0% found this document useful (0 votes)
5 views22 pages

Pome Paper 1

This chapter discusses the application of complex systems theory to economic decision-making, highlighting the chaotic and non-linear nature of social systems. It emphasizes the need for adaptability in business practices due to rapid changes in consumer behavior and offers principles for effective policy-making in complex environments. The chapter also presents various applications illustrating the implications of complexity on small economies, corporate management challenges, and the importance of risk management in financial contexts.

Uploaded by

Aarsh Bajaj
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
5 views22 pages

Pome Paper 1

This chapter discusses the application of complex systems theory to economic decision-making, highlighting the chaotic and non-linear nature of social systems. It emphasizes the need for adaptability in business practices due to rapid changes in consumer behavior and offers principles for effective policy-making in complex environments. The chapter also presents various applications illustrating the implications of complexity on small economies, corporate management challenges, and the importance of risk management in financial contexts.

Uploaded by

Aarsh Bajaj
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 22

Economic decision making: application of the

theory of complex systems

Robert Kitt
arXiv:1208.1277v2 [q-fin.GN] 13 Apr 2013

Abstract In this chapter the complex systems are discussed in the context of eco-
nomic and business policy and decision making. It will be showed and motivated
that social systems are typically chaotic, non-linear and/or non-equilibrium and
therefore complex systems. It is discussed that the rapid change in global con-
sumer behaviour is underway, that further increases the complexity in business
and management. For policy making under complexity, following principles are of-
fered: openness and international competition, tolerance and variety of ideas, self-
reliability and low dependence on external help. The chapter contains four applica-
tions that build on the theoretical motivation of complexity in social systems. The
first application demonstrates that small economies have good prospects to gain
from the global processes underway, if they can demonstrate production flexibility,
reliable business ethics and good risk management. The second application elabo-
rates on and discusses the opportunities and challenges in decision making under
complexity from macro and micro economic perspective. In this environment, the
challenges for corporate management are being also permanently changed: the bal-
ance between short term noise and long term chaos whose attractor includes cus-
tomers, shareholders and employees must be found. The emergence of chaos in
economic relationships is demonstrated by a simple system of differential equa-
tions that relate the stakeholders described above. The chapter concludes with two
financial applications: about debt and risk management. The non-equilibrium eco-
nomic establishment leads to additional problems by using excessive borrowing;
unexpected downturns in economy can more easily kill companies. Finally, the de-
mand for quantitative improvements in risk management is postulated. Development
of the financial markets has triggered non-linearity to spike in prices of various pro-
duction articles such as agricultural and other commodities that has added market
risk management to the business model of many companies.

Robert Kitt
Department of Mechanics and Applied Mathematics, Institute of Cybernetics at Tallinn University
of Technology, Akadeemia tee 21, 12061, Tallinn, ESTONIA, e-mail: [email protected]
Swedbank AS, Liivalaia 8, 15040, Tallinn, ESTONIA, e-mail: [email protected]

1
2 Robert Kitt

Introduction

The study of complex systems has long been applied to the social sciences (cf.
[17, 18]). Financial markets and financial time series have been of special inter-
est among scientists as there is a well-accessible supply of data in time resolutions
ranging from seconds to years. Therefore, many scientists like physicists, math-
ematicians, engineers and others have been attracted by research of the financial
markets. Moreover, for about two decades for now, a branch of statistical mechanics,
econophysics, has dealt with the financial time series analysis (cf. [16, 11]) by using
models first developed in statistical mechanics (cf. [29] and references therein).
It is not surprising, that the academic literature has been populated with numerous
applications that confirm the non-linearity and/or complexity in social phenomena.
Interestingly, the first two noteworthy applications came from scholars (as opposed
to scientists) in the first half of 20th century: the works of Vilfredo Pareto of wealth
distribution (cf. [20]) and George K. Zipf (cf. [32]) of frequency distribution of
words in English language. But it was only in 1963, when Benoit Mandelbrot sug-
gested (cf. [12]) to use Levy stable distribution function as characteristics of finan-
cial market fluctuations; and in 1965 (cf. [13]) when he recommended processes
with long-term memory. In addition to stochastic phenomena, the deterministic
chaos also describes complexity. One of the first applications of chaos in economics
were reported by Tõnu Puu in 1989 (cf. [26]). The applications of econophysics
are mostly descriptive: typically the dynamical stochastic models are derived from
data analysis. By today, it is widely accepted, that majority of social phenomena
obeys non-linear properties or complexity. However, the research about the origin
of complexity in social sciences (including economics and financial markets) has
somewhat been unclear.
The aim of this chapter is to show that economic policy and decision making is
an application of the theory of complex systems. Hence, the economic systems can
very seldom be reduced to the linear, forecastable systems, which is the essence of
many economics and business textbooks. It seems that mankind has always searched
for some clarity or order in its arrangements. There has always been a drift towards
some hierarchy, or structure. Only in very recent past, perhaps due to the progress
of the so-called third industrial revolution (cf. section 1.2), there has been some
admittance that natural state of human society is better described by complexity;
non-Gaussian stochasticity or chaos. Or, to put it in another words, the equilibrium
economics has started to leave its space to non-equilibrium economics.
This chapter is organized as follows: first the complex or non-equilibrium phe-
nomena is discussed in an economic arrangements from theoretical point of view.
The rise of power-laws is theoretically motivated. The change in the behaviour of
consumers is discussed and the examples of power-laws are given. To conclude, the
guidelines are given for successful management of complex phenomena in business
and economics. Further, four applications based on non-equilibrium phenomena are
discussed. The first application discusses the opportunities for small economies in
changing market environment. The challenges of business managers is elaborated
and the chapter concludes with the two financial applications. The first of them dis-
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 3

cusses threats arising from excessive usage of debt and the second highlights the
importance of risk management in the future.

1 Complex social systems

The population has rapidly grown in past centuries. So have the social relationships
between humans beings. They form increasingly complex networks that have been
studied by many fields of science (e.g. complexity, network, chaos science). As it
emerges, many, if not all, human networks are scale free, i.e. they cannot be char-
acterized by some average or variance. For example: the question about average
company does not make sense, as in every industry there are giants and pygmies
side by side. Or perhaps the better example is the distribution of wealth: already ac-
cording to Pareto (cf. [20]), the 80% of the land is owned by 20% of the people. The
spreading of such systems is striking: internet routers, airport densities, book sales,
brand awareness are just few examples that obey so-called power-law, i.e. system
members obeying property x decreases with x in power of α . Mathematically the
power-law can be written:

P(x) ∝ x−α (1)


where P(x) denotes cumulative probability distribution of variable x. The power-law
leads to the scale invariance that can be explained as the system without character-
istic scale to measure it.
It is important to note that the complexity can be driven from ordinary func-
tional dynamic equations that just contain the non-linear element. Therefore the re-
searcher, economist or businessman needs to be very careful when building his/her
theory or business plan on some equilibrium in the system. Non-linear dynamics
typically leads to non-equilibrium systems; or to the equilibriums that are not stable.
The important question is to ask why? Why social systems lead to the power-laws,
scale invariance and chaos? In the following sections the complexity is theoreti-
cally motivated and the applications are offered for economic decision and policiy
making.

