beyond the projection period in Kosovo. In Bosnia and Herzegovina and Montenegro, the supply of and
the demand for Med-GENs would be well aligned and in a state of equilibrium. Likewise, in Albania,
North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo, the highly educated would face labour shortages towards the end
of or shortly after the projection period but persistent and growing excess labour beyond the projection
period in Bosnia and Herzegovina and Montenegro.

Additional scenarios point to important country-specific labour market responses and indicate policy
options which could help to mitigate projected labour market imbalances for different skill groups:

For instance, policies which lead to zero net migration among all educational groups would have little
discernible effect in the majority of WB6 countries since net migration, while quite sizeable in absolute
terms, only accounts for a small share of the total working-age population 15+. There are, however,
some notable exceptions. In view of the sizable net emigration, zero net migration would alleviate the
imminent labour shortage among the low-educated and Med-GENs in North Macedonia, Med-VETs in
Bosnia and Herzegovina, the highly educated in Kosovo and would further enhance excess labour
supply among Med-GENs in Kosovo. Conversely, in view of the substantial net immigration, zero net
migration would cause a labour shortage among the highly educated in North Macedonia right at the
beginning of the projection period.

Labour market policies, which mainly aim to increase the activity rates of the low-educated and Med-
VETs, would lead to an increase in their labour supply and subsequently delay projected labour
shortages among the low-educated and Med-VETs in Albania and among Med-VETs in North
Macedonia. In some WB6, this would even turn projected labour shortages into excess labour supply,
38 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
Working Paper 200

such as among the low-educated and Med-VETs in Bosnia and Herzegovina or the low-educated in
North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo. In Montenegro, however, the labour supply effect among the low-
educated would be too small to alleviate their projected imminent labour shortage.

Likewise, education policies which put strong emphasis on upgrading the skill mix of the working-age
population towards Med-GENs and the highly educated would, on the one hand, exacerbate projected
labour shortages among the low-educated and Med-VETs in all WB6 countries (except Kosovo). On the
other hand, in most WB6 countries, such policies would turn projected labour shortages among Med-
GENs and the highly educated into excess labour and, in some WB6 countries, they would further
intensify projected excess labour, such as among Med-GENs in Kosovo and the highly educated in
Bosnia and Herzegovina and Montenegro.

Joint labour market and education policies would exacerbate labour market imbalances and lead to
labour market shortages among the low-educated and Med-VETs during the projection period in all WB6
countries, except for Bosnia and Herzegovina and Kosovo, where the low-educated would face excess
labour beyond the projection period. By contrast, in all WB6 countries, Med-GENs and the highly
educated would instead experience substantial excess labour.

Higher GDP growth would result in an increase in labour demand among all educational groups and,
with only a few exceptions, an increase in labour shortages within the projection period in all six Western
Balkan countries. By contrast, in Kosovo, there would still be excess labour among Med-VETs and
temporarily also among the low-educated and Med-GENs.

Structural change would generally avert actual or imminent labour shortage among the low- educated and
Med-VETs as projected by the baseline scenario and, in some WB6 countries, lead to excess supply
among the low-educated and Med-VETs in Albania and Kosovo, among the low-educated only in North
Macedonia and Serbia and among Med-VETs only in Montenegro. By contrast, Med-GENs and the highly
educated would experience labour shortages in all Western Balkan countries except for Kosovo.

Higher GDP growth and structural change together would lead to moderate labour demand effects
among the low-educated and Med-VETs but would result in significant increases in labour demand
among Med-GENs and the highly educated in all WB6 countries, which would aggravate already existing
or imminent labour shortages among Med-GENs and the highly educated and lead to partly substantial
labour shortages during the projection period in all WB6.

Finally, development policies which combine labour market and education policies with high GDP growth
and structural change would still result in labour market imbalances among the four educational groups,
as the purpose of the exercise was not to fine-tune the model to avoid any mismatches to exist even in
this (from a development perspective) positive scenario. In particular, the low-educated would face
labour shortages either within or shortly after the projection period in Albania, Montenegro and North
Macedonia and excess labour in Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia and Kosovo. Med-VETs would
experience labour shortages within or shortly after the projection period in all WB6 except for Kosovo,
where (like the low-educated) they would face high and persistent excess labour. Moreover, there would
be labour shortages – either during or shortly after the projection period – among both Med-GENs and
the highly educated in Albania, North Macedonia and Serbia and among Med-GENs only in Montenegro.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION 39
Working Paper 200

Conversely, there would be excess labour among Med-GENs and the highly educated in Bosnia and
Herzegovina and Kosovo and the highly educated in Montenegro.

