(Ebook) Global and Asian Perspectives On International Migration by Graziano Battistella (Eds.) ISBN 9783319083162, 9783319083179, 3319083163, 3319083171 Instant Download
(Ebook) Global and Asian Perspectives On International Migration by Graziano Battistella (Eds.) ISBN 9783319083162, 9783319083179, 3319083163, 3319083171 Instant Download
https://ebooknice.com/product/global-and-asian-perspectives-on-
international-migration-4931622
(Ebook) Biota Grow 2C gather 2C cook by Loucas, Jason; Viles, James ISBN
9781459699816, 9781743365571, 9781925268492, 1459699815, 1743365578, 1925268497
https://ebooknice.com/product/biota-grow-2c-gather-2c-cook-6661374
ebooknice.com
(Ebook) Matematik 5000+ Kurs 2c Lärobok by Lena Alfredsson, Hans Heikne, Sanna
Bodemyr ISBN 9789127456600, 9127456609
https://ebooknice.com/product/matematik-5000-kurs-2c-larobok-23848312
ebooknice.com
(Ebook) SAT II Success MATH 1C and 2C 2002 (Peterson's SAT II Success) by Peterson's
ISBN 9780768906677, 0768906679
https://ebooknice.com/product/sat-ii-success-math-1c-and-2c-2002-peterson-s-sat-
ii-success-1722018
ebooknice.com
(Ebook) Master SAT II Math 1c and 2c 4th ed (Arco Master the SAT Subject Test: Math
Levels 1 & 2) by Arco ISBN 9780768923049, 0768923042
https://ebooknice.com/product/master-sat-ii-math-1c-and-2c-4th-ed-arco-master-
the-sat-subject-test-math-levels-1-2-2326094
ebooknice.com
(Ebook) Cambridge IGCSE and O Level History Workbook 2C - Depth Study: the United
States, 1919-41 2nd Edition by Benjamin Harrison ISBN 9781398375147, 9781398375048,
1398375144, 1398375047
https://ebooknice.com/product/cambridge-igcse-and-o-level-history-
workbook-2c-depth-study-the-united-states-1919-41-2nd-edition-53538044
ebooknice.com
https://ebooknice.com/product/vagabond-vol-29-29-37511002
ebooknice.com
https://ebooknice.com/product/undocumented-dominican-migration-51978346
ebooknice.com
https://ebooknice.com/product/asian-perspectives-on-international-investment-
law-31755804
ebooknice.com
https://ebooknice.com/product/29-single-and-nigerian-53599780
ebooknice.com
Global and Asian Perspectives on International
Migration
Global Migration Issues
Volume 4
Series Editor:
Dr. Frank Laczko
Head of Research and Publications,
International Organization for Migration (IOM),
Geneva
This book series contributes to the global discussion about the future of migration
policy through the publication of a series of books on emerging migration issues.
Most reports on migration policy tend to focus on national or regional perspectives;
books in this series will focus on global policy challenges, such as the impact of
climate change or the global economic crisis, on migration.
This series is closely linked to the production of IOM’s World Migration Report.
Some of the books in this series will be based on research which has been prepared
for the World Migration Report.
The series also includes a special focus on the linkages between migration and
development, and the themes discussed each year at the Global Forum on Migration
and Development (GFMD), given the growing policy interest in harnessing the
benefits of migration for development.
More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/8837
Graziano Battistella
Editor
1 3
Editor
Graziano Battistella
Scalabrini Migration Center
Quezon City
Philippines
Many ideas come to mind, float in the air, bounce back and forth in conversations
with colleagues and friends and then go nowhere. Some ideas keep returning and
beg for implementation. A conference pairing scholars from Asia with colleagues
from the west was one such idea that did not go away. And a conference was planned
and came to fruition in April 2013 with the support of individuals and institutions,
who I am pleased to acknowledge.
From inception to implementation there is a crucial phase which consists in find-
ing the right cooperation. First of all, it is important to secure the cooperation of
authors willing to put their mind into the task of writing and discussing theoretical
perspectives on migration. For this reason, my first acknowledgement goes to the
authors who have participated in the conference and then revised their contributions
in view of a publication.
To bring together a group of scholars from North America, Europe and Asian
countries requires the support of persons who believe in the initiative. In this
case, I was fortunate to find support from the regional and local offices of the
International Labour Organization (ILO) and the International Organization for
Migration (IOM). In particular, I am grateful to Nilim Baruah and Manuel Imson of
the ILO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific, based in Bangkok; to Catherine
Vaillancourt Laflamme and Jennifer dela Rosa of the ILO Decent Work Across
Borders, a project funded by the European Union, based in Manila; to Andrew Bruce
of the IOM Regional Office in Bangkok; to Ovais Sarmad, who was then with the
IOM Administrative Centre in Manila; and to Frank Laczko of the IOM Headquar-
ters in Geneva, who supported the publication of the manuscript with Springer.
The execution of the project was possible because of the cooperation of the
staff of the Scalabrini Migration Center. In particular, the initiative was discussed
and refined with Maruja M. B. Asis. Valentin Mendoza, Cecille Guerrero, Leonila
Domingo and John Paul Asis assisted in the organizational aspects; Karen Anne S.