1.1 Motivation of complexity in social sciences

It has been said that a biological system is in equilibrium only when the cell is dead.
The question arises, what determines, if an economic system is under equilibrium
or not? In the Table 1, the conditions for certain equilibrium are compared with
equivalents of non-equilibrium.
The complexity can be easily increased by combining any of the factors above.
For example, a stochastic process with power-law distribution and long-range mem-
4 Robert Kitt

Table 1 Sources of non-equilibrium in socio-economic processes


Equilibrium Non-equilibrium Complexity resulting from non-
equilibrium
Deterministic linear dynamic Deterministic non-linear dy- Deterministic chaos
equations namic equations
Converging variance of ran- Diverging variance of ran- Power-law distribution
dom process dom process
Independent random vari- Time-related random vari- Fractality and long-term correla-
ables ables tions

ory is called multi-fractal process (cf. [14, 15]). As noted above, there is a number
of reports about economic systems obeying complex dynamics. However in eco-
nomics, one should always ask why the system is having non-linear properties?
The key difference between social and natural sciences is that the latter has super-
universal properties (laws of nature) that are present at any time in any place. The
social systems, according to the the best available knowledge do not obey such uni-
versal properties. Even if such universal law exists, then it is so vaguely defined,
that the dynamical equations cannot be derived. For example, the utility theory sug-
gests that all economic agents are striving for maximum utility. The utility, how-
ever, is not universally defined. Some consider money as a proxy for utility, some
add soft factors such as happiness. Poincaré has suggested that if the assumptions
of mathematical models are not valid, the models do not work. The same applies
to applications in economy and social science. Barabási and Albert have shown (cf.
below), that power-laws are arising from growth and preferential attachment of the
system. Therefore, we can conclude, that the power-laws are justified in the studies
of current economic conditions. But due to the lack of super-universal social laws,
one should always be critical of applying the model for future forecasting purposes.
Additionally, on has to evaluate the assumptions behind each model. If a socio-
economic model is empirically verified from past data; and it is claimed that this
model is universal (i.e. applies also to the future or is good for making predictions)
then it can be classified as historicism as elaborated by Karl Popper (cf. [24]).
To motivate existence of power-laws in social sciences one has to go back into
1950s when Hungarian mathematicians Paul Erdös and Alfred Renyi studied first
the random graphs (cf. [8]). Their work has guided studies of complex networks for
decades until increased research in the field started to question whether it is right
to assume complete randomness in real networks (such as internet) or expect some
organization of the system. If the network was random then the distribution of the
number of connections from arbitrary point in the network (denoted as degree dis-
tribution) would follow Poisson distribution. In 1999 Barabási and Albert reported
(cf [2] and references in [1]) that (degree distribution of) real networks deviated
significantly from expected Poisson distribution and obeyed a power law instead.
They also showed that the system must have growth and preferential attachment
properties to result power-law behaviour. Preferential attachment denotes that the
relationships between system members do not appear randomly, but new links pre-
fer to attach to connected members.
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 5

The complexity arises from non-linear components in the system. The sources
of non-linearity (but still deterministic and non-stochastic behaviour) are countless:
from micro-economics the supply and demand functions can be non-linear (cf [4]);
production cost does not have to be linear function of volumes (economists are call-
ing this scale-effect or scale-efficiency); and relationship between unemployment
and inflation (so-called Phillips curve) might be non-linear to mention just the few.
The power-law behaviour is the signature of underlying complexity of the system.
It is the key warning signal, that the system under consideration might have some
intrinsic non-equilibrium properties.
The discussion above has shown, that socio-economic system can easily become
complex system. The presence of power-laws, memory and deterministic chaos in
economic process has been motivated and empirically confirmed by many authors.
Next it is discussed whether the global economy has recently increased its complex-
ity and therefore the scientists and economists and businessmen have to change their
paradigms in interaction with surrounding economic problems.

1.2 Trends in consumer behaviour

The special editorial report devoted to the third industrial revolution was published
in the April 21st, 2012 issue of the British weekly the Economist. The Economist
claimed, that current changes in global economic development have exceeded the
usual evolutionary process and the global economy might be in the verge of the
revolutionary changes. This is, of course, a revolution in production methods, not a
political revolt against ruling classes.
The first so-called industrial revolution took place about two hundred years ago,
in the late 18th century in Britain with mechanisation of textile industry. In the fol-
lowing decades the idea of letting machines do the work (instead of physical work
by people) spread around to the other industries and countries. The second industrial
revolution started at the beginning of the 20th century in America and was charac-
terized by mass production. The iconic industrialist Henry Ford has said that any
customer can have a car painted any colour that he wants so long as it is black
(cf. [10]). In other words, the production processes were improved and tremendous
efficiency gains were achieved over the 20th century. More people than ever before
could allow themselves a car, computer, washing machine or any other industrial
product. Since the beginning of the industrial revolution, the improvements in qual-
ity of life for ordinary people are incomparable with the developments known since
the beginning of the civil society.
By the beginning of the 21st century the global economy has reached the point
where production is no longer an issue. The unit cost of production (in terms of
raw material, time or labour) is lower than ever before. But the problem has turned
and the production issues have been replaced with marketing issues. The supply
of goods is saturated and the consumers are more selective than ever before. Con-
sumers want to have individual solutions for the price of mass production and all
6 Robert Kitt

this should be available instantly. Auto-mobile industry, the flagship of the second
industrial revolution, does not produce for the retail consumers identical cars any
more. The keywords for the third industrial revolution are: customer centric, flex-
ibility, speed, preciseness. The consumers are now literally dictating the market.
The importance of intermediaries and whole-sellers (who depict the choice for con-
sumers) is decreasing in time. Thanks to the possibilities of e-commerce, even the
physical constraints do not matter any more. Everyone can shop online.
These trends have major (or revolutionary) effect to the production. The efficient
manufacturing of big quantities is not suitable for changed consumer behaviour. Not
only the production quantities, but the logistics should match the changed environ-
ment. The Economist makes case that the productions is therefore returning to the
proximity of consumers. Consumer preferences are subject to complex decision-
making. Therefore, the demand side of the economic supply/demand relationship
is expected to create clustering (i.e. power-laws). In addition, the consumer choices
are very sensitive to the small details. In physics, it denotes the sensitivity to the
initial conditions, that leads to the chaotic behaviour of the system.

