Short Term Momentum
Short Term Momentum
Mamdouh Medhat
Cass Business School, City, University of London
Maik Schmeling
Goethe University Frankfurt and Centre for Economic Policy Research
(CEPR)
A key stylized fact in the asset pricing literature is that stock returns
exhibit reversal at short horizons of 1 month (Jegadeesh 1990) but
continuation—or momentum—at longer horizons between 2 and 12
months (Jegadeesh and Titman 1993, 2001). In this paper, we show
that reversal and momentum coexist with striking magnitudes at the 1-
month horizon. While the previous month’s thinly traded stocks exhibit
a strong short-term reversal e↵ect, the previous month’s heavily traded
stocks exhibit an almost equally strong continuation e↵ect, which we
We appreciate helpful comments from Ralph Koijen and two anonymous referees. We also
thank Cli↵ Asness, Pedro Barroso, John Campbell, Giovanni Cespa, Zhi Da, Alexander
Hillert, Alexandre Jeanneret, Christian Julliard, Tim Krönke, Albert Menkveld, Markus
Nöth, Richard Payne, Lasse Pedersen, Chris Polk, Angelo Ranaldo, Savina Rizova, Ioanid
Roşu, Lucio Sarno, Julian Thimme, Gyuri Venter, Michela Verardo, Christian Wagner,
Josef Zechner, and Irina Zviadadze; seminar participants at various business schools and
asset managers; and participants at the Chicago Quantitative Alliance 2018 fall conference,
the Research in Behavioral Finance 2018 conference, the London Empirical Asset Pricing
2019 fall workshop, the Swiss Society for Financial Market Research 2019 annual meeting,
the French Finance Association 2019 annual meeting, the London Business School 2019
summer symposium, and the 12th annual Hedge Fund Research Conference. We are
grateful for the Best Paper Award at the Chicago Quantitative Alliance (CQA) 2018
Academic Competition. All errors are our own. Send correspondence to Maik Schmeling,
[email protected].
Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies 2021.
doi:10.1093/rfs/Sample Advance Access publication XXXX XX, 2021
Coexistence
Coexistenceofofreversal
reversaland
andmomentum
momentumininone-month returns
1-month returns
20%
16.44%
10%
Average excess return (annualized)
0%
-3.39%
-10%
-16.92%
-20%
Short-term reversal* Short-term reversal Short-term momentum
[Lowest turnover decile] [All stocks] [Highest turnover decile]
Figure 1
Coexistence of reversal and momentum in 1-month returns
This figure shows the average excess returns to three long-short strategies that buy
the previous month’s winners and short the losers among U.S. stocks. The conventional
short-term reversal strategy (Jegadeesh, 1990) is from a univariate decile sort on the
previous month’s return using NYSE breakpoints. The short-term reversal* and short-
term momentum strategies trade the corner portfolios from double decile sorts on the
previous month’s return and the previous month’s share turnover using NYSE breakpoints;
short-term reversal* trades only in the lowest-turnover decile while short-term momentum
trades only in the highest-turnover decile. The portfolios underlying all three strategies
are value weighted and rebalanced at the end of each month. The performance of the
portfolios underlying the short-term reversal* and short-term momentum strategies is
provided in Table 1. The sample is all common nonfinancial shares on the NYSE, AMEX,
and NASDAQ exchanges and covers July 1963 to December 2018.
dub short-term momentum. Figure 1 illustrates our main results for the
United States.
To obtain our main results, we double decile sort stocks on the
previous month’s return and the previous month’s share turnover using
NYSE breakpoints and form value-weighted portfolios. We find, first,
significant short-term reversal among stocks with low share turnover.
The short-term reversal* strategy, which buys the previous month’s
winners and shorts the losers within the lowest turnover decile, generates
a negative and significant average return of 16.9% per annum (Figure
1, left bar). Second, our key finding is that short-term reversal is reversed
among stocks with high share turnover. The short-term momentum
strategy, which buys the previous month’s winners and shorts the losers
within the highest turnover decile, generates a positive and significant
average return of +16.4% per annum (Figure 1, right bar). We show
that both strategies generate significant abnormal returns relative to
the standard factor models currently applied in the literature. We also
show that short-term momentum persists for 12 months and is strongest
among the largest and most liquid stocks. Finally, we show that our main
findings extend to 22 developed markets outside the United States.
We provide additional results and robustness tests that shed light
on the economic drivers of our findings. First, skipping the last few
days of the formation month implies stronger short-term momentum (on
average 22.0% per annum) because this mitigates end-of-month liquidity
trading (Etula, Rinne, Suominen, and Vaittinen 2020). Second, short-
term momentum survives conservative estimates of transaction costs
(Novy-Marx and Velikov 2015). Third, while short-term momentum
is naturally related to conventional price- and earnings-momentum
strategies, its correlations with such strategies are moderate and do
not appear to fully capture its average return, at least when judged
by spanning tests. Fourth, short-term momentum does not appear to
be driven by momentum in industry returns (Moskowitz and Grinblatt
1999) or by momentum in factor returns (Ehsani and Linnainmaa 2020).
Fifth, it is not a result of any correlation between share turnover and
size, liquidity, or volatility. Lastly, it exhibits far less crash risk than
does conventional price momentum (Daniel and Moskowitz 2016).
Short-term momentum is difficult to reconcile with rational expec-
tations equilibrium (REE) models of the volume-return relation. In
Campbell, Grossman, and Wang (1993), noninformational trading due
to liquidity demand causes temporary price pressure when absorbed
by liquidity suppliers. As a result, returns coupled with high volume
will subsequently reverse. This runs opposite to short-term momentum.
In Wang (1994) and Llorente et al. (2002), informed trading due to
private information causes persistent price movements that counteract
temporary price pressure. Hence, among stocks with a high degree of
information asymmetry, returns coupled with high volume will reverse
less and may even continue. This would be an explanation for short-term
momentum if it were driven by high-information-asymmetry stocks.
However, while Wang (1994) and Llorente et al. (2002) argue that such
stocks should be small, illiquid, and have low analyst coverage, short-
term momentum is strongest among the largest, most liquid, and most
extensively covered stocks.1
1
Wang (1994) argues that contemporaneous evidence “is consistent with our model if we
assume that there is more information asymmetry in the market for small-size firms than
for large-size firms” (p. 151). Llorente et al. (2002) proxy for higher information asymmetry
using smaller size, lower liquidity, and lower analyst coverage.