Liao and Cecilia Marave provided editorial assistance. The mistakes that remain
are mine.
v
Contents
vii
viii Contents
Manolo I. Abella Centre for Migration Policy and Society, University of Oxford,
Oxford, UK
Fernando T. Aldaba Ateneo de Manila University, Quezon, Philippines
Graziano Battistella Scalabrini Migration Center, Quezon City, Philippines
Jean-Pierre Cassarino Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies, European
University Institute, Florence, Italy
Stephen Castles University of Sydney, Sydney, NSW, Australia
Geoffrey Ducanes School of Economics, University of the Philippines, Quezon
City, Philippines
Christian Joppke University of Bern, Bern, Switzerland
Eleonore Kofman Middlesex University, London, UK
Philip L. Martin University of California, Davis, USA
Derya Ozkul University of Sydney, Sydney, NSW, Australia
Rinus Penninx University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
Piyasiri Wickramasekara Global Migration Policy Associates (GMPA),
Geneva, Switzerland
Biao Xiang COMPAS, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
Brenda S. A. Yeoh National University of Singapore, Singapore, Singapore
In-Jin Yoon Korean University, Seoul, Republic of Korea
ix
Chapter 1
Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical
Framework
Graziano Battistella
Research on migration has increased with the rise in international migration since
the early 1960s, highlighting new migration patterns and their impacts. However,
the expanding stock of migration research has not made it easier to govern migra-
tion or solve the problems of migrants. Instead, more complex migration relation-
ships have outpaced the capacity of research to offer suggestions on how best to
manage new flows of people over national borders. This chapter tackles the fun-
damental question of what is known about migration; in particular, it examines the
characteristics of migration in Asia and the issues generated by migration flows in a
continent with 60 % of the world’s people and some of the most complex migration
relationships. It will then introduce the contributions in this volume, which were
presented at an international dialogue on some aspects of migration and conclude
with questions for further research.
The formulation of a theoretical approach to migration began a long time ago. Ra-
venstein’s laws on migration appeared in 1885, at the time of the great migration
from Europe to the Americas, although the laws were formulated to explain internal
migration in the United Kingdom (Ravenstein 1985). The application of Raven-
stein’s laws to international migration (Ravenstein 1889) inspired theorizing about
migration, and neoclassical economics were developed in the 1950s (Lewis 1954)
and refined in the 1970s by Harris and Todaro (1970). The push-pull model ad-
vanced by Lee (1966) came to dominate the explanation of the origin and develop-
ment of migration for many years.
Towards the end of the twentieth century, scholars reviewed various migration
theories in response to social and economic changes that led to new forms and
G. Battistella ()
Scalabrini Migration Center, Quezon City, Philippines
e-mail: [email protected]
G. Battistella (ed.), Global and Asian Perspectives on International Migration, 1
Global Migration Issues 4, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-08317-9_1,
© Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2014
2 G. Battistella
International labor migration involves people moving over national borders for a
certain period of time in search of better opportunities, so the reasons for unequal
development must be understood to comprehend migration. Prebisch (1950) en-
visaged a world organized into two types of states: those at the center import raw
materials and export finished products, and states on the periphery export raw ma-
terials and import finished products. Such an unequal trading relationship keeps
developing nations in a peripheral condition, prompting Prebisch to suggest import
substitution so that developing countries can develop their manufacturing sectors.
The center-periphery concept was adopted by dependency theory (Franch 1969;
Cardoso and Faletto 1979), which posited that the center-periphery relation was
an integral component of the capitalist model of development. The world systems
theory (Wallerstein 1975) introduced a third type, the semi-periphery, to describe
countries that depend on the center but also have some control over countries at the
periphery. These broad theories contribute to the understanding of the origins of
migration by illustrating the ways that capitalist nations penetrate the markets of
the countries at the periphery, displacing workers and turning some into migrants
who move to the more developed countries. The linkages established by political
and economic dependency tend to favor migration flows. More specifically, Sassen
(1988) argued that migration to the US was a byproduct of the internationalization
of production, as the outflow of capital generates an inflow of labor.
In addition to the economic, the demographic, political and social contexts lay
the premise for possible migration movements. The linkage with the demographic
factor was best theorized by Zelinsky (1971) who argued that migration develops
according to regularities which are modeled on the modernization process and are
structured in correlation with the demographic transition. The weaknesses of that
correlation, particularly when applied to a specific region like Asia, were under-
scored by Skeldon (1992). Nevertheless, the importance of the demographic differ-
entials among countries as a premise to labor movements remains patent. The po-
litical and social factors were emphasized particularly by historians who observed
that political ties functioned as facilitators of migration movements. The European
colonialism stands out as the macroscopic example of such ties, with people moving
first toward the colonial states, workers being transferred to the colonies and among
colonies as indentured labor and migrants moving toward the colonizing countries
during and after the colonial period (Emmer 1986).
After understanding the broad causes of migration with the help of the dependency
theory and world systems theory, the structural economic factors at the origin and
the destination must be clarified. Neoclassical economists emphasized macro-level
variables such as differences in endowments of capital and labor that encourage
4 G. Battistella
1.1.3 Personal Factors
Understanding the background context and the structural factors at the origin and
the destination illustrates the propensity to migrate but is not sufficient to explain
why people migrate. In fact, although factors are similar for a specific population,
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 5
those who decide to migrate are a minority within the population. Globally, they
constitute about three percent of the world’s population (UN-DESA 2013). In some
countries of origin this proportion is higher, but still a minority. Therefore, in ad-
dition to structural and family factors influencing the decision to migrate, personal
factors must also be considered.
At the personal level, it is always observed that migrant workers are mostly
young adults, persons in the prime of their productive life. In this regard, the pro-
pensity to migrate was considered at different stages of a person’s and family’s life:
young single adults are more mobile than married persons and married persons are
more mobile before children go to school, etc. (De Jong and Gardner, 1981). While
criticized for its limitation to the nuclear type of family, the idea remains that demo-
graphic characteristics of migrants have a role in the decision to migrate.
In looking at the micro-level motivational approach to the decision to migrate,
De Jong and Fawcett (1981) found the previous theories incapable of explaining
most of all why some people do not migrate. In that regard, in contrast with the
excessive role given to economic reasons, they emphasized that migration should
be considered as the result of many motives. They proposed to apply to migration
the value-expectancy model, which consists in viewing migration as the result of a
cost-benefit analysis between values and expectancies (1981, p. 47). Values can be
classified in seven categories: wealth, status, comfort, stimulation, autonomy, affili-
ation, morality, while expectancy refers to the belief that a particular behavior will
attain a certain value. On the basis of the value-expectancy model, some hypotheses
can be made concerning the probability of mobility by specific groups of people.