1.3 Rise of power laws in the World economics and trade

Further it is analysed how recent societal trends have increased the complexity. The
model of Barabási-Albert (cf. [2]) is used. To recall, the model claims that the sys-
tem must have properties of growth and preferential attachment to result the power-
law behaviour. It will be showed that many social and economic systems obey those
two properties and therefore the power-law behaviour is theoretically motivated.
First the growth component is discussed. In order to motivate the complexity,
the system must have the change in its size. To put it inother words, the number
of social agents must vary in order to have power-law in social system. It will be
quite easy to show that this is the case in many of the social systems. The first
and foremost, the population of the Globe has reached 7 billion by 2012; and the
rate of increase as been also increasing. From a pessimistic note from economic
perspective, the increase has not been in the most developed parts of the Globe
and therefore it might not contribute to the increased complexity. This note can be
ignored because of the decreased barriers in the global trade. The World is becoming
increasingly global in its trading affairs. The local differences are fading away and
therefore the increase in population is reaching to the global markets. Therefore, the
increased trading relations also increase the number of potential customer for each
company regardless of its physical location. As it will be shown later, this brings
unique opportunities for the smaller countries.
The second requirement from Barabási-Albert model for arising the power-laws
is preferential attachments. This phenomenon denotes the behaviour, where social
agents prefer to connect with the agents that have more connections at first place.
When intuitively true, it can be proved by ruling out the opposite. Let us consider an
arbitrary social system, that is related to the human behaviour. Preferential attach-
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 7

ment does not exist, when the decision making over the population is completely
random. Whereas there is definitely an element of randomness involved, any of the
product or service for the sale contains an unique value proposition that influences
decision making. The examples of those are: historical habits, expensive marketing
campaign, cheap price of the product, well-known (and prestigious) brand, lack of
alternatives and others. With the growth and preferential attachment components in
place, the Barabási-Albert model has its pre-conditions in place and the systems
under observation obey power-law. This is a matter of fundamental importance in
social and economic affairs: with the rise of power-law the systems become scale
invariant, i.e. they loose the meaning of properties of average and standard devia-
tion.
The power-law in stock price fluctuation is caused because investors have their
preferences to buy stocks by definition (hopefully nobody picks stocks randomly)
and the number of investors in given company is continuously changing (growing or
decreasing). The number of internet websites and academic papers grows; and is is
likely that more popular websites or papers are getting more and more connections
to them. Number of words in any language is growing; people prefer to use only
limited amount of them and therefore the distribution of word usage follows power-
law (i.e. Zipf’s law). The wealth of the individuals grow; but more money in absolute
terms is earned by the ones with higher initial capital (although the percentage of
the return might be higher with those of low initial capital). The list can easily be
prolonged and the power-law is observed in very many social systems. But before
the usage of its applications, it would be still wise to consider, if the system has the
instrinsic properties to yield power-law behaviour.
As a final note, the preferential attachment refers to the free will of the agent.
This is of course the cornerstone of free will (in political terms) or free capital-
ism (in economic terms). The changes in political regimes in the past decades have
positively contributed to share of people who are currently part of global capitalist
system. Those people have started to express their free political and economic will.
And the latter has significantly contributed to the rise of the demands from con-
sumer side. Coupled with the technological advancements, inter-connectivity due to
the internet, the global preferential attachments have most likely gone through qual-
itative change that gives the rise of complexity and power-laws in countless social
applications.

1.4 About social predictions and economic forecasts

Forecasting and socio-economic determinism has been a desire for the mankind
since Plato. Karl Popper, in his seminal book of The Open Society and Its Enemies
(cf. [23]), analyses brilliantly the problems arising from unvertainty and openness
of the society. According to the Popper, Plato saw and understood very well the
changes in the society that have started to transform from tribalism to the democ-
racy. Plato’s response was to freeze all of the changes and return to the old, closed
8 Robert Kitt

society. The key difference between open and closed society is that in the former
the individual decisions of the people almost did not exist; all of their choices were
pre-determinied by customs of the tribe or society. But this was also mental relief,
as people did not bear any responsibility for such decisions. In open society, on
contrary, people have to decide by theirselves about their actions, but they are also
responsible for their actions. During the course of past two millenia, the problem of
Plato has re-occurred a number of times (cf. numerous references in Popper’s The
Open Society and Its Enemies [23]) with the issues circling around (i) individual
freedom and responsibility of the person and/or (ii) collective welfare of the nation
and the means to achieve this.
It can be discussed, wheather the tribalism was truly closed society or not (at
the end of the day, the laws of nature still applied to the society), but it has no
relevance in the current context. The one and truly relevant point is that the society
is a complex system with countless interconnections and non-linear relationships. It
cannot be reduced to the linear system for the forecasting purposes. The power-laws
and scale invariance (i.e. lack of characteristic measures such as averages or standard
deviations) simply cannot allow to ignore one-off, big time changes. Critical Mass,
a book by Philip Ball (cf. [3]), describes wide variety of such phenomena. Fooled
by Randomness and Black Swan by Nassim Nicholas Taleb (cf. [30, 31]) adds the
flavour of the financial markets.

The problem of the Analyst

Many fields of human activities celebrate calendar year by nominating and choos-
ing the best performer of the year. Among others, the best athletes, artists and ar-
chitects get selected. From another perspective, various magicians are continuously
providing the forecasts for the coming periods. Regardless of the used methods
(tarot cards, celestial bodies or other tools), one can be very sceptical about the
social forecasts, as once again, there are no super-universal laws that describe the
social systems. However, all kinds of forecasts are very popular, as they provide a
sort of security that people would like to have in their lives. This is especially true
for the stock markets, but also for various aspects of people’s personali lives. A very
interesting book about forecasting (cf. [28]) was written by Ian Rowland, a British
magician, who has debunked various aspects of paranormal phenomena.
What is the role of forecasting in economic decision making? Certainly the stock
exchange prices are driven by various forecasts: the ones drawn by the companies
themselves and the others offered by analysts in investment banks. In addition, the
micro economic (or company level) forecasts are dependant on the general macro
economic situation; and further the predictions of economists influence the forecasts
of the stock analysts. Note, that the current passage is by no means restricted to the
stock exchange, but the logic offered can be easily applied to the other fields of fi-
nance (e.g. agriculture as discussed in section 5). But are such predictions contribut-
ing to the economic decision making, or perhaps vice versa, make things worse?
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 9