2
Models of boundedly rational traders have been invoked to explain why volume greatly
exceeds what is expected under REE and why patterns in returns and volume are tightly
linked (see, e.g., Hong and Stein 2007; French 2008). Underreaction is often invoked as
the mechanism underlying return continuation in models that relax the strict rationality
assumption (see, e.g., Fama 1998; Daniel and Hirshleifer 2015).
3
In his explanation of the opposing findings, Cooper (1999) conjectures that “in the context
of Wang’s (1994) model, it may be that in periods of large price movements, high volume
for smaller (larger) stocks represents a higher percentage of liquidity (informed) traders,
resulting in greater subsequent reversals (continuations)” (p. 921). This contrasts with
Wang’s (1994) argument that high-information-asymmetry stocks should be smaller, not
larger (see our footnote 1). While our evidence in principle supports Cooper’s conjecture,
we will argue in Section 3 that it is for reasons outside of the Wang model.
4
Our asset pricing tests employ value-weighted portfolios from sorts based on NYSE
breakpoints as well as weighted least squares (WLS) cross-sectional regressions with
market capitalization as the weight. Llorente et al. (2002) use stock-by-stock, full-sample
regressions of daily returns on the previous day’s return and its interaction with de-trended
log-turnover in their tests. Based on ex post cross-sectional variation in the interaction
coefficients, they argue that high-volume days are followed by return continuation among
the smallest and most illiquid stocks. Since their horizon is daily and their findings are not
based on investable portfolios, their tests are inherently di↵erent from ours. Furthermore,
the fact that any such daily return continuation is limited to the smallest and most illiquid
stocks raises questions about its economic significance.
5
Asness (1995) finds stronger 1-month reversal among low-volume stocks but does not
document continuation among high-volume ones. Lee and Swaminathan (2000) study how
volume a↵ects the relation between the value and momentum e↵ects, but consider longer
formation periods of at least 3 months. Gervais, Kaniel, and Mingelgrin (2001) find that
stocks with unusually high volume outperform those with unusually low volume. Cespa,
Gargano, Riddiough, and Sarno (2020) find stronger reversal in daily returns among low-
volume currencies but do not find continuation among high-volume currencies.
with reversal at the 1-month horizon, albeit confined to the stocks with
the highest trading activity. In addition, we provide guidance as to
which broader class of models (fully vs. boundedly rational) that is most
plausible as an explanation for short-term momentum.
1. Main Results
This section presents our main results. We first show that double sorting
on the previous month’s return and turnover reveals strong reversal
among low-turnover stocks but almost equally strong momentum among
high-turnover stocks. We then show that standard factors cannot
account for either e↵ect; that the returns to the short-term momentum
strategy persist for 12 months after formation; and that short-term
momentum is strongest among the largest stocks. Finally, we show that
our main results also hold internationally.
6
Prior to February 2001, we divide NASDAQ volume by 2.0. From February 2001 to
December 2001, we divide by 1.8. From January 2002 to December 2003, we divide by
1.6. From January 2004 and onward, NASDAQ volume no longer di↵ers from NYSE and
AMEX volume, and we apply no adjustment.
TO 1,0 deciles
Portfolio excess return
Low 1.28 1.23 0.99 0.85 0.70 0.80 0.59 0.74 0.26 0.14 1.41 1.45 1.43
( 7.13) ( 6.19) ( 5.95)
2 1.54 1.22 0.98 0.99 1.05 0.98 0.70 0.69 0.57 0.35 1.19 1.31 1.34
( 4.61) ( 4.04) ( 4.21)
3 1.71 1.53 0.96 1.11 0.99 0.94 0.75 0.60 0.64 0.36 1.34 1.62 1.66
( 5.02) ( 5.61) ( 4.87)
Short-term Momentum
4 1.51 1.35 1.43 0.98 1.10 1.07 0.81 0.83 0.64 0.65 0.85 1.02 0.91
( 3.63) ( 4.15) ( 2.92)
5 1.11 1.10 1.26 1.17 1.10 1.00 0.60 0.92 0.90 0.66 0.45 0.63 0.51
( 1.94) ( 2.29) ( 1.54)
6 1.26 1.38 1.40 1.14 1.00 1.14 1.12 1.19 0.78 0.67 0.59 0.60 0.41
( 2.50) ( 2.35) ( 1.20)
7 1.39 1.06 1.12 1.22 0.84 1.05 0.83 0.98 0.96 0.73 0.67 0.85 0.96
( 2.52) ( 2.55) ( 2.37)
8 0.92 1.17 1.25 0.99 1.12 1.02 1.02 0.85 0.82 1.15 0.23 0.13 0.21
(0.85) (0.47) (0.60)
9 0.71 1.37 1.29 1.24 1.21 1.22 1.00 1.12 1.02 0.75 0.05 0.00 0.19
(0.21) (0.01) (0.55)
High 0.00 0.83 1.14 1.08 1.03 0.78 1.01 1.16 0.99 1.36 1.37 1.37 1.65
(4.74) (4.22) (4.47)
TO 1,0 strategies
E[re ] 1.28 0.41 0.15 0.23 0.33 0.01 0.42 0.42 0.73 1.50
( 5.04) ( 1.75) (0.59) (0.80) (1.34) ( 0.05) (1.58) (1.54) (2.76) (5.46)
7
NYSE breakpoints, first on r1,0 and then on TO 1,0 . Portfolios are value weighted and rebalanced at the end of each month. The table also shows
the performance of long-short strategies across the deciles. Test statistics (in parentheses) are adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation.
Time-series averages of the portfolios’ characteristics are provided in Table A.1 in the appendix. The sample excludes financial firms. Data are at the
monthly frequency and cover July 1963 to December 2018, except for the q-factors, which are available from January 1967.
The Review of Financial Studies / v 00 n 0 2021
7
The models of Campbell, Grossman, and Wang (1993), Wang (1994), and Llorente et al.
(2002) suggest a nonlinear relation between expected and realized returns for a given level
of volume. Conditional sorts allow us to use the full sample period, but Table A.2 in the
appendix shows similar results for independent sorts starting from July 1969. Sorting first
on returns and then on turnover produces the largest spreads in holding-period returns,
but the results are similar for the reverse sorting order. The average cross-sectional rank
correlation between 1-month returns and turnover is 9.99% (t = 8.29), so the interpretation
of the double sorts is largely una↵ected by the sorting order. Our use of conditional decile
sorts based on NYSE breakpoints follows Fama and French (1992). Fama and French
(2015, 2016) also use conditional sorts based on NYSE breakpoints in some of their tests
and Ken French maintains several decile double sorts on his website.