A further study analyzing migration from the Philippines examined the discrepan-
cies between the intention to migrate and the actual implementation. The study
explained the discrepancies “in terms of unanticipated constraints and facilitators,
as well as changes in the conditions that precipitated the migration intention in the
first place” (Gardner et al. 1986, p. 63).
The final component for the initiation and continuation (see later) of migration
is characterized by the role of intermediaries (labor recruiters, brokers, transport
agencies, etc.). Direct hiring—a process in which employers hire migrants with-
out the intermediation of recruitment and placement agencies—or hiring through
government-to-government agreements apply only to a minority of workers. For
the majority, employers utilize the service of intermediaries and migrants secure
a visa and employment abroad through labor recruiters. Intermediaries charge
employers for their services, but in many countries, they also earn by exacting
a fee from the migrants, although this practice is barred by the ILO Private Em-
ployment Agency Convention, 1997 (No. 181). The profitable activity of labor
recruitment has generated a proliferation of agencies, compelling governments to
regulate it. Goss and Lindquist (1995) emphasized the importance of intermediar-
ies in what they called the migrant institution, suggesting the application of the
6 G. Battistella
structuration theory to migration as the best way to unify the knowledge of the mi-
gration process. Others have focused on the role of intermediaries as merchants of
labor (Martin 2005) who tend to prolong migration beyond its necessity because
of its profitability; they also contribute to the commodification of labor migration.
Gammeltoft-Hansen and Sorensen (2013) have further elaborated on the role of
intermediaries by adding to their facilitating role (performed by labor recruiters)
the control role (performed by private security agencies which act on behalf of
governments) and the rescue role (performed by non-government organizations
or NGOs, migrant associations and civil society groups). Regardless of the dif-
ferent angles, and barring a major overhaul of the migration systems, it is clear
that for the majority of workers migration cannot occur without the intervention
of intermediaries.
Migration implies that migrants live and work in a country where they were not
born or different from their usual country of residence. How migrants can suc-
cessfully incorporate in the society of destination has long interested sociologists,
particularly in countries of permanent migration. The Chicago School, which spe-
cialized in the social analysis of life in an urban context, formulated the assimila-
tion theory. Robert Park (1924) theorized the race relations cycle, which goes from
contact to competition to accommodation and finally, assimilation, in a sequence
considered normative and irreversible. A less normative approach was taken by W.I.
Thomas, who recommended a wise policy of assimilation that does not destroy the
memories of migrants, but builds on them. The assimilation theory dominated the
debate until the early 1960s, when it was comprehensively formulated by Milton
Gordon (1964). In theorizing the nature of assimilation he distinguished the vari-
ous types or stages of assimilation: from the initial stage of cultural or behavioral
assimilation to the final one of civic assimilation (1964, p. 71). Of the three major
theories of the assimilationist process, he considered Anglo-conformity as the most
successful. The competitive theory of the melting pot did not see a practical imple-
mentation, as in fact, many melting pots were created within the American society
(see also Glazer and Moynihan 1963). As for cultural pluralism, he considered it a
minor key for the understanding of ethnic America, while his preference was for
structural pluralism.
Ironically, the ultimate theorization of assimilation came at the time of its demise
due to the emergence of a strong movement for the discovery of ethnic origins.
Instead of assimilation, integration was considered the most appropriate term. Its
main characteristic is that while assimilation is considered a unidirectional process,
integration is considered a bidirectional one, in the sense that migrants have some-
thing to contribute to the local society and that successful incorporation requires for
the receiving society to provide the opportunities for it. However, integration was
never formulated in a coherent theoretical model (Favell 2001) and assimilationism
did not die. In studying the more recent generations of migrants to the US, Portes
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 7
and Zhou (1994) spoke of segmented assimilation, as some of the new migrants
assimilate to the lower echelons of society. Alba and Nee (2003) supported a return
to assimilationism, but devoid of ethnocentrism and determinism and in which the
process of assimilation as boundary crossing is substituted with that of boundary
blurring.
While integration was formally defined by the Commission of the European
Union (C2003/336), multiculturalism was debated as a different form of organizing
societies with migrants. Philosophically, the debate was polarized around the com-
munitarian and liberal positions. Charles Taylor’s sharp criticism of the false neu-
trality of liberalism on values—i.e., hiding the intent to impose the hegemony of
western culture—and the emphasis on equality which is only procedural equality,
led him to advocate for a public recognition of the collective rights of minority
cultures (Taylor 1992). Habermas (1993) thinks that autonomy requires participa-
tion (civic autonomy) to be real autonomy, therefore, democracy must be delibera-
tive, a process in which all participate, including migrants. Migrants should not be
required to attain cultural integration, but political integration, the adhesion to the
constitutional values (constitutional patriotism). Diversities must be respected, but
rights remain individual in nature. Kymlicka (1995) takes a middle position when
he rejects the procedural neutrality of liberals as discriminating and the uncritical
recognition of the collective rights of minorities. He makes a distinction between
internal and external restrictions that minority cultures impose. He considers exter-
nal restrictions acceptable, while internal restrictions are against liberal principles.
“Liberals should seek to ensure that there is equality between groups, and freedom
and equality within groups” (Kymlicka 1995, p. 194). Recently, Murray (2012) has
taken some distance from the misconception that, in multicultural policies, anything
goes, but also from attributing an excessive role to multicultural policies, which
“represent only one small part of the legislative toolkit available to decision-makers
engaged in the business of maintaining unity and social solidarity in conditions of
diversity” (p. 150). He advocated for civic multiculturalism, where both majority
and minorities respect differences and contribute to social cohesion.