As discussed in section 1.1, the mathematical models should be dropped, if the


assumptions are no longer valid. Further, the only super-universal law in economics
can be formulated as follows:

Revenues − Costs = Pro f its (2)

Therefore, the only reasonable economic forecast relies in simple modelling, where
revenues and costs are depicted. If the model works on paper, it may also work in
real life. If the model does not work on paper, then there are very little chances that
the business will work in real life. However, typically economic models contain non-
linear inputs because of stochasticity (variability of input and/or output quantities),
non-linearity (clustering of purchases or sales of the company) or other reasons,
that make the forecasting pointless. For example, in order to forecast stock price
the analysts must account not only for the company-specific reasons, but as well as
behaviour of other investors in the market. This equals of forecasting the social (i.e.
complex) systems.
The problem of the analysis broadcasted in popular media includes the following
shortcomingis: (i) missing error estimates, (ii) missing back-tests of the achieved
results; and (iii) missing personal responsibilites. In physics, all experiments are
conducted with mandatory error estimates. In economics and financial markets, the
error estimates are never given that would leave the user of such forecast with no
idea of the accuracy of the forecast. Further, even if the forecast proved to be right,
there is never no information given about the method itself, or the reliability of
the forecast in slightly different initial conditions. From section 1.1, the complex
systems are very sensitive to the initial conditions. Therefore, if no additional in-
formation is given, there result is not qualitatively different from the random luck.
Thirdly, no analyst is responsible for their results, that are used in media. So, even
if the results are not correct, the analyst typically bears no responsibility for the
advice. Why should anyone take such forecasts seriously?
The critique above was not intended to dismiss all aspects of economic analy-
sis. As noted previously, the models that build on the pre-determined rules can be
verified and falsified (as defined by Popper in The Logic of Scientific Discovery
[22]). However, the critique is addressed to the blind belief of any of the forecasts
of complex social systems.

1.5 Possibilities of handling the complexity

The power-laws and chaotic processes have already put many companies out of
business and most probably will do also in the future. In this section some stylized
approaches are suggested in order to manage the changed economic environment.
10 Robert Kitt

Openness and international competition

The most fascinating thing about the globalization and international integration is
the international competition. The competition, by definitions means threats and op-
portunities. The competition forces producers to continuous improvements in order
to appeal the consumers. The definition of the consumer and the market has changed
in the past decade; so has the demand of the consumers. About 20 years ago, the con-
sumer potential of any product was determined by population living in certain area
and having relevant income level. Due to the advances of internet, the geographic
borders have vanished. The physical stores are there to remain for food and other
daily products (and perhaps daily services such as hair-dressers, car washes etc). On
the same time, the dealerships for consumer staples have to reconsider their busi-
ness plan. The market for all products and services has become more competitive
and therefore the following can be generalized: the producers must aim to produce
globally best product since the consumers want to buy globally best products. Ob-
viously, the definition of the product can include various components; as described
by value proposition in (cf. [6]). If the local language is the part of the value propo-
sition (for example for a video game), then the producer can claim, that he/she is
doing the best product in local language; that sells with higher price than the English
language equivalents. This might be true, and the producer might be successful, but
in conventional market conditions, the producer always bears the risk that the con-
sumer’s preferences change and s/he is out of business. Therefore, given the rise
of competition and higher demands from consumers, the producers must always be
open to the innovation and assume the global competition; even if they are servicing
only local consumers.

Tolerance and variety of ideas

Hayek has said (cf. [9]) that the society cannot be measured in a single scale of
more and less. The number of opinions might be as large as the number of people.
The democratic society respects all opinions that are not dangerous to others. The
dominance of the single opinion is also dangerous as it can be wrong. In the context
of economic management, due to the complexity, the direct and indirect outcomes
of decisions are never clear. Therefore it is important to consider and tolerate within
society or company, but also in department or family level the variety of opinions in
decision-making. The next question arises from the implementation of the decision.
Should it be done with one big bang or slowly, step by step. As it was discussed
above, the complex systems tend to be non-equilibrium. So, every big step may
drive the unit under discussion quickly out of equilibrium. Therefore it is important
to manage step by step. In popular reading, it is also known as method of trial-and-
error. Should the idea or decision prove to be wrong; one can easily reverse the
situation and try other solutions.
The pessimist in complexity phenomena might argue that the piecemeal imple-
mentation of any plan never allows to achieve extraordinary results. A wise person
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 11

never puts all eggs into one basket. Whether the company is an established one or
a start-up, the owners very seldom take single risks with all of their capital. If the
new business venture is still pursued, with all the capital under risk; the successful
outcome cannot still be classified as wise, but rather lucky.
As the final note, the variety of ideas very seldom rises from single source of
knowledge. Therefore, along with continuous innovation, the variety of ideas should
be always searched for. One original sources of the ideas is to look at the intersec-
tions of various disciplines. People with different background are more likely to
produce truly innovative ideas as opposed to similar people. Interdisciplinary fields
of science, business or social life are more likely to yield new ideas that expand
mankind’s knowledge and welfare.

Low dependence on external help

External interference into any physical system disturbs the system. As discussed
previously, the small disturbances can yield the qualitatively different outcome of
the system under chaos. But what if the disturbances are permanent and/or large?
Then the system has to be redesigned and all of the dynamic equations should be
rewritten. The social systems behave analogically. The small disturbances are per-
haps new competitors; or small new technological innovations. The technological
innovations can lead also to the new industries and big changes, but this is also
part of the usual market behaviour. However, the government interference into eco-
nomic system is big disturbance that reshapes the whole economy in general or any
industry in particular. The government interference creates market distortions that
companies should comply with. This can be advantageous (in case of subsidies)
or disadvantageous (rules and regulations). Important is to note that companies un-
der global competition may respectively have opportunity or threat to survive. The
government interference is very powerful tool that influences the system. Under
complexity, it can therefore with the fraction of the second, reshape the destinies
of many companies and workers in those companies. The same is true also for the
demand side of economy. With the increased regulations the consumers might pay
higher prices.
To summarize, the companies should be aware of the distorted market models,
since they are competing internationally. This is also the case, if the distortion is
beneficial in short term, and is creating the advantages. The threat is that the man-
agers might be deluded from observing international competition; and if the public
support disappears, they may find themselves in trouble.