8
For comparison, the conventional STREV strategy (from a univariate decile sort on r1,0 )
yields 0.28% with t = 1.68 over our sample; see also Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2015, 2020).
The corresponding conventional momentum strategy (from a univariate decile sort on the
prior 12-2 month returns) yields 1.21% per month with t = 4.77.
Table 2
Short-term momentum’s factor exposures and abnormal returns
9
The STMOM strategy is not within the univariate span of the MOM factor (abnormal
return of 1.13% with t = 3.36). The converse is also true. The STREV* strategy is not
within the univariate span of the standard STREV factor (abnormal return of 0.91%
with t = 4.78), but the standard STREV factor is, in fact, within the univariate span of
the STREV* strategy (abnormal return of 0.03% with t = 0.31).
10
A
8
Short-term momentum
-2
1 6 12 18 24
600
200
-200
-600
-1000
Figure 2
Short-term momentum’s persistence and historical performance Panel A shows
the average cumulative sums of post-formation excess returns to each of the short-term
momentum and short-term reversal* strategies along with 95% confidence bands. Panel
B shows a time-series plot of cumulative sums of excess returns to the two strategies as
well as a conventional short-term reversal strategy. Data are at the monthly frequency
and cover July 1963 to December 2018.
11
Table 3
Short-term momentum controlling for size
12
10
The largest-500 STMOM strategy trades in an average of 129 and 121 stocks on its long
and short sides with average market capitalizations of $14.0 billion and $13.7 billion.
In December 2018 (the end of our sample), the top-five holdings on the long side were
Alphabet, Exxon, Walmart, AT&T, and Home Depot, while the top-five holdings on the
short side were Microsoft, Johnson & Johnson, Pfizer, Verizon, and Procter & Gamble.
11
Hendershott and Menkveld (2014), for instance, study price pressure across NYSE size
quintiles and find that “[p]rice pressure for the quintile of largest stocks is 17 basis points
with a half life of 0.54 days. For the smallest-stocks quintile, it is 118 basis points with a
half life of 2.11 days. These price pressures are roughly the size of the (e↵ective) bid-ask
spread” (p. 406).
13
continuation. We will later show that our results are also not driven by
any correlation between turnover and each of liquidity and volatility.
As we will discuss in Section 3, the results of Table 3 are at odds
with the “high-information-asymmetry” mechanism in the models of
Wang (1994) and Llorente et al. (2002), which counterfactually predicts
stronger STMOM performance among smaller stocks. In practical terms,
the results of Table 3 mean that STMOM is considerably cheaper
to implement and more scalable than is STREV*. In Section 2.2, we
will study the performance of the large-caps and megacaps STMOM
strategies net of transaction costs and with an implementation lag.
12
Following Fama and French (2015), we define book equity, B, as shareholder’s equity plus
deferred taxes minus preferred stock. In the definition of B, shareholder’s equity is SEQ.
If SEQ is missing, we substitute it by common equity (CEQ) plus preferred stock (defined
below), or else by total assets minus total liabilities (AT LT). Deferred taxes is deferred
taxes and investment tax credits (TXDITC) or else deferred taxes and/or investment tax
credit (TXDB and/or ITCB). Finally, preferred stock is redemption value (PSTKR) or
else liquidating value (PSTKL) or else carrying value (PSTK). B/M is book equity divided
by market capitalization (CRSP’s PRC times SHROUT) as of prior December, where the
lagging is to avoid taking unintentional positions in conventional momentum. dA/A 1 is
the year-over-year change in total assets divided by 1-year-lagged total assets. Following
Ball et al. (2016), COP is total revenue (REVT) minus cost of goods sold (COGS), minus
selling, general, and administrative expenses (XSGA), plus R&D expenditures (XRD,
zero if missing), minus the change in accounts receivable (RECT), minus the change
in inventory (INVT), minus the change in prepaid expenses (XPP), plus the change in
deferred revenue (DRC + DRLT), plus the change in trade accounts payable (AP), plus
the change in accrued expenses (XACC). All changes are annual, and missing changes are
set to zero.
14
0.32 0.59 0.50 0.63 0.42 0.62 0.46 0.65 0.47 0.73 0.25 0.52
Short-term Momentum
r1,0
( 4.16) ( 8.05) ( 6.76) ( 8.21) ( 5.62) ( 8.29) ( 5.88) ( 8.82) ( 5.15) ( 7.28) ( 2.36) ( 5.08)
TO 1,0 0.06 0.05 0.10 0.10 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.02 0.09 0.01
(0.64) ( 0.82) (1.39) (1.31) ( 0.33) ( 0.17) ( 0.13) ( 0.21) (0.91) (0.25) (0.67) (0.12)
r1,0 ⇥TO 1,0 0.19 0.29 0.20 0.19 0.16 0.18 0.18 0.23 0.26 0.33 0.35 0.57
(5.45) (9.06) (6.21) (6.04) (5.23) (5.06) (5.66) (5.17) (5.10) (5.26) (4.01) (5.74)
15
equity. Data are at the monthly frequency and cover July 1963 to December 2018.
The Review of Financial Studies / v 00 n 0 2021
The all-stock regressions show that r1,0 predicts the cross section
of monthly returns with a negative and significant slope (t-statistic of
4.16 without controls and 8.05 with controls). They also show that
r1,0 ⇥TO 1,0 has roughly the same predictive power as r1,0 itself, albeit
with a positive slope (t-statistics of 5.45 and 9.06). Similar results hold
within each size quintile, although the slope on r1,0 generally decreases
in magnitude with size while that on r1,0 ⇥TO 1,0 tends to increase
with size. This suggests that low-turnover reversal becomes weaker with
size and, conversely, that high-turnover continuation becomes stronger
with size, consistent with the size-conditional strategy performance in
Table 3. Taken literally, the regressions suggest that 1-month returns
are positively autocorrelated when turnover is 0.50/0.20 = 2.5 standard
deviations above average among microcaps, but that 0.25/0.35 = 0.7
standard deviations are enough for the same relation among megacaps.