Politically, multiculturalism has remained publicly recognized in Canada and
Australia, while it underwent some crisis in Europe. However, the discussion on the
plurality of cultures and the need for social cohesion within societies continues. The
issue was the object of the Human Development Report in 2004 (UNDP 2004), with
emphasis on cultural freedom. In some circles, to overcome the major deficiency of
multiculturalism, which is the lack of dialogue among the various cultures which
potentially leads to cultural ghettos and an erosion of social cohesion, it is impor-
tant to go beyond multiculturalism in favor of intercultural dialogue. The UNESCO
report of 2009 emphasized that there must be an educational effort to acquire the
competencies in intercultural dialogue, which include listening, understanding and
wonder (UNESCO 2009, p. 46).
The realization that migrants in traditional countries of settlement were not avail-
ing of the possibility to acquire citizenship and the irruption of the globalization
discourse demanded new perspectives on the belonging of migrants. Some authors
advanced the notion of transnationalism as a condition in which migrants belong
8 G. Battistella
and interact with different spaces at the same time (Basch et al. 1994). Although it
is acknowledged that the transnational condition might apply only to a minority of
migrants (Portes 2003), the concept has challenged the static approach to migration
as a one-time, definitive movement, so typical, and yet also so partially true, of the
nineteenth century migration to the Americas.
Migration in general, as well as labor migration in particular, has increased in the past
decades. Oft quoted figures produced by the UN Population Commission say that
migrants were about 154 million in 1990 and are estimated to be 232 million in 2013
(UN-DESA 2013). The growth of migration is attributed to the same factors that
originate it, in addition to other factors that have been observed for quite some time.
Chain migration is an expression that was already used during the great migra-
tion from Europe to the Americas. The distinctive feature of chain migration is
that it differs from impersonally organized migration, because the arrangements
for the migrants are made “by means of primary social relationship with previ-
ous migrants” (Macdonald and Macdonald 1964, p. 82, italics in the original text).
The concept of chain migration, which during the years of the great migration was
symbolized by entire villages that moved from Europe to the Americas, was refor-
mulated in the more comprehensive notion of migration networks. These networks
are characterized primarily by interpersonal connections that link migrants, former
migrants and non-migrants through family, friendship and acquaintance ties. As the
scarcity of information is one of the biggest challenges that migrants face, obtaining
information from personal and social networks facilitates the migration process and
increases the probability to migrate. In broad terms, the linkages that one can find
within a migration network constitute social capital, the value of which is propor-
tional to its possibility to be converted into real capital (Massey et al. 1987). The
role of migration networks, particularly in decreasing the cost of migration, also
explains why migration movements tend to last longer than the structural factors
would require. To further explain the tendency of migration to expand and continue,
Massey et al. (1998, pp. 45–50) also borrowed the notion of cumulative causation
from Gunnar Myrdal (1957), to indicate that, since an act of migration modifies the
context in which it takes place, successive migration acts become easier and more
probable for others. Cumulative causation will ultimately limit itself because of the
process of saturation, when decreasing migration costs are no longer significant in
the decision to migrate.
If migration is initiated by certain structural differences between the origin and the
destination, the closing of those differences is expected to end migration. At the
macro level, while the demand for migrant labor might continue in the country of
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 9
In this synthesis, migration has been considered in its various aspects as a process
which begins, continues and ends because of structural and personal factors. The
10 G. Battistella
various theories have contributed to the understanding of the remote causes (the
background context); the proximate determinants (the structural factors at the origin
and the destination); the role of intermediaries; the personal motivations for leaving,
for staying abroad and for returning; and the different ways in which a society with
migrants can respect differences while attaining social cohesion.
Various aspects of the migration process were not considered. Among them: the
impact of migration on the countries of origin, the countries of destination and the
migrants themselves; the social consequences of migration; the nexus between mi-
gration and development; and the gender perspective on migration. Most of all, the
synthesis did not address the fact that the movement of workers across borders does
not take place freely. It is heavily regulated by each state, sometimes in the exiting
process, to ensure protection to nationals going abroad, and always in the admis-
sion process, because every state considers the policy on admission of migrants
as an expression of its sovereignty. Zolberg (1999) advocated the need to “bring
the state back in” as an essential component for the understanding of migration. In
this regard, the interpretative and predictive power of theories has to contend with
political decisions, which do not cohere with theoretical formulations. It is not pos-
sible to expand on each of the aforementioned missing components in this chapter.
However, in regard to the policy aspects it is worthwhile to observe that research on
migration policies has established some regularities, which include:
• absolute control of migration is not possible or not desired;
• excessively restrictive migration policies generate irregular migration;
• admission policies are more open during times of economic growth and more
restricted in time of economic recession;
• migration policies tend to be more in favor of migrants than the prevailing public
opinion;
• the inefficiency of migration policies depends often on the lack of coherence
with policies in other sectors;
• sectors that might be at the opposite side in other issues, can find themselves on
the same side when it comes to migration (the “strange bedfellows” of Zolberg
(1999)).
Trying to represent the whole synthesis in an abstract formulation might remain
difficult because of too many components. The most comprehensive formulation
was proposed by the systemic approach. Mabogunje (1970) attempted it in regard
to rural-urban migration in Nigeria and Kritz et al. (1992) applied it to international
migration. While the systemic approach helps us understand that it is not possible to
look at migration simply as a movement from country A to country B while ignoring
all the other relevant dimensions, it does not sufficiently address all the elements of
the synthesis and it remains difficult to validate through research.
In spite of the missing components, the synthetic overview has helped us un-
derstand that many questions have been addressed in migration research and have
received partial explanations. Most of the questions and the research looking for
answers have been elaborated in North America and Western Europe, with the per-
manent, long-term or guest workers migration models as the object of analysis.
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 11
Asia has come more recently into the picture, as labor migration within the region
took off only in the early 1970s. International migration in the Asian context merits
the question whether it might challenge some aspects of the general theoretical
formulation. In migration within Asia the role of the state is preponderant and leads
to a migration system which is much more rigid than in other regions of the world.