Qualitative improvements in risk management

The increased complexity demands the qualitative improvements in risk manage-


ment. There are various sources where the company or private individual can be ex-
posed to the complexity. It is utmost critical that the company will be aware of such
12 Robert Kitt

phenomena. It has to understand the sensitivity of its cash-flows of the variables it is


exposed. Further, the risk mitigation plan should be devised. It is important to stress,
that not all risks can be or should be hedged. After all, the companies typically earn
money for risk taking. Hence, the good risk management is not risk minimisation,
but risk optimisation. But one can optimise only after the risks are identified and
quantified. This requires dedicated attention from to top management or owners of
the company; after all, it is their interest that the company would not suffer against
unforeseen risks. And all of the risks arising from complexity are not seen without
proper attention. The risk management issues are also discussed in section 5 of this
chapter.

2 Application: Opportunities for small economies

Countries, like companies are obeying power-law, if their size (in terms of popula-
tion or economic output) is observed. It is tempting to ask that who will win from
the third industrial revolution (cf. section 1.2) or from complexity or combination
of both. Instead it is asked, what are the opportunities for small economies to bene-
fit from the underlying changes in the global economy. Note, that the definitions of
economy and small are not given in this context. It can apply for the nation, com-
pany, or family.
The value proposition of the production company in the new environment can be
elaborated as follows: first and foremost, the changes in consumer behaviour call
for individual solutions. In every industry the consumers are expecting the tailor-
made solutions that are different (or at least look different) than the others. This
calls also for decreased production quantities which, in turn, affect production pro-
cesses. Therefore, the flexibility of production is playing increasing role in global
competition. The producer or service provider has to be quickly able to adjust to the
new orders; the delays in production drive up production costs. The flexibility has
also other meanings: it is ability to quickly introduce new products or variations of
existing ones; it implies quick and reliable delivery of the goods; it raises a question
of whether the company should enter or exit new elements in product value chain.
This means that the company may decide to start to produce more value-adding
components to existing products; or to increase the production cycle (i.e. start pro-
ducing also goods that it was previously buying in). Excelling in production does
not necessarily make the company successful as the products also need to be sold.
But selling has not that much changed due to the complexity. There is just another
dimension; that is to provide the value proposition above: flexibility, individual so-
lutions, small quantities, efficient production and quick delivery. However, since the
competition in production side is also growing the reliability and business ethics of
each company as well as nation starts to play increasingly large role. The successful
companies cannot allow themselves to break their promises or violate oral or written
agreements.
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 13

The concept of flexibility has so far only limited reach in academic literature.
Only very recently, a group lead by prof. Luciano Pietronero has devised a new
method to rank the countries. It opposes two-hundred-year old concept (cf. for ex-
ample [27]) of economic specialization (and of static equilibrium) and ranks the
countries by complexity of their products (cf. [5]). The suggestion of their method
is to study the complexity (and variety) of the exported products that serves the
proxy to the future well-being of that country (as measured by GDP).
The small economies can use this change in economic landscape for their benefit.
It is clear advantage as compared to the big economies, that are used to make huge
quantities of similar products. Obviously, bigger economies adjust as well; but their
production efficiency advantage is disappearing. The small economies have to be
agile in finding new opportunities. They have to strive for the best product in the
world and not for a less. Continuous innovation and rethinking of the business model
is of benefit. They must continuously try new things; if one does not try, one cannot
also succeed. But the risks have to be carefully measured. It is dangerous to get
stuck with single buyer of the production: not only this makes negative impact to
the agility, but also the buyer might start to push down the margins of the producer.
Finally, the small economies should be counting only to themselves. It applies to
the national level, but also to the company level. No government subsidy will make
any of the companies to produce or sell better. From public point of view it has to
be assured, that none of the productions is discriminated by other countries; and the
government might want to help with investments. But the companies have to find
the customers by them selves. No government support (by small country) will help
to reshape the global consumer behaviour.
To conclude, the increased complexity (due to globalization, usage of internet
and liberalized markets) opens the opportunities for the small economies. With flex-
ible production, reliable business ethics and managed risks, they have all chances to
succeed.

3 Application: Changes in business management

The fact that the world becomes more and more complex was already discussed
above. It is reasonable to assume that business environment also changes and be-
comes more and more complex.

3.1 Problem of trustful sources: success-driven business literature


ignores the failures

There is a myriad of books written about business and management, that typically
state or study trivialities: buy cheap and sell expensive; in order to succeed the
unique value proposition needs to be developed and exploited. There are plenty
14 Robert Kitt

of tools to determine the strategy. For example, one only needs to draw Porter’s
five forces (cf. [25]). In the course from determinism to chaos more individual ap-
proaches start to prosper. Blue Ocean Strategy (cf. [6]) is the method where value
proposition of individual product/service is modified; similarly the methods de-
picted by Moskowitz and Gofman (cf. [19]) about segmentation. However, what
seems to be very common for the conventional business books is absolute igno-
rance towards survivorship bias: namely all of the examples brought forward are
positive. At least in theory (and much in practice) there are failing business strate-
gies. However, those seem to be missing from popular literature: almost always the
theories are backed with the success-stories. To summarize, all of the (successful)
books write about successful strategies, leaving unanswered the empiricist’s ques-
tion: what made a strategy fail? It would be interesting to speculate, how many
product launches, business ventures, restructurings and similar has to fail in order
to produce single successful one.

Unsuccessful response to the complexity

In late 1990s, before the burst of so-called high-tech bubble, the popular buzz-word
was New Economy. This term was coined mostly to describe the technological ad-
vancement. But not only. It was also symbol of boundary-less activity, agility, in
some cases loose financial management. For some time there existed a claim that the
company of the New Economy does not have to be profitable; and the right assess-
ment of the value of the company (i.e. share price) was not done by money earned
to shareholders, but clicks received by company’s web-site (there was even price-
to-click ratio introduced to be a better proxy than price-to earnings ratio). By today
such party is clearly over; performance management is back in stage and companies
are counting money more than ever before. As an aftermath of recent economic and
financial crisis, the regulations and standards in many sectors (including financial,
industrial and services) are about to increase. The companies have to strive for order
in management and market relationship in order to survive.
Yet, the 21st century has not made the shareholders rich. The performance of the
biggest stock indices in US and Europe has been modest, if not negative, in the past
decade. If not nominally, then volatility-adjusted performance for sure. (Note that
the aim of this chapter is not to discuss the statistical properties of stock indexes;
there are most definitely market segments that have posted life-high returns). At the
same time companies around the globe have succeeded in many paradigm-changing
innovations: the usage of Facebook, smart-phones, hybrid cars or renewable energy
has increased by order of magnitude. It would be probably hard to find a single cor-
porate executive who can claim that their efficiency has not risen. Additionally, the
financial management of companies (and public sector) is better than ever before.
The market has done its job perfectly: companies are fitter than ever before. But
as discussed above, the consumers are also demanding more than ever before. The
complexity has risen, but the response has not yet been successful.
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 15