We caution, however, against reading too much into the magnitudes
of the slope estimates or taking the parametric relations literally. Cross-
sectional regressions are useful for studying return predictability in a
multivariate setting but, unlike portfolio sorts, they impose a potentially
misspecified functional form and are sensitive to outliers (Fama and
French, 2010). Furthermore, the R2 values in Table 4 imply that
over 80% of the variation in monthly returns is not captured by the
parametric relations. A more careful interpretation (cf. Fama, 1976)
is that each slope is the average return to a long-short strategy that
trades on a unit spread in the part of the variation in the independent
variable that is orthogonal to all other independent variables. Under
that interpretation, each t-statistic is proportional to the Sharpe ratio
of the implied long-short strategy. The regressions in Table 4 thus
show that the long-short strategy that trades on orthogonal variation in
r1,0 ⇥TO 1,0 generates a positive Sharpe ratio that is roughly equal in
magnitude to the negative Sharpe ratio on the strategy that trades on
orthogonal variation in r1,0 .13
13
This interpretation is applicable here because the interaction is far from perfectly
correlated with the straight variables: if we let z(·) denote standardization, then the
average cross-sectional rank correlation between z(r1,0 )⇥z(TO 1,0 ) and each of z(r1,0 )
and z(TO 1,0 ) is 17.34% (t = 35.22) and 4.00% (t = 12.10), respectively.
14
The countries are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France,
Germany, Great Britain (the United Kingdom), Greece, Hong Kong, Italy, Ireland,
Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Singapore, Spain, Sweden, and
Switzerland.
16
TO 1,0 deciles
Portfolio excess return
Low 1.28 0.57 0.42 0.14 0.21 0.43 0.27 0.55 1.06 1.97 3.25 3.06
( 6.36) ( 5.83)
2 1.66 0.69 0.25 0.21 0.17 0.09 0.11 0.02 0.40 0.88 2.53 2.09
( 4.63) ( 2.90)
3 1.02 0.59 0.39 0.24 0.29 0.06 0.31 0.03 0.57 1.37 2.40 2.09
Short-term Momentum
( 5.16) ( 4.50)
4 0.63 0.87 0.44 0.30 0.39 0.41 0.20 0.10 0.18 0.52 1.14 0.74
( 2.73) ( 1.71)
5 1.27 0.75 0.31 0.37 0.27 0.43 0.60 0.33 0.31 0.54 1.81 1.47
( 4.13) ( 2.24)
6 0.46 0.62 0.38 0.47 0.61 0.27 0.46 0.32 0.20 0.15 0.61 0.10
( 1.58) ( 0.22)
7 0.91 0.62 0.04 0.51 0.11 0.42 0.39 0.20 0.21 0.08 0.83 0.93
( 2.01) ( 1.65)
8 0.38 0.46 0.24 0.33 0.33 0.25 0.25 0.81 0.40 0.37 0.01 0.04
( 0.03) ( 0.08)
9 0.06 0.16 0.38 0.36 0.27 0.52 0.26 0.63 0.38 0.26 0.32 0.46
(1.13) (1.41)
High 1.03 1.30 0.63 0.21 1.04 0.11 0.22 0.24 0.10 0.36 1.39 1.36
(3.65) (3.45)
TO 1,0 strategies
E[re ] 2.30 1.87 1.05 0.07 1.25 0.32 0.05 0.31 1.16 2.33
This table shows international portfolios from double sorts on the previous month’s return (r1,0 ) and turnover (TO 1,0 ). We use independent double
sorts to form country-specific portfolios that are value weighted and rebalanced at the end of each month. We then weight each country’s portfolio
17
by the country’s total market capitalization for the previous month to form each international portfolio. All returns and market values are in U.S.
dollars and excess returns are above the monthly U.S. Treasury-bill rate. The table also shows the raw and risk-adjusted returns to long-short strategies
within the deciles, where risk-adjustment is relative to Fama and French’s (2017) developed markets five-factor model including the momentum factor
(DMFF6). Test statistics (in parentheses) are adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. Data are at the monthly frequency and cover January
1993 to December 2018.
The Review of Financial Studies / v 00 n 0 2021
15
The long and short sides of the international largest-100-per-country STMOM strategy
trade in an average of 499 and 470 stocks. In December 2018, the top holdings from
the top-five countries on the long side were NTT DoCoMo (Japan), BMW (Germany),
China Mobile (Hong Kong), Banco Santandar (Spain), and AB InBev (Belgium), while
the top holdings from the top-five countries on the short side were Toyota (Japan),
Nestle (Switzerland), Allianz (Germany), Citic (Hong Kong), and AstraZeneca (the United
Kingdom).
18
Coexistence
Coexistenceofofreversal
reversaland
andmomentum
momentumininone-month returns:International
1-month returns: Internationalevidence
evidence
1
Sharpe Ratio (annualized)
-1
Short-term momentum
-2 Short-term reversal*
AUS PRT BEL SGP DNK DEU NZL CAN SWE NOR HKG JPN AUT GBR ESP IRL ITA CHE NLD FRA FIN GRC
Figure 3
International short-term momentum returns This figure shows the annualized
Sharpe ratios of the country-specific international short-term momentum and short-term
reversal* strategies. The underlying portfolios are from independent double sorts into
deciles based on the previous month’s return and turnover. Portfolios are value weighted
and rebalanced at the end of each month. All returns and market values are in U.S. dollars.
Data are at the monthly frequency and cover January 1993 to December 2018.
19
Table 6
Short-term momentum and end-of-month e↵ects
A B
Performance of r1,0 EOM strategies Performance of rEOM strategies
within TO 1,0 EOM deciles within TO EOM deciles
20
16
Table IA.4 in the Internet Appendix shows that the results from Table 6 also hold in
our international sample. In untabulated tests, we find very similar results when focusing
on the last 5 (instead of 3) trading days for month t 1 (the formation period) and,
furthermore, that these results are robust to also excluding the first 1–3 trading days
from the return for month t (the holding period).
21
A Sorts on day d based on prior return and turnover over days d −20 to d −3
(i.e., skipping days d , d −1, and d −2)
3
Average excess return over days d + 1 to d + 21 (%)
Short-term momentum
Short-term reversal*
2
1
0
-1
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21
B Sorts on day d based on prior return and turnover over days d , d −1, and d −2
1
Average excess return over days d + 1 to d + 21 (%)
0
-1
-2
-3
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21
Figure 4
Short-term momentum and end-of-month e↵ects This figure shows the average
excess returns to STMOM and STREV* strategies formed on di↵erent days (d) during
the month. Panel A shows strategies formed on day d based on prior return and turnover
over days d 20 to d 3, skipping the most recent 3 days (i.e., days d 2,d 1, and d).