This has resulted in some out-of-the-box patterns, such as the development of labor
migration to the Gulf countries from countries with which they did not have previ-
ous political or social ties, or Japan’s insistence not to import less skilled migrant
workers despite the decades-long demand for such workers, or the by-passing of
intermediaries with South Korea’s government-to-government arrangements with
selected countries of origin. Irregular migration, which is widespread in the re-
gion, does not appear to be an anomaly but a component embedded in the system.
The incorporation of migrants into society is unforeseen, to the point that in some
places, like the Gulf countries, migrants are maintained separately from the local
population. One could say that those points do not invalidate theory, as they pertain
to the governance of migration. If it is true that the governance of migration cannot
be effective when it clashes with fundamental dynamics illustrated by theories, then
it remains difficult to explain why the migration system in Asia has persisted for
over four decades. Regardless of the stance on this matter, this chapter argues that
the specificities of migration in Asia should be examined to verify the theoretical
questions they raise.
1.2 Migration in Asia1
Asia is the origin of large flows of migrants toward countries of traditional settle-
ment in North America and Oceania and of long-term migration in Europe. In 2012,
41 % of immigrants receiving permanent status in the US were from Asia (in par-
ticular China, India and the Philippines) (US DHS 2012); the top three source coun-
tries of permanent residence in Canada were again China, the Philippines and India,
which account for 36 % of the total (Government of Canada 2012); the same three
countries were among the top four countries of origin for Australia in 2012–2013. In
particular, the Indian sub-continent contributed 29 % to Australia’s total migration
program and North Asia, 23 % (Australian Government, Department of Immigra-
tion and Citizenship 2013).2 Our focus, however, is on labor migration, of which we
provide a very cursory overview of flows and characteristics.
1
This brief overview will not include Central Asia. The Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) coun-
tries and/or Middle East countries are also referred to as West Asia.
2
Asia is also a region of vast internal migration. Perhaps the most renowned internal movement
concerns migrants from the rural to the coastal provinces of China, involving 221 million people
(AMO 2012 (2013)).
12 G. Battistella
All regions in the Asian continent are both origin and destination of migrants. How-
ever, the Middle East and East Asia are prevalently destination of flows originating
mainly from South and Southeast Asia. Migrants from the Indian subcontinent are
almost exclusively absorbed by the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries.
The percentage is particularly high (over 90 %) for Indians and Pakistanis. Of the
Indians, however, the count is limited to those migrants who need the exit clearance
(Exit Check Required), which applies only to workers in less-skilled occupations
and working in 17 specific countries. They reached 747,041 in 2012 and worked
mostly in Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates (UAE) and Oman (Government
of India, Ministry of Overseas Indian Affairs 2013). The same Gulf countries were
the main destinations of Pakistani workers, 456,893 in 2011. Migrants from Ban-
gladesh numbered over half a million in 2011, after a decline in 2010 because of the
2008–20 09 recession, and reached 607,798 in 2012, but declined again to 409,253
in 2013.4 Large numbers of Bangladeshis also migrate to India, although in a mostly
irregular way. Nepal has become more prominent as a country of origin (354,716 in
2011) and in addition to the Gulf countries, it deploys many migrants to Malaysia.
The flow from Sri Lanka has been stable for some years (262,960 in 2011), of which
over 90 % were directed to the Gulf countries. Apart from South Asia, migrants in
the Gulf countries originate from the Philippines and Indonesia. The Gulf countries
are distinctive in terms of the overwhelming percentage of foreign labor force (from
21 % in Saudi Arabia to 88 % in the UAE), which is a cause for concern across the
region. All GCC countries have embarked on specific programs to reduce depen-
dence on foreign workers and provide more jobs for their nationals. Aside from the
Gulf countries, Jordan and Lebanon are also destinations of migrant labor, particu-
larly from the Philippines, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka. Jordan has become a country
of temporary resettlement for a large number of asylees from Syria since the civil
war erupted in 2011.
In East Asia, the main destinations for migrant labor are Japan, South Korea
and Taiwan. The number of foreigners registered in Japan, which does not admit
unskilled foreigners as workers, has been declining because of the global crisis,
but surpassed two million, mainly from China, South Korea, Brazil, the Philip-
pines, Peru and the US. Foreign workers in South Korea (which has a country-to-
country admission scheme) numbered 595,098 in Dec 2011, 529,690 in Dec 2012,
and 547,590 in Dec 2013. Of them, 203,473, about 37.2 % in Dec. 2013, were ethnic
Koreans from China according to the Korea Immigration Service statistics.5 Mi-
grants in Taiwan were 489,134 at the end of 2013, mostly from Indonesia, Vietnam,
3
Unless otherwise specified, figures in this section are taken from the Asian Migration Outlook
2012 (AMO 2012 (2013)).
4
http://www.bmet.gov.bd/BMET/viewStatReport.action?reportnumber=18. Accessed 21 Mar
2014.
5
I am grateful to Ki-seon Chung, senior researcher at Migration Research and Training Center of
the International Organization for Migration (IOM MRTC) in Korea for this information.
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 13
the Philippines and Thailand (ROC (Taiwan), Ministry of Labor 2014). In addition
to migrant labor, all three countries have a considerable number of foreigners—
mostly women—married to their nationals. This has ignited a great deal of attention
in South Korea, which has instituted a multicultural program to provide foreign
spouses with the necessary acculturation to adapt in Korean society.
In addition to being the main sources of migrant labor for the Middle East and
East Asia, South and Southeast Asia are also destinations of migrants, mainly from
countries within their respective regions. In South Asia, India is the main destina-
tion of migrants from Nepal and Bangladesh. While Nepalese can freely enter India
because of the open border agreement, Bangladeshis cross the border and enter the
state of Assam mostly without authorization. In Southeast Asia, Singapore, Malay-
sia and Thailand are destinations of labor flows from within and outside the region.