3.2 Through Chaos to Determinism

To summarize at this point: corporate executives (as well as public administrators)


have to respond to both: (i) increased consumer demands for value innovation (that
drives up costs); and (ii) increased demands from regulatory and financial insti-
tutions. And, as companies become more and more competitive, there is the third
dimension: ongoing competition for the labour force. What is the right management
approach in this context? Tom Peters describes in his classic book In Search for
Excellence (cf. [21]) various management styles that make companies successful.
However, it seems that all of his advice is bound to linear evolution - that should be
amended in the context of non-linear or non-equilibrium economics.

An illustrative model of chaos in economics

In this section an illustrative model is constructed in order to demonstrate the emer-


gence of chaos from simple micro economic relationship.
Consider an arbitrary company that sells an arbitrary good. It is simplified that
the company is selling the unit labour hours; and the quantity available for sales (i.e.
supply) at time t is denoted as qS . In this model, the quantity for sales can be also
interpreted as the satisfaction of the employees - the bigger the number of employees
the higher is the satisfaction of the employees. The customers are purchasing the
same unit labour hours and their demand (at time t) is denoted as qD . It can also
be interpreted as the satisfaction of the consumers - the more they are buying the
higher the satisfaction. At time t the transactions are concluded at the price p; the
wealth of the shareholders is W ; and the employees are compensated at the unit rate
of C. Therefore, the full cost of production is qSC; the revenues of the company are
qD p. From these simple definitions the following equations are derived.
The satisfaction of the employees is positively related to the compensation. The
compensation (i.e. salary) has to be higher than critical value C0 ; otherwise the em-
ployees are leaving.
dqS
= γ (C − C0 ) (3)
dt
The satisfaction of the consumers is negatively related to the price. If the price is
higher than critical value of p0 the consumers will not conduct any transactions.
dqD
= δ (p0 − p) (4)
dt
The relationship between shareholders and employees is also positive: if the
shareholders are doing well, they tend to raise the salaries of the employees.
dC
= βW (5)
dt
16 Robert Kitt

If the supply is larger than the demand, the price has to be lowered. It is assumed
that the price is not related to the wealth of shareholders.
dp
= −α (qS − qD ) (6)
dt
Finally, the change in shareholders’ wealth equals to revenues less costs.

dW
= pqD − CqS (7)
dt
Merging Equations (7) and (5) yield following:

d 2C
= β (pqD − CqS ) (8)
dt 2
To summarise, the micro economics of simple company can be presented in a
form of system of ordinary differential equations.

dt = γ (C − C0 )
 dq
 S

 dqD = δ (p − p)

dt 0
d 2C (9)
 2 = β (pq D − CqS )
 ddtp

dt = −α (qS − qD )

Due to the non-linearity, the emergence of chaos can be predicted. It is not at-
tempted to solve these equations analytically. However, it is easy to demonstrate that
the numerical solutions inevitably lead to the chaos. In figure 3.2 the happyness of
the consumers (variable qD ) is plotted against salaries C. From economic point of
view the vertical axis demonstrate the quantities demanded by the customers (qD ).
In both plots the quantities in demand drop to the low territories, but recover later. In
chart (b) the value of qD is even negative at some point. In real economic situations,
this represents very bad business conditions and perhaps even the bancrupcy of the
company.
Although very primitive, the illustrations carried out in this section demonstrate
very well the chaotic and complex nature of the business conditions. With small-
est change of the parameter α the qualtitative difference between those two situa-
tions becomes apparent. Therefore the policy makers in social systems (including
business and economics) have to be very careful with their decision-making. Only
smallest change in any of the parameteres can lead to the qualitatively different out-
comes.

Chaotic management approach

It is proposed to implement a chaotic management approach in order to succeed in


the 21st century. Chaos, as defined in physics, refers to the dynamical process that
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 17

Fig. 1 C-qD plot with the parameters. (a) α = 0.6; δ = 0.2; γ = 0.3; β = 0.005; C0 = 100; p0 =
100. Initial conditions of the system: qS (0) = 10; C(0) = 101; dC(0)/dt = −0.2 and p(0) = 101.
(b) α = 0.525; δ = 0.2; γ = 0.3; β = 0.005; C0 = 100; p0 = 100. Initial conditions of the system:
qS (0) = 10; C(0) = 101; dC(0)/dt = −0.2 and p(0) = 101.

oscillates randomly around some attractor (or basin). Chaos is not randomness. It
is random only by observing from short distance (e.g. short time). By borrowing
the phraseology from Graph theory (cf. [1]), the successful company is consisting
of graph of three nodes: clients (i.e. public), shareholders and employees and three
edges. This Corporate Graph serves as the basin for attractor of chaotic dynamical
process as the company evolves during the time. The process gets very complicated
as there is a high degree of noise (news-flow, competitor and customer behaviour)
and high degree of conflict of interests across the edges. As one can see, the deter-
minism in the contemporary management is unstable. Therefore the conventional
tools of performance management have to be adjusted. The goals and targets might
change overnight and the management culture has to account for this. The man-
agement under chaotic conditions is much more complicated than the management
under deterministic or linear conditions. However, this is most likely irreversible
trend and the management in the future is most likely even harder than the one of
today.
To conclude, the modern management is like deterministic chaos. Whereas un-
derlying structure of the stakeholders interest is determined (by the Corporate Graph
above) the daily management is full of randomness. Successful leader has to keep
its graph together with sound balance between short and long time horizon.
18 Robert Kitt

4 Application: Threats from debt accumulation

The essence of debt is to gear up the shareholder’s capital. The motivation and ex-
tent of debt usage may vary. Business textbooks recommend to use it for capital
optimization purposes, but debt may also be required due to insufficient amount
of equity in the company. The sources of debt financing consist largely of two
groups: banks (typical for continental Europe) and debt capital markets (Anglo-
Saxon model). The same principles apply to the private individuals; only the main
reason for them is to engage into larger investments than their cash accounts allows.
Usage of debt is largely justified in daily business processes and offering debt fi-
nancing is major source of revenues for commercial banks. Mismanagement of the
debt leads to the bankruptcy of private entity and/or credit losses for commercial
banks. Therefore, the debt issuing and management is of interest to both: borrower
and lender.
In addition to private individuals and companies the States (via respective gov-
ernments) are issuing debt to manage public finances. Whereas there are differences
between the countries, the public debt tends to be larger than the private aggregated
debt. Again, in general the usage of public debt is justified with the reasons being
similar to the private purposes. And similarly, mismanagement of public debt can
become a threat to the national solvency.
From the textbooks, the main risks associated with debt are: credit risk (i.e. bor-
rower’s financial inability or institutional unwillingness to serve the debt), interest
rate risk (i.e. difference between market value and notional amount) and currency
risk (i.e. difference arising from currency fluctuations).