Panel B shows strategies formed on day d based only on prior return and turnover over the
most recent 3 days (i.e., days d 2,d 1, and d). We use conditional sorts into deciles based
on NYSE breakpoints, first on returns and then on turnover. Portfolios are value weighted
and returns are calculated over days d+1 to d+21. The sample excludes financial firms.
Data are at the daily frequency and cover the end of July 1963 to the end of December
2018.
22
where the sum is taken over all stocks in the portfolio in months t 1 or t
and is divided by 2 to avoid double counting buys and sells. The product
(1+rit )wi,t 1 is the weight of stock i just before rebalancing at the end of
month t. We set wi,t 1 = 0 if stock i is not in the portfolio in month t 1,
and similarly for wit . The portfolio’s half-spread in any given month is
the value-weighted average of 12 (ASK BID)/( 12 (ASK+BID)).
Table 7 shows strategy performance net of transaction costs. The
benchmark STMOM strategy (Table 1) turns over 89% and 90% of its
long and short sides each month on average, yet these incur relatively
modest average half-spreads of 0.17% and 0.24% per month. Table A.4
in the appendix explains why: for every $1 investment, each side puts on
average just 9 cents into microcaps but around 30 cents into megacaps.
The strategy’s average monthly cost is therefore just 0.89⇥0.17+0.90⇥
0.24 = 0.37%, implying a net average return of 1.00% per month with
t = 3.47. Its FF6 net abnormal return is equally large and strong, while
its net information ratio relative to a “FF8” model (FF6 plus the two
conventional reversal factors) is 0.92. The benchmark STREV* strategy
turns over more often and incurs higher half-spreads because it puts
much more weight on microcaps (Table A.4). Its average monthly cost
of 1.94% therefore subsumes its average gross return when judged by
our conservative approach.
17
Half-spreads are simpler than the “e↵ective bid-ask spread” proposed by Hasbrouck (2009)
and used by Novy-Marx and Velikov (2015), but the resultant costs are still conservative,
especially for large institutional traders. Like e↵ective spreads, half-spreads do not account
for the price impact of large trades and should be interpreted as the costs faced by
a small liquidity demander. The resultant costs are nonetheless conservative (an upper
bound) because they assume market orders and immediate liquidity demand, instead
of limit orders, an assumption that likely overstates the actual average costs associated
with implementing a strategy. Frazzini, Israel, and Moskowitz (2015) find that the actual
trading costs faced by a large institutional trader are an order of magnitude smaller than
those estimated for the average trader because a large institutional trader will attempt to
trade within the spread, use limit orders, and supply, rather than demand, liquidity.
23
Short-term momentum 1.37 0.89 0.17 0.90 0.24 0.37 1.00 1.00 0.44 1.78 0.92
(4.74) (3.47) (3.09) (6.11)
Short-term momentum 1.83 0.89 0.18 0.91 0.24 0.38 1.45 1.42 0.61 2.18 1.11
(excl. EOM) (5.52) (4.38) (4.12) (6.95)
Short-term momentum 0.74 0.83 0.17 0.85 0.21 0.32 0.42 0.45 0.33 1.03 1.07
(5⇥5, excl. EOM) (4.21) (2.40) (2.35) (6.61)
The Review of Financial Studies / v 00 n 0 2021
Short-term momentum 0.77 0.83 0.08 0.84 0.10 0.15 0.62 0.59 0.38 1.22 1.01
(large-caps, excl. EOM) (3.90) (3.14) (2.78) (7.07)
Short-term momentum 0.72 0.84 0.07 0.85 0.08 0.13 0.59 0.59 0.34 1.24 0.90
(megacaps, excl. EOM) (3.76) (3.10) (2.66) (6.46)
This table shows strategy performance net of transaction costs. “TO” is average turnover, computed as the time-series average of one-half of the sum of
absolute monthly changes in the portfolio weights (Eq. (1)). “HS” (in % per month) is the average half-spread, computed as the time-series average of
the portfolios’ monthly value-weighted average half-spreads. “Cost” (in % per month) is the sum of the average turnover times the average half-spread
for the long and short sides. “FF8” is FF6 plus the conventional short-term and long-term reversal factors. “IR” is the information ratio, computed
18
For comparison, the conventional momentum strategy incurs an average cost of 0.26% per
month and its net return is 0.95% per month (t = 3.74). Moskowitz and Grinblatt’s (1999)
industry momentum strategy incurs an average cost of 0.34% per month and its net return
is 0.64% per month (t = 3.02). The average cost of the conventional STREV strategy is
0.56% per month, which subsumes its average gross return.
19
We employ quarterly earnings starting from the end of the month of the announcement
date (Compustat’s RDQ). CAR3 is the 3-day cumulative return minus the value-weighted
market return around earnings announcements. SUE is the year-over-year change in split-
adjusted earnings per share (EPSPXQ/AJEXQ) divided by its standard deviation over
the latest eight announcements (minimum of six) excluding the current announcement.
ROE is total quarterly earnings (IBQ) deflated by one-quarter-lagged book equity.
25
20
Table IA.5 in the Internet Appendix shows additional characteristic tilts as well as average
portfolio overlap for the five momentum strategies. An interesting observation is that,
while conventional momentum has the well-known strong tilt toward growth stocks, short-
term momentum has a slight but significant value tilt. The two strategies’ average portfolio
overlap is 34% for winners and 20% for losers.
26
Table 8
Short-term momentum and other stock-level momentum strategies
This table studies the benchmark STMOM strategy (Table 1) in the context of four
other stock-level momentum strategies: a conventional momentum strategy (MOM)
based on prior 12-2 months performance (r12,2 ), a post-earnings announcement drift
(PEAD) strategy based on cumulative 3-day abnormal return around quarterly earnings
announcements dates (CAR3 ), a PEAD strategy based on standardized unexpected
earnings (SUE), and an earnings-momentum strategy based on the quarterly return on
equity (ROE). The strategies trade value-weighted portfolios from decile sorts using
NYSE breakpoints and are rebalanced at the end of each month. Test statistics (in
parentheses) are adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. The sample excludes
financial firms, and the sorts on ROE exclude firms with negative book equity. Data are
at the monthly frequency and cover July 1963 to December 2018, but the PEAD and
ROE strategies start from January 1972 because of data availability in Compustat.