Statistics on the origin of foreigners in Singapore are not known, but the share of the
foreign population to the total population reached 37 % in 2011. The foreign work-
force was approximately 1.2 million, mostly unskilled migrants, particularly do-
mestic workers and construction workers. In Malaysia, registered foreign workers
were 1.8 million in 2011, over 50 % of whom came from Indonesia. The legalization
program in 2011–2012 registered 2.5 million foreigners, of whom 1.3 million were
in an irregular situation. Thailand is the destination of migrants from Myanmar,
Cambodia and Laos. The actual number of foreign workers is not known, as the
registered ones (1.3 million in 2011) represent only a portion of the total foreign
workforce. Annual registrations yield different results, making it difficult to trace
the trend of the foreign population in the country.
Among the countries of origin in Southeast Asia, Indonesia and Myanmar are the
countries that deploy the largest number of migrants within the region: Indonesia
to Malaysia and Myanmar to Thailand. Both corridors are largely unauthorized.
The Philippines is the most important country of origin in terms of worker deploy-
ment and policies designed to facilitate and protect overseas labor. In 2012, a total
of 1,802,031 Filipino workers went abroad, of whom 458,575 left as new hires,
976,591 as re-hires and 366,865 as seafarers (POEA 2013). Among the various
countries of origin, only the Philippines includes seafarers in its count of over-
seas workers, also because it is the highest deploying country in that sector. While
largely going to the Gulf countries, the Philippines deploys workers in many other
destinations, but particularly to Hong Kong, Singapore and East Asian countries.
1.2.2 Characteristics
The annual flow of migrants within Asia approaches four million people. The domi-
nant model of employment is largely temporary labor migration with the following
characteristics:
• Temporary low-skill employment. In general, migrants are hired with a short-
term contract (mostly two years), which is not renewable onsite. Migrants must
return to their country of origin and can be rehired, and those who do, cannot
14 G. Battistella
6
In the Philippines it is equivalent to one month salary. However, domestic workers should not
be charged any fee.
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 15
7
Hugo (1998) had arrived at the same conclusion in his overview of the applicability of theories
to Asian migration.
1 Migration in Asia: In Search of a Theoretical Framework 17
51. Cat., V, 4:
55. Cic., Parad. Stoic., II, 18: “Mors est terribilis iis quorum cum vita omnia
exstinguntur, non iis quorum laus emori non potest.”
56. Cic., Pro Archia, 11, 26; cf. Tusc., I, 15, 34.
57. Diog. Laert., X, 16 = fragm. 217 Usener; cf. Plin., H. N., XXXV, 5.
69. See, for all this, Lecture III, p. 96 s.; cf. VIII, p. 195.
81. Pascal, Pensées, III, 206 (t. II, p. 127, Brunschvigg): “Le silence éternel de
ces espaces infinis m’effraie.”
82. See Lecture III, p. 98; VI, p. 161 s.; VII, p. 184.
86. Lehrs, Populäre Aufsätze aus dem Altertum, 1875, p. 349 ss.; Fowler,
Religious Experience of the Roman People, p. 382 ss.
100. See Lecture II, p. 90; IV, p. 109; VIII, p. 196 ss., 206.
105. Propertius, IV, 5, 3: “Nec sedeant cineri Manes.” Cf. Lucan, IX, 2.
106. Pliny, H. N., XVI, 44, §234; cf. Livy, XXXVIII, 53.
109. Bücheler, Carm. epigr., 1555: “Haec certa est domus, haec est colenda
nobis.”
110. Virg., Aen., III, 67: “Animam sepulcro condimus.” Cf. Pliny, Epist., III, 27,
12: “Rite conditis Manibus.”
113. Lucian, Philopseudes, 27; cf. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8379, l. 50 ss.
114. Kaibel, Epigr. Graeca, 646 = Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8156; cf. Lucian, De
luctu, 19.
120. Servius, Aen., V, 79: “Ad sanguinis imitationem, in quo est sedes animae.”
Cf. II, 532.
123. CIL, XIV, 3323 = Dessau, 8090: “Hoc peto aego a bobis unibersis
sodalibus ut sene bile refrigeretis.”
127. Dessau, 8154 = CIL, XII, 5102 = Bücheler, Carm. epigr., 788:
130. Augustine, De mor. eccles., 34: “Qui luxuriosissime super mortuos bibant
et epulas cadaveribus exhibentes super sepultos se ipsos sepeliant et voracitates
ebrietatesque suas deputent religioni.”
131. Constitutiones Apostol., VIII, 42.
133. Cf. Petronius, 71: “Omne genus poma volo sint circa cineres meos et
vinearum largiter”; Dessau, 8342 ss.; below, Lecture VIII, p. 200.
139. Diog. Laert., VIII, 32; cf. Servius, Aen., III, 63; Lecture VI, p. 160.
144. CIL, VIII, 2803a: “Donata, pia, iusta, vale, serva tuos omnes.”
148. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8006. “Manus mala” means probably a murder
produced by witchcraft; cf. ibid., 8522; Lecture V, p. 135.
152. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8201a: “Tu qui legis et dubitas Manes esse, sponsione
facta invoca nos et intelleges.”
155. CIL, VI, 12072: “Parce matrem tuam et patrem et sororem tuam
Marinam, ut possint tibi facere post me sollemnia.”
158. Plato, Republ., X, 615 A B; cf. Norden, Aeneis Buch VI, p. 10.
160. Virg., Aen., VI, 325 ss: “Inops inhumataque turba.... Centum errant annos
volitantque haec litora circum.”
171. Piganiol, Revue d’histoire et de litt. religieuses, VI, 1920, p. 335 ss.
187. Tim. Locr., De anim. mundi, 17, p. 104 D; cf. Schmekel, Mittlere Stoa,
1892, p. 435.