Implications of complexity to debt management

In must be noted, that by introducing complexity, there are no changes in any of the
matters above. Conventional private, corporate or public finance has no alterations
due to the complexity. What complexity does, is making financial system more frag-
ile. Namely, the usage of debt in the balance sheet implies certain level of confidence
that borrower is able to serve its obligations. Under stable conditions, the borrow-
ers can estimate their cash flows and then derive their debt service ability. Usually
the cash flows of households consist of salaries; the free cash flow of companies is
revenues minus costs; and the public sector cash flows is essentially collected taxes
plus one-off items, such as privatization.
Complexity and power-laws add additional element of uncertainty into cash
flows. The economic system is never in equilibrium and therefore the borrowers
must qualitatively re-estimate their ability to service the debt. All economic agents
must ask the following questions: what if the salary/revenues disappear from one
day? What if there is unforeseen economic depression? What if the assumptions of
balance sheet optimization task are no longer valid? The debt needs to be serviced
at all given times. The borrower faces problems, if it fails even in short term despite
the fact that the balance sheet and all other conventional measures are still satis-
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 19

factory. Complexity makes borrowing fragile since the short-term problems can kill
the borrower. As we have recently seen (cf international help to Greece, Ireland and
other countries in Europe) the sovereign States are not that different from private
entities. It can be speculated that the increased amount of money has increased the
complexity and that, in turn, has triggered the problems for over-borrowed countries.
To conclude, the usage of debt is very common and it helps to increase the op-
portunity set for private and public institutions. However, the extent of debt usage
should be considered carefully; the optimization techniques for certain aim (e.g.
return of equity) are subject to equilibrium that does not hold in real, complex eco-
nomic systems.

5 Application: Negative impacts of market-driven complexity

So far the discussion has mainly been focused on positive aspects of complexity.
This has opened many new alternatives and created new possibilities for people.
However, there is a clearly negative application due to the market liberalization and
the rise of complexity. This is the application of long-term investments.
The long-term investments such as manufacturing plants and infrastructure have
faced clear set-back from the liberalization of the markets. Let us consider the sim-
plified example of electrical plants. The life-span of the plant and therefore the busi-
ness plan is drawn for decades. The feasibility analysis of the construction of the
new plant goes like follows: revenue minus cost minus debt service costs yields the
shareholder’s profit. The output of the electrical plant is by definition the electricity
and hence the revenues of the plant is generated from the sales of electricity. The
cost of building an electrical plant is huge; this can be done only by borrowing. From
the previous, borrowing makes the system fragile and the debt servicing flows have
to be carefully planned with buffers and cushions for the extraordinary events. How-
ever, with the good investment plan it is not unusual to draw the feasible business
plan for electrical plant. The problematic aspect is added by increased uncertainty
in revenues. Note, that the complexity arising from the market fluctuations of input
commodity (e.g. coil, gas) is ignored here because of simplicity. By market liberal-
ization, the electricity is freely traded in the market. What trades in the market tends
to fluctuate. And this adds uncertainty and complexity by the order of magnitude.
Since the amount of equity in the balance sheet is limited; the drop in revenues can
influence the debt servicing ability. One should not be confused between market rev-
enues and revenues from public subsidies. Public subsidies exist to eliminate some
market inefficiencies; or to execute a political goal. In the context of electricity such
goal is to facilitate the renewable energy sources. Hence, there is stable stream of
cash-flows coming from government that is typically reliable source of revenues in
business plan. To conclude, there is probably a relationship between market liberal-
ization and willingness for private entrepreneurs to set up new electrical plants.
The example of electrical plants can be easily generalized to any of the produc-
tion facility. The business plan faces additional stochasticity from almost all of the
20 Robert Kitt

inputs as well as outputs. To elaborate: one of the largest cost items is electricity,
also various commodities including metals and food. Note that the cost of labour is
not accounted here - the labour market has not essentially changed in the context of
recent jump to the higher level complexity. Similarly to the costs, the revenue side
(i.e. the sales of the company) fluctuates in the market; and it should be as the output
of one company is input to other companies or individuals. Whereas the input prices
can be passed through to the output prices is the function of company management
skills and market practices.
An interesting trend of increased market-based trading takes place in agriculture.
Recently, the number of agricultural products that are traded in the financial mar-
ket has increased. This has lead to new market participants in the form of financial
investors (growth in map). From consumer demand, there is also the preferential
attachment. Recall from section 1.3 that growth and preferential attachment are the
two pre-conditions for the rise of power-laws from Barabási-Albert model. There-
fore, the rise of power-law has gained its legitimacy and, indeed, the prices of agri-
cultural commodities have started to fluctuate in more unpredictable way. Note, that
the prices used to be predictable as the market participants included only producers
on supply side and consumers on demand side of the economic equation. Therefore,
the complexity of agricultural business model has exceeded the production-specific
aspects and includes now also the complexity of the financial markets.
What would be the tools for businesses to overcome the complexity of markets?
The first and foremost, the business managers have to accept the complexity and to
admit the higher degree of unpredictability in their business plans. The second line
of defence is to explicitly state the quantities under risk and then to find the risk
mitigating solutions. For example, the electrical plant managers should think about
their cash-flow sensitivity towards the price of gas or coal (inputs) and electricity
(output). The risk mitigation can be done through financial contracts as OTC for-
wards, futures; options or other similar instruments; or by passing through the input
fluctuation to the output. The problem with this approach is that the length of such
contracts is typically short and cannot be used for the whole lifetime of the business
plan. Despite of that, the increased complexity calls for the qualitative increase in
risk management of the corporate and/or public management. Another solution to
the problem is financial innovation. Namely, the loans of the banks might depend
on the price of some commodity, but it is only partial solution as then the banks
would be taking the price risk. The full solution is that the banks can also finance
themselves based on some commodity index; that in turn calls for the financial mar-
ket to create such instruments. And, as we have seen, this might trigger in turn an
additional level of complexity.