27
21
Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) argue that “[o]ne possible explanation for the
discrepancy between short-term (one-month) reversals for individual stocks and short-
term continuations for industries is that the one-month return reversal for individual
stocks is generated by microstructure e↵ects (such as bid-ask bounce and liquidity e↵ects),
which are alleviated by forming industry portfolios” (p. 1274). Our results suggest that
conditioning on high turnover is an alternative and equally e↵ective way of alleviating
microstructure e↵ects.
28
29
30
to those observed for the market but orders of magnitude lower than
those observed for conventional momentum. It also shows that while
conventional momentum exhibits negative and significant coskewness
(Harvey and Siddique 2000; Schneider, Wagner, and Zechner 2020) and
downside beta (Henriksson and Merton 1981), both are positive albeit
small and statistically insignificant for STMOM.
Panel B shows results from Daniel and Moskowitz’s regressions,
rte = (↵0 +↵B IB,t e
1 )+( 0 +( B + B,U IU,t )IB,t 1 )rmt +✏t , (2)
where rte is a strategy’s excess return, rmt e
is the market excess
return, IB,t 1 is an ex ante 24-month “bear market” indicator, and
IU,t is a contemporaneous 1-month “up-market” indicator. Here, B
captures the di↵erence in beta during bear markets, while B,U captures
the di↵erence in beta in rebounds after bear markets. Conventional
momentum has a bear-market beta of b0 + bB = 0.34 when the
contemporaneous market return is negative but b0 + bB + bB,U = 1.06
when the contemporaneous market return is positive. In contrast,
STMOM’s bear-market beta is 0.51 when the contemporaneous market
return is negative but just +0.05 when the contemporaneous market
return is positive. That is, STMOM is a better hedge in bear markets
and has no negative market exposure in rebounds.
31
22
Wang (1994) assumes long-lived private information and that liquidity-related trading is
due to hedging a nontraded asset which is correlated with the risky asset, that is, that
liquidity-related trading is “endogenous.” Inspired by Wang (1994), Llorente et al. (2002)
also assume endogenous liquidity-related trading but drop the assumption of long-lived
private information. As a result, higher volume is always associated with more reversal in
their model, but the e↵ect of volume decreases in magnitude with information asymmetry.
23
We focus on the models’ predictions for return autocorrelation conditional on high volume
because their predictions for return autocorrelation conditional on low volume are less
clear-cut and receive less attention. In Campbell, Grossman, and Wang’s (1993) model,
the sign of return autocorrelation conditional on low volume is ambiguous (equation (16),
p. 929). In Llorente et al.’s (2002) model, which simplifies that of Wang (1994), return
autocorrelation conditional on low volume is captured by ✓1 , about which they write “the
result on ✓1 can be sensitive to the simplifying assumptions of our model. For example,
when motives for hedging trade [...] are persistent, the returns can become positively
serially correlated (even in the absence of trading). In addition, when private information
is long-lived, the behavior of return autocorrelation is more involved, and the impact of
information asymmetry on ✓1 becomes more complex (see, e.g., Wang 1994)” (p. 1015–6).
32
24
Avramov et al. (2006) argue that the di↵erent roles of turnover “could arise because
demand shocks are attenuated at the monthly frequency as compared to the weekly
frequency, which would suggest that turnover may be a poor proxy for noninformational
trades at the monthly frequency.” (p. 2367). Table IA.13 in the Internet Appendix
shows that using turnover orthogonal to illiquidity does not a↵ect our main results and
that replacing turnover with illiquidity in our double sorts does not lead to significant
continuation.
33
Table 9
Short-term momentum controlling for illiquidity
A. Monthly sorts
Liquid 0.88 0.67 0.64 0.72
(3.55) (2.51) ( 3.62) ( 3.83)
2 0.38 0.32 1.02 0.97
(1.43) (1.15) ( 5.12) ( 4.42)
3 0.21 0.11 1.24 1.26
(0.85) (0.36) ( 7.05) ( 6.21)
4 0.04 0.15 1.44 1.44
( 0.16) ( 0.53) ( 7.22) ( 4.90)
Illiquid 0.77 1.11 1.67 1.90
( 2.38) ( 2.92) ( 7.32) ( 6.94)
B. Weekly sorts (rebalanced Tuesday, skipping Tuesday)
Liquid 0.18 0.19 0.34 0.32
( 3.15) ( 3.26) ( 8.37) ( 7.94)
2 0.50 0.49 0.45 0.45
( 8.26) ( 7.99) ( 11.02) ( 10.71)
3 0.55 0.54 0.41 0.40
( 9.59) ( 9.11) ( 8.68) ( 8.56)
4 0.79 0.77 0.43 0.41
( 13.64) ( 13.42) ( 9.35) ( 9.06)
Illiquid 1.00 1.00 0.37 0.36
( 14.84) ( 15.15) ( 8.15) ( 7.98)
This table shows the performance of short-term momentum and short-term reversal*
strategies constructed with a control for the Amihud (2002) illiquidity measure. Panel
A shows results for monthly sorts, while panel B shows results for weekly sorts. The
strategies are from 5⇥3⇥3 conditional sorts on illiquidity (Illiq1,0 ), returns, and
turnover, in that order, measured over the previous month or week. Illiq1,0 is the average
absolute daily return relative to the daily dollar trading volume. The breakpoints for
illiquidity are NYSE quintiles, while the breakpoints for returns and turnover are the
20th and 80th percentiles for NYSE stocks. Portfolios are value weighted. Test statistics
(in parentheses) are adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. The sample
excludes financial firms. In panel A, portfolios are rebalanced at the end of each month
and Illiq1,0 is computed using a minimum of 15 daily observations. In panel B, portfolios
are rebalanced each Tuesday, skipping signals and holding-period returns over Tuesday
itself to avoid undue influence from bid-ask bounce. That is, for the sort on Tuesday
of week t, the sorting variables are returns, turnover, and illiquidity measured from
Wednesday of week t 1 to Monday of week t, both inclusive, and the holding-period
return is computed from Wednesday of week t to Monday of week t+1, both inclusive.
For the weekly sorts, Illiq1,0 is computed using a minimum of four daily observations.
Data are at the monthly or weekly frequency and cover the beginning of July 1963 to the
end of December 2018.