189. Cf. on this doctrine Revue de philologie, XLIV, 1920, p. 230 ss.
193. On this doctrine see Comptes rendus Acad. Inscriptions, 1920, p. 272 ss.
197. Cic., Tusc., I, 21, 48; cf. I, 6, 10; Nat. deor., II, 2, 5.
201. Plutarch, Non posse suaviter vivi sec. Epic., 27, p. 1105.
204. See, for instance, Jahresh. Instit. Wien, XVII, 1914, p. 133 ss.; or Hermes,
XXXVII, 1902, p. 121 ss.
209. Plutarch, Non posse suaviter vivi sec. Epic., 27, p. 1105.
216. Porph., De abstin., 38 ss.; cf. Bousset, Archiv für Religionswiss., XVIII,
1915, p. 134 ss., and Andres in Realencycl., Supplementband, III, 315.
217. Cf. Comptes rendus Acad. Inscriptions, 1918, p. 278 ss.
224. Toutain, Revue des études anciennes, XIII, 1911, p. 166 ss.; cf. ibid., p.
379 s.
231. Jamblich., Vit. Pyth., XVIII, 82 = Diels, Vorsokratiker, I3, p. 358, 18; cf.
Plut., De genio Socr., 22, p. 590 C; Hierocles, In Aur. carm., end.
242. CIL, VI, 29954; see below, Lecture VI, p. 157 ss.
243. Commodian, VIII, 10: “Sacerdotes ... numina qui dicunt aliquid morituro
prodesse.”
246. Lucan, Phars., I, 45; Statius, Theb., I, 27; cf. my Études syriennes, 1917,
p. 97 s.
250. Cic., Tusc., I, 12, 28: “Totum prope caelum nonne humano generi
completum est?”
254. Porph., Sent., 292 (p. 14, Mommert); Proclus, In Remp., I, p. 152, 17,
Kroll; In Tim., III, p. 234, 25, Diehl.
255. Cf. my Mysteries of Mithras, Chicago, 1903, p. 145; below, Lecture VI, p.
169; VII, p. 187.
256. Origen, Contra Celsum, VI, 21; cf. Monum. mystères de Mithra, I, p. 118.
261. Ibid., p. 7.
265. Manilius, I, 41; cf. Boll, Aus der Offenbarung Iohannis, 1914, p. 136 ss.
270. Hermes Trismeg. ap. Stob., Ecl., I, 49, 69 (I, p. 466, Wachsmuth).
273. CIL, VI, 1779 = Bücheler, Carm. epigr., 111, 23: “(Me) sorte mortis
eximens in templa ducis....”
283. Hermes Trismeg., Poimandres, I, 26: Τοῦτό ἐστι τὸ ἀγαθὸν τέλος τοῖς
γνῶσιν ἐσχηκόσι θεωθῆναι.
286. See Oriental religions, p. 100, and below, Lecture VIII, p. 210 ss.
298. Plato, Republ., p. 615 C; cf. Norden, Aeneis Buch VI, 1903, pp. 11, 27.
301. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8497 ss.; cf. Recueil des inscriptions du Pont, 9, 258.
302. Horace, Epod., 5, 92; cf. Livy, III, 58, 11.
307. Diog. Laert., II, 5, §45; cf. Lamprid., Heliog., 33, 2: “Praedictum eidem
erat a sacerdotibus Syris biothanatum se futurum.”
309. Macrob., Somn. Scip., I, 13, 1, probably after Numenius (Revue des
études grecques, XXXII, 1921, p. 119 s.).
313. Demon: Kaibel, Epigr. Gr., 566, 4; 569, 3, etc.—Evil god: Dessau, 8498;
cf. 9093: “Cui (sic) dii nefandi parvulo contra votum genitorum vita privaverunt.”
316. Rohde, Psyche, II4, p. 411; cf. Perdrizet, Negotium perambulans, 1922, p.
19 ss.
317. Audollent, Defixionum tabellae, 1904, p. 40, nr, 22 ss.; see above, Lecture
I, p. 68.
318. Wessely, Griech. Zauberpap. aus Paris in Denkschr. Akad. Wien, XXXVI,
1888, p. 85, l. 2577 ss., p. 86, l. 2645 ss.
325. Sen., Dial., VI, 23, 1; Plut., Cons. ad uxorem, 11; cf. Dessau, 8481 ss.
330. Bücheler, Carm. epigr., 569: “Vitaeque e limine raptus.... Non tamen ad
Manes sed caeli ad sidera pergis.” Cf. ibid., 569, 611.
332. Rohde, Psyche, II4, p. 374, n. 2; Lawson, Modern Greek folk-lore, 1910 p.
140 ss.; cf. Dessau, 8748.
333. Bücheler, Carm. epigr., 1233; cf. Statius, Silv., II, 6, 100.
334. Kaibel, Epigr. Graeca, 570, 571; cf. CIL, VI, 29195 = Dessau, 8482:
“Ulpius Firmus, anima bona superis reddita, raptus a Nymphis.”
335. Cf. Anderson, Journ. hell. stud., XIX, 1899, p. 127, nr, 142, and below,
note 42.
343. Horace, Od., III, 2, 21; cf. Introd., p. 13; Lecture IV, p. 113.
347. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 7846: “Extra auctorateis et quei sibei [la]queo manu
attulissent et quei quaestum spurcum professi essent.”
350. Cf. Revue des études grecques, XXXII, 1921, p. 113 ss.
370. See Lecture III, p. 107; Monum. mystères de Mithra, I, p. 118 s.; II, p.
525.
372. Charles R. Morey, East Christian paintings in the Freer collection, New
York, 1914, p. 17 ss.
373. Ladder among other magical emblems on terra cotta discs found at
Taranto; cf. Revue archéologique, V, 1917, p. 102.
377. Cf. Joseph Keil, Jahresh. Instituts Wien, XVII, 1914, pp. 138, 142, n. 13;
Bormann, Bericht des Vereins Carnuntum, 1908–1911, p. 330, where Itala felix
applies not to the ship but to the dead woman.