The analysis points to important policy options. For instance, policies which lead to zero net migration
would not have a significant impact on labour supply over the time horizon of this modelling exercise and
would therefore not be particularly important in alleviating labour market imbalances in the WB6. The
only exception is North Macedonia (a beneficiary of return migration flows from intra-regional migration),
where such a policy should be avoided due to the detrimental effect it would have on the supply of the
highly educated. By contrast, labour market policies in terms of increases in activity rates would increase
the labour supply of the low-educated and Med-VETs, helping to avert labour market shortages.
However, the scope of labour policy action differs across the WB6 and is comparably small in Albania,
where activity rates of both educational groups are already high, but much higher in the remaining
countries. An important aspect in this regard is gender-specific differences in activity rates which tend to
be higher, the lower the level of education. Hence, increasing the activity rates of women is generally of
key importance. In view of observable effects, the increase in the activity rate among the low-educated
in Montenegro needs to be much higher to avert imminent labour market shortages. A higher activity
rate of women should be an important policy objective. Conversely, in Kosovo, a more moderate
increase would suffice to address projected imminent labour shortages among the low-educated. This
also applies to Bosnia and Herzegovina, where a more moderate increase in the activity rate would be
enough to address projected imminent labour shortages among Med-VETs.

Some important policy options can also be deduced from the development scenario which combines
increases in GDP growth and structural change with labour market and education policies and therefore
looks at a situation when countries have embarked on an improved economic development trajectory. In
addition to labour market policies, it also points to the importance of education policies for upgrading the
skill mix of the workforce. It shows that a shift in the skill mix of the working-age population towards Med-
GENs and the highly educated is indispensable in all WB6 to be able to meet the growing demand for
skilled labour from higher economic growth and structural change. It also highlights the fact that some
labour market imbalances would occur in almost every WB6 country – which is to be expected in such a
context. Despite applying an equally optimistic ‘development’ scenario as for the other WB6 economies,
labour market imbalances remain most pronounced in Kosovo where all educational groups experience
substantial excess labour. This suggests that in the case of Kosovo, much higher GDP growth would be
needed to address the substantial labour market imbalances that would arise in the development scenario.
40 REFERENCES
Working Paper 200

7. References

World Bank (2020). An Uncertain Recovery. Western Balkans Regular Economic Report No. 18.

Fotakis, C., and Peschner, J. (2015). Demographic change, human resources constraints and economic
growth – The EU challenge compared to other global players. European Commission (DG EMPL) Working
Paper 1/2015.

Leitner, S. (2021). Net Migration and its Skill Composition in the Western Balkan Countries between 2010 and
2019: Results from a Cohort Approach Analysis. wiiw Working Paper No. 197.

Peschner, J., and Fotakis, C. (2013). Growth potential of EU human resources and policy implications for
future economic growth. European Commission (DG EMPL) Working Paper 3/2013.

Stehrer, R., and Leitner, S.M. (2019). Demographic Challenges for Labour Supply and Growth. wiiw Research
Report No. 439.
8. Annex

ANNEX
Figure A.1 / Past and future projected skill-specific activity rates by sex

Source: LFS for Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Serbia and Kosovo; own calculations.

Working Paper 200

41
IMPRESSUM

Herausgeber, Verleger, Eigentümer und Hersteller:


Verein „Wiener Institut für Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche“ (wiiw),
Wien 6, Rahlgasse 3

ZVR-Zahl: 329995655

Postanschrift: A 1060 Wien, Rahlgasse 3, Tel: [+431] 533 66 10, Telefax: [+431] 533 66 10 50
Internet Homepage: www.wiiw.ac.at

Nachdruck nur auszugsweise und mit genauer Quellenangabe gestattet.

Offenlegung nach § 25 Mediengesetz: Medieninhaber (Verleger): Verein "Wiener Institut für


Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche", A 1060 Wien, Rahlgasse 3. Vereinszweck: Analyse der
wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung der zentral- und osteuropäischen Länder sowie anderer
Transformationswirtschaften sowohl mittels empirischer als auch theoretischer Studien und ihre
Veröffentlichung; Erbringung von Beratungsleistungen für Regierungs- und Verwaltungsstellen,
Firmen und Institutionen.
wiiw.ac.at

https://wiiw.ac.at/p-5820.html

You might also like