34
much less among the most liquid stocks compared to the most illiquid
ones. These weekly-horizon results are consistent with the findings
of Avramov, Chordia, and Goyal (2006) but, again, directly oppose
the high-information-asymmetry mechanism. We conjecture that the
performance of the weekly STMOM strategies is due to temporary price
pressure dominating other e↵ects at the weekly horizon, but less so for
more liquid stocks.
25
Analysts’ forecast data come from the Institutional Brokers’ Estimate System (I/B/E/S),
but we use only unadjusted forecasts to mitigate the reporting inaccuracies, rounding
errors, and look-ahead-biases identified in previous studies (Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina
2002). Our tests use earnings-per-share forecasts for the month closest to, but preceding,
the month in which a firm announces its quarterly earnings (Compustat’s RDQ).
26
This literature includes Johnson (2004), Verardo (2009), Banerjee (2011), Cen, Wei, and
Yang (2017), Cujean and Hasler (2017), and Loh and Stulz (2018), among many others.
35
Table 10
Short-term momentum controlling for analysts’ forecast
36
27
Examples include Odean’s (1998) “overconfident” traders who condition on prices
but exaggerate the precision of their own signals (see also Daniel, Hirshleifer, and
Subrahmanyam 1998); Hong and Stein’s (1999) “newswatchers” that trade on their private
information but do not condition on prices (see also Hong and Stein 2007); Hirshleifer, Lim,
and Teoh’s (2011) “inattentive” traders who condition on a subset of publicly available
information, but not on prices; Banerjee’s (2011) “dismissive” traders who condition on
prices but downplay the precision of others’ signals; Eyster, Rabin, and Vayanos’ (2019)
“cursed” traders who do not fully condition on prices; and Mondria, Vives, and Yang’s
(2020) “unsophisticated” traders who condition on a noisy version of the price for inference
purposes.
37
38
Table 11
Cross-sectional regressions to predict the growth in gross profits
39
Table 12
Cross-sectional regressions to predict the growth in earnings
40
4. Conclusion
Momentum (the tendency for winners to outperform losers) and reversal
(the tendency for losers to outperform winners) coexist with almost
equal strengths at the 1-month horizon. While the previous month’s
low-turnover stocks exhibit a strong short-term reversal e↵ect ( 16.9%
per annum), the previous month’s high-turnover stocks exhibit an
almost equally strong continuation e↵ect (+16.4% per annum), which
we dub short-term momentum. This finding is not limited to the
United States but extends to 22 international developed markets. We
show that short-term momentum generates significant abnormal returns
relative to standard factors; persists for 12 months; is stronger with an
implementation lag; survives conservative estimates of transaction costs;
and is strongest among the largest, most liquid, and most extensively
covered stocks.
Short-term momentum and conventional price momentum share the
same basic philosophy: both are a bet on recent winners financed
by a bet against recent losers, and both are designed to avoid
diluting the continuation e↵ect with short-term reversal. However, while
conventional momentum does this by skipping the most recent month,
short-term momentum’s trading signal is the performance over the most
recent month, and it instead avoids reversal by conditioning on high
share turnover in the most recent month. The two are alike in terms of
profitability and persistence and are related in terms of characteristic
tilts, portfolio overlap, and time-series correlation. However, there are
also noteworthy di↵erences between them. While short-term momentum
is strongest among the largest and most extensively covered stocks,
Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000) find that “once one moves past the very
smallest capitalization stocks (where thin market making capacity does
indeed appear to be an issue) the profitability of momentum strategies
declines sharply with market capitalization” and “momentum strategies
work particularly well among stocks that have low analyst coverage” (p.
267). In addition, short-term momentum exhibits far less crash risk than
does conventional momentum and, unlike conventional momentum, does
not appear to be spanned or driven by other, well-known momentum
e↵ects, such as those in earnings, industry returns, and factor returns.
As such, an open question for future research is whether short-term
momentum and conventional momentum are the same phenomenon in
di↵erent guises or related phenomena with important di↵erences.
Theoretically, the existence of a high-turnover continuation e↵ect is
postulated by the models of Wang (1994) and Llorente et al. (2002). Still,
these models’ high-information-asymmetry mechanism is not supported
in the data as an explanation for short-term momentum. While high-
information-asymmetry stocks should be small, illiquid, and have low
41
42
Table A.1
Portfolio characteristics for double sorts on 1-month returns and turnover
r1,0 deciles
43
44
TO 1,0 deciles
Portfolio excess return
Low 1.28 1.28 0.83 0.93 0.63 1.01 0.78 0.74 0.38 0.14 1.42 1.53 1.57
( 6.11) ( 5.95) ( 6.27)
2 1.71 1.06 1.02 0.95 1.05 0.88 0.75 0.73 0.64 0.03 1.74 1.76 1.73
( 5.41) ( 4.61) ( 4.51)
3 1.36 1.27 1.27 1.02 1.16 1.00 0.59 0.75 0.36 0.47 0.89 1.05 1.15
( 2.54) ( 2.75) ( 3.04)
4 1.62 1.46 1.40 1.36 0.90 1.06 0.82 0.59 0.82 0.09 1.53 1.82 1.73
( 5.15) ( 5.88) ( 4.90)
5 1.52 1.55 1.38 1.02 1.21 0.86 0.86 0.98 0.61 0.46 1.06 1.29 1.37
( 3.22) ( 3.00) ( 3.37)
6 1.55 1.10 1.32 1.24 0.82 0.84 0.99 1.07 0.77 0.72 0.83 0.96 0.90
( 2.59) ( 2.63) ( 2.36)
7 1.13 1.01 1.17 0.95 1.04 1.21 0.92 0.98 0.80 0.49 0.64 0.77 0.67
( 3.10) ( 2.73) ( 2.39)
The Review of Financial Studies / v 00 n 0 2021
8 1.33 1.10 1.14 1.06 1.19 1.18 0.96 0.84 0.88 0.79 0.55 0.43 0.40
( 2.07) ( 1.39) ( 1.18)
9 0.94 1.10 1.17 1.24 1.14 0.95 1.05 1.26 1.00 0.69 0.25 0.31 0.23
( 0.91) ( 1.07) ( 0.56)
High 0.12 0.78 0.98 1.00 0.86 0.48 0.89 0.96 0.90 1.12 1.00 0.98 1.06
(4.02) (3.40) (3.31)
TO 1,0 strategies
E[re ] 1.16 0.50 0.15 0.08 0.23 0.53 0.10 0.23 0.52 1.26
This table shows portfolios from independent double sorts on the previous month’s return (r1,0 ) and turnover (TO 1,0 ). We use sorts into deciles based
on NYSE breakpoints. Portfolios are value weighted and rebalanced at the end of each month. The table also shows the performance of long-short
strategies across the deciles. Test statistics (in parentheses) are adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. Time-series averages of the
portfolios’ characteristics are provided in Table IA.1 in the Internet Appendix. Data are at the monthly frequency and cover July 1969 to December
2018, where the start date ensures nonempty portfolios as a result of the independent sorts.