386. Eunap., Hist., fr. 26 (F. H. G. IV, 25; cf. Études syriennes, p. 104).
388. Weichert, Der Seelenvogel in der alten Literatur und Kunst, Leipzig,
1902; see above, Lecture III, p. 93.
391. Anth. Pal., VII, 62 = Diog. Laert., III, 44; cf. Études syriennes, p. 88:
400. Cic., Tusc., I, 42 ss.; Sextus Empir., Adv. Math., IX, 71, 4; cf. above,
Introd., p. 29.
401. Winds and souls, see below, Lecture VII, p. 185.
402. See below, Lecture VII, p. 186; cf. Lecture II, p. 81.
425. Timaeus, p. 41 D E.
426. See above, Lecture III, p. 106 s., and Introd., p. 41; cf. p. 24.
434. Even the devout Plutarch rejects them as superstitious imaginations; cf.
De superst., 167 A.
437. Punishment by fire is mentioned for the first time in Philodemos, Περὶ
θεῶν, XIX, 16 ss. Philodemos being a Syrian, it is not unlikely that this tenet is of
Oriental origin. Cf. Diels, Abhandl. Akad. Berlin, 1916, p. 80, n. 3.
438. See above, Introd., pp. 8, 17 s., and Lecture II, p. 83.
440. The Druses have even preserved the ancient doctrine that the number of
souls is always the same in the world. Cf. Silvestre de Sacy, Religion des Druses,
1838, II, p. 459.
444. Hermes Trismeg. ap. Stob., Ecl., I, 49, p. 398, 16 ss., Wachsmuth.
445. Tim. Locr., p. 104 E.
446. Ps.-Plut., Vita Homeri, 126; Porph. ap. Stob., Ecl., I, 49, 60, p. 445,
Wachsmuth.
451. Museum of the University of California; Kaibel, Inscr. Sicil. et Ital., 12,
1196. The sentence is taken from Republ., X, 617 C.
452. Porph., De regressu anim., fr. 11, Bidez = Aug., Civ. Dei, X, 30; Jamblich.
ap. Nemes., De nat. hom., 2; cf. Zeller, Philos. Gr., V4, p. 713.
453. .sp 1
“Has omnes, ubi mille rotam volvere per annos,
Lethaeum ad fluvium deus evocat agmine magno,
Scilicet immemores super ut convexa revisant,
Rursus et incipiant in corpore velle reverti.”
Aen., VI, 749–753.
456. See Lecture VI, p. 161; cf. below, Lecture VIII, p. 196.
462. Macrob., Comm. Somn. Scip., I, 11, 8; Proclus, In Tim., II, 48, 15 ss.,
Diehl.
465. Tibullus, II, 6, 30: “Sic bene sub tenera parva quiescat humo.”
467. Securitati aeternae; cf. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8025 ss., 8149.
468. Cic., Catil., IV, 7; cf. Tusc., I, 11, 25; 49, 118.
470. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8024 and note; cf. Cic., Tusc., I, 41, 97; and Introd., p.
10.
473. Bücheler, ibid., 507: “Poena fuit vita, requies mihi morte parata est.”
475. Dessau, Inscr. sel., 8393, 79: “Te di Manes tui ut quietam patiantur atque
ita tueantur opto.”
480. Comptes rendus Acad. Inscr., 1912, p. 151 ss.; cf. Bücheler, Carm. epigr.,
513.
485. Zeno, fr. 147 (von Arnim, Fragm. Stoicorum, I, p. 40): “Zeno docuit sedes
piorum ab impiis esse discretas et illos quidem quietas ac delectabiles habitare
regiones.”
486. See Introd., p. 25; Lecture III, p. 96.
490. Sen., Consol. Marc., 24, 5: “(Animus) nititur illo unde demissus est; ibi
illum aeterna requies manet e confusis crassisque pura et liquida visentem.”
492. Cf. Aug., Serm., CCLX (P.L. XXXVIII, 1132, 38): “Dixerunt Platonici ...
animas, ire ad superna caelorum et requiescere ibi in stellis et luminibus istis
conspicuis.”
495. St. Ambrose, De bono mortis, 9; cf. Kaibel, Inscr. Sic. It., 2117.
498. IV Esdr., VII, 91: “Requiescent per septem ordines”; cf. VII, 95 (p. 131 ss.,
Violet).
500. Ambrose, De bono mortis, 12, § 53 (P.L., XIV, 154); cf. IV Esdr., VII, 39.
515. Bücheler, Carm. epigr., 1317 = CIL, VI, 142; cf. Plato, Phaedo, p. 107D.
521. Julian, Caesares, p. 307 C; cf. Introd., p. 29; Lecture III, p. 98.
525. For instance, by the physician Thessalus (under Nero); cf. Cat. codd.
astrol., VIII, 3, p. 137; VIII, 4, p. 257.
530. The true interpretation has been given by Bevan, Stoics and Sceptics,
1913, p. 112 s.
531. Georg., II, 489 ss.:
537. Μόνος πρὸς μόνῳ. The expression had been used by religion before
being taken over by philosophy. Cf. Le culte égyptien et le mysticisme de Plotin, in
Monuments Piot, XXV, 1922, p. 78 ss.
TRANSCRIBER’S NOTES
1. P. 137, changed ἄνώνυμοι to ἀνώνυμοι.
2. P. 137, changed ἄτρόφοι to ἄτροφοι.
3. P. 225, changed Ἁγιάζο to Ἁγιάζω.
4. P. 225, changed εἴς to εἰς.
5. [391], changed ἀποσκοπεεις to ἀποσκοπέεις.
ἕλικας.
8. Silently corrected typographical errors and variations in
spelling.
9. Archaic, non-standard, and uncertain spellings retained
as printed.
10. Footnotes were re-indexed using numbers and collected
together at the end of the last chapter.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK AFTER LIFE IN
ROMAN PAGANISM ***
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
ebooknice.com