Lecture 22 S1_2025
Lecture 22 S1_2025
Reshad Ahsan
Lecture 22
Introductory Microeconomics
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 1 / 23
Learning objectives
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 2 / 23
Cournot quantity competition
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 3 / 23
Firm 1’ production problem
where Q1 and Q2 are Firm 1 and Firm 2’s output, respectively, and
QT = Q1 + Q2 is the total industry output.
If Firm 2 increases its output, the market price will fall, and adversely
affect Firm 1.
Firm 1 seeks to maximise: π1 = P(QT )Q1 − TC (Q1 ).
Profit maximisation (dπ1 /dQ1 = 0) allows us to derive Firm 1’s
reaction function.1
1
Deriving Cournot reaction functions is easier as you can use the MR = MC equilibrium
condition. I have skipped this step here, but you are encouraged the derive the reaction function
in the next slide from Firm 1’s profit maximisation problem with MC = 25. Next week’s tutorial
will give you another opportunity to practice this.
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 4 / 23
Firm 1’ reaction function
Q1
Q1
This tells us Firm 2’s profit-
maximizing output in response
R2
to Firm 1’s output.
Notice that the optimal Q2 is
also declining in Q1 .
To plot the above, we can
rearrange it to write Q1 =
75 − 2Q2 . R1
Q2
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 6 / 23
Cournot equilibrium
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 7 / 23
Outline
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 8 / 23
Political advertising
2
In the U.S. context, political advertising is more effective because it influences turnout, an issue that is less important in
Australia.
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 9 / 23
Game theory
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 10 / 23
Important concepts
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 11 / 23
Nash equilibrium
Nash equilibrium
A situation in which players each
choose their best strategy given the
strategies that all other players have
chosen.
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 12 / 23
A payoff matrix
Consider the payoff matrix (or game table) below that lists each
player’s payoffs from various advertising scenarios.
Player 2
(column player)
Advertise Don’t advertise
Advertise (250, 250) (750, 0)
Player 1 (row player)
Don’t advertise (0, 750) (500, 500)
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 13 / 23
Considering Nash equilibrium candidates
Player 2
Advertise Don’t advertise
Advertise (250, 250) (750, 0)
Player 1
Don’t advertise (0, 750) (500, 500)
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 14 / 23
Considering other Nash equilibrium candidates
Player 2
Advertise Don’t advertise
Advertise (250, 250) (750, 0)
Player 1
Don’t advertise (0, 750) (500, 500)
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 15 / 23
Nash equilibrium
Player 2
Advertise Don’t advertise
Advertise (250, 250) (750, 0)
Player 1
Don’t advertise (0, 750) (500, 500)
Thus, the only cell where neither player has an incentive to deviate is
(Advertise, Advertise). This is the Nash equilibrium.
This is an equilibrium with a lower combined and individual payoff
than (Don’t advertise, Don’t advertise).
This is an illustration of a prisoner’s dilemma, where cooperation is
mutually beneficial but difficult to maintain.
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 16 / 23
Worked example
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 17 / 23
Worked example: solution
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 18 / 23
Outline
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 19 / 23
Dominant strategy
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 20 / 23
Iterated deletion of dominated strategies in a 3 × 3 payoff
matrix
Player 2
Low Med. High
Low (1, 2) (0, 1) (2, 0)
Player 1 Med. (2, 3) (1, 2) (3, 1)
High (4, 4) (5, 5) (6, 6)
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 21 / 23
Nash equilibrium in a 3 × 3 payoff matrix
Player 2
Low Med. High
Low (1, 2) (0, 1) (2, 0)
Player 1 Med. (2, 3) (1, 2) (3, 1)
High (4, 4) (5, 5) (6, 6)
If Player 1 chooses High, then Player 2 knows that High is also its
dominant strategy.
It follows that (High, High) is the unique Nash equilibrium.
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 22 / 23
Additional materials
This week’s optional exercise asks you to consider a game where there
is more than one Nash equilibrium.
Recommendations for further reading (optional)
An analysis of political donations before 2022 federal elections.
Lecture 22 (ECON10004) 23 / 23