Conclusion

Non-equilibrium economy via its applications of chaotic dynamic and non-linear


stochasticity is in the rise. The rise of power-laws in many social systems are dis-
Economic decision making: application of the theory of complex systems 21

cussed and it is shown that the systems with growth and preferential attachments
are characterised by power-laws. These conditions are satisfied in increasing num-
ber of fields in socio-economic landscape and therefore the non-linear or complex
phenomena is increasingly dominant in social systems. In addition, the changes are
also under-way in global consumption patterns that together with inter-connectivity
through the internet make business and economic environment more and more com-
plex. For successful management under complexity, a following principles are of-
fered: openness and international competition, tolerance and variety of ideas, self-
reliability and low dependence on external help.
Despite of increasing complexity, it seems that small economies have good
prospects to gain from the global processes underway. The key to success is flexible
production, reliable business ethics and good risk management. Management itself
is also changing. The static approaches and tools have to be complemented with
dynamic and more agile approaches. Corporate executives do not have the luxury of
not to react to the market information promptly. The managers have to find good bal-
ance between main stakeholders (customers, shareholders and employees) as well as
market reactions. From financial aspects the excessive usage of debt is questioned.
The debt makes companies fragile as short-term temporary downturns can under
unfavourable circumstances kill the company. The increasing non-linearity in the
economic surroundings has influenced many industries. As it is shown, the busi-
ness models start including also the financial risk management as an integral part of
company’s operations.

Acknowledgements This contribution was written in the 2nd Ph.D. School of ”Mathematical
modelling of complex systems” in Pescara, Italy in July 2012. Author would like to thank all
of the attending students and professors for fruitful discussion; and especially Proffessors. G.I.
Bischi and T. Bountis. Author would also like to thank Prof. J. Engelbrecht and Dr J. Kalda from
Institute of Cybernetics at Tallinn University of Technology for fruitful discussions. The support
of Estonian Science Foundation (Grant ETF7909) supported by the EU through the European
Regional Development Fund is highly appreciated.

References

1. Albert R., Barabási A.-L. (2002) Statistical mechanics of complex networks. Reviews of
Modern Physics 74:47-97
2. Barabási A-.L., Albert R. (1999) Emergence of Scaling in Random Networks. Science
286:509-512
3. Ball P. (2004) Critical Mass. Random House, London
4. Bischi G.I., Kopel M. (2001) Equilibrium selection in a nonlinear duopoly game with adaptive
expectations. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 46:73-100
5. Caldarelli G., Cristelli M., Gabrielli A., Pietronero L., Scala A., Tacchella A. (2012) A net-
work analysis of countries’ export flows: firm grounds for the building blocks of the economy.
Available via arxiv.org
http://arxiv.org/abs/1108.2590. Cited 25 Dec 2012
22 Robert Kitt

6. Chan Kim W., Mauborgne R. (2005) Blue Ocean Strategy: How to Create Uncontested Mar-
ket Space and Make the Competition Irrelevant. Harvard Business School Publishing Corpo-
ration
7. The Economist (2012) A third industrial revolution, editorial in April 21st 2012 issue.
http://www.economist.com/node/21552901. Cited 25 Dec 2012
8. Erdős P., Renyi A. (1959) On Random Graphs. Publicationes Mathematicae (Debrecen)
6:290-297.
9. Hayek F.A. (1944) The Road to Serfdom. G. Routledge & Sons. Reprinted by Routledge 2009
10. Henry Ford. Quoted in Wikiquote.org
http://en.wikiquote.org/wiki/Henry_Ford. Cited 18 Jan 2013
11. Kitt R. (2005) Generalised Scale-Invariance in Financial Time Series. Doctoral thesis, Tallinn
University of Technology, Tallinn, Estonia
12. Mandelbrot B.B. (1963) The Variation of certain speculative prices. The Journal of Business
36: 394-419
13. Mandelbrot B.B. (1965) Une classe de processus stochastiques homothetiques a soi; applica-
tion a la loi climatologique de H.E. Hurst. Comptes Rendus (Paris) 260:3274-7
14. Mandelbrot B.B. (1982) The Fractal Geometry of Nature. W.H.Freeman, New York
15. Mandelbrot B.B. (1997) Fractals and Scaling in Finance: Discontinuity, Concentration, Risk.
Springer New York
16. Mantegna R., Stanley H.E. (2000) An Introduction to Econophysics: Correlations and Com-
plexity in Finance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK
17. Miller J., Page S. (2007) Complex Adaptive Systems. Princeton University Press, Princeton
NJ
18. Mitchell M. (2011) Complexity: A Guided Tour. Oxford University Press, New York NY
19. Moskowitz H., Gofman A. (2007) Selling Blue Elephants: How to make great products that
people want before they even know that they want them. Wharton School Publishing, Pearson
Education Inc NJ
20. Pareto V. (1896-7) Cours d’Economie Politique. Lausanne: F. Rogue
21. Peters T. , Waterman R.H. jr (1982) In Search of excellence. Harper & Row. Reprinted by
Profile books Ltd, UK 2004
22. Popper K. (1934) Logik der Forschung. First published in English in 1959: The Logic of
Scientific Discovery. Routledge, London
23. Popper K. (1945) The Open Society and Its Enemies. Routledge & Kegan Paul. Reprinted by
Routledge in 2005
24. Popper K. (1957) The Powerty of Historicism. Routledge. Reprinted by Routledge 2010
25. Porter M. (1979) How Competitive Forces Shape Strategy. Harvard Business Review
26. Puu T. (1989) Nonlinear Economic Dynamics. Springer; see also Puu T., Panchuk A. eds.
(2011) Nonlinear Economic Dynamics, Nova Publishers
27. Ricardo D. (1817) Principles of political economy and taxation. London: John Murray, re-
trieved Jan 02 2013 via Google Books
28. Rowland I. (2008) The Full Facts Book of Cold Reading, 4th ed. Ian Rowland Limited, Lon-
don
29. Stanley H.E., Plerou V., Gabaix X. (2008) A statistical physics view of financial fluctuations:
Evidence for scaling and universality. Physica A 387:3967-3981
30. Taleb N.N. (2005) Fooled by Randomness: The Hidden Role of Chance in Life and in the
Markets 2nd ed. Penguin books, London
31. Taleb N.N. (2007) The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable 2nd ed. Random
House
32. Zipf H.K. (1949) Human Behaviour and the Principle of Least Effort. Addison-Wesley, Cam-
bridge MA

You might also like