Short-term Momentum
Table A.3
Independent quintile double sorts on 1-month returns and turnover excluding
end-of-month e↵ects
B. Portfolio characteristics
r1,0 EOM quintiles r1,0 EOM quintiles
Low 0.10 0.03 0.00 0.04 0.12 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02
2 0.09 0.03 0.00 0.04 0.11 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04
3 0.09 0.03 0.00 0.04 0.11 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06
4 0.10 0.03 0.00 0.04 0.12 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09
High 0.12 0.03 0.00 0.04 0.16 0.20 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.21
45
A B
Average fraction of each $1 investment
allocated to each NYSE size quintile (%) Investment capacity
Average December
Strategy Leg Micro 2 3 4 Mega fraction (%) 2018 ($B)
Short-term momentum Long 8.5 12.9 19.2 27.1 32.3 0.69 71.4
Short 8.8 14.4 21.3 27.1 28.4 0.57 38.7
Short-term reversal* Long 27.4 14.2 13.8 16.1 28.5 0.88 43.0
Short 39.2 13.9 12.0 13.7 21.1 0.62 12.1
Short-term momentum Long 5.7 9.1 14.1 23.1 48.1 4.25 387.4
(5⇥5, excl. EOM) Short 6.3 9.9 15.2 23.7 45.0 3.10 863.6
Short-term momentum Long 0.0 0.0 11.4 32.7 56.0 2.31 353.3
(largecaps, excl. EOM) Short 0.0 0.0 10.7 31.9 57.3 2.21 465.7
Short-term momentum Long 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 2.17 587.0
(megacaps, excl. EOM) Short 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 2.07 650.3
This table shows the investment allocation and capacity for the strategies considered in Table 7. Panel A shows, for each strategy, the time-series
A B
Decomposition of benchmark strategy performance into
an industry-hedged (“within-industry”) component and the industry hedge
Strategies from sorts on
industry-demeaned variables Benchmark strategies Industry-hedged strategies The industry hedges
Low 2.00 2.12 2.07 1.41 1.45 1.43 1.73 1.74 1.73 0.32 0.29 0.30
( 10.25) ( 8.51) ( 7.25) ( 7.13) ( 6.19) ( 5.95) ( 8.41) ( 8.26) ( 7.52) (3.68) (3.27) (3.00)
2 1.73 1.94 1.84 1.19 1.31 1.34 1.62 1.78 1.76 0.43 0.47 0.42
( 7.57) ( 6.61) ( 4.87) ( 4.61) ( 4.04) ( 4.21) ( 7.00) ( 5.93) ( 6.62) (3.74) (4.26) (3.04)
3 1.75 1.95 1.93 1.34 1.62 1.66 1.65 1.83 1.87 0.30 0.21 0.22
( 7.79) ( 6.43) ( 4.83) ( 5.02) ( 5.61) ( 4.87) ( 7.32) ( 7.37) ( 6.50) (2.57) (1.57) (1.52)
4 2.08 2.23 2.32 0.85 1.02 0.91 1.22 1.33 1.21 0.37 0.31 0.31
( 7.75) ( 8.63) ( 9.15) ( 3.63) ( 4.15) ( 2.92) ( 5.84) ( 6.08) ( 5.25) (3.21) (2.53) (2.20)
5 1.09 1.28 1.08 0.45 0.63 0.51 0.96 1.08 0.96 0.51 0.46 0.44
( 4.37) ( 4.58) ( 3.72) ( 1.94) ( 2.29) ( 1.54) ( 4.63) ( 4.71) ( 3.57) (4.50) (3.85) (3.14)
6 0.96 0.97 1.02 0.59 0.60 0.41 0.94 1.05 0.97 0.35 0.45 0.56
( 3.95) ( 3.53) ( 3.27) ( 2.50) ( 2.35) ( 1.20) ( 4.88) ( 4.52) ( 3.56) (2.74) (3.35) (3.08)
7 0.89 0.91 0.92 0.67 0.85 0.96 0.94 1.09 1.19 0.27 0.23 0.23
( 3.32) ( 2.85) ( 2.61) ( 2.52) ( 2.55) ( 2.37) ( 4.13) ( 3.77) ( 3.85) (2.31) (1.56) (1.36)
8 0.33 0.44 0.42 0.23 0.13 0.21 0.19 0.22 0.19 0.42 0.35 0.40
( 1.24) ( 1.75) ( 1.38) (0.85) (0.47) (0.60) ( 0.81) ( 1.00) ( 0.69) (4.01) (2.96) (2.98)
9 0.04 0.21 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.19 0.12 0.25 0.12 0.17 0.26 0.31
( 0.17) ( 0.67) ( 0.29) (0.21) (0.01) (0.55) ( 0.58) ( 0.98) ( 0.43) (1.56) (2.31) (2.17)
47
(“within-industry”) component and the industry hedge. The industry-hedged strategies are from sorts on unadjusted variables, but each stock’s
position is combined with an o↵setting position of equal size in the corresponding value-weighted industry portfolio. The industry hedges are these
o↵setting positions in the value-weighted industry portfolios. The industries are the Fama and French 49 industries. Test statistics (in parentheses) are
adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. The sample excludes financial firms. Data are at the monthly frequency and cover January 1963 to
December 2018.
Table A.6
Short-term momentum and crash risk
48
Skew 0.55 0.48 5.74
( 7.08) ( 6.24) ( 29.72)
Kurtosis 9.87 7.55 74.05
(12.73) (10.94) (20.65)
Co-skewness 0.47 1.87
(1.60) ( 8.05)
Down-side 0.07 0.71
(0.52) ( 6.35)
B. Regression results
Intercepts, slopes, and test-statistics (in parentheses)
from time-series regressions of strategy returns
References
Amihud, Y. 2002. Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series e↵ects.
Journal of Financial Markets 5:31–56.
Asness, C. S. 1995. The Power of past stock returns to explain future stock returns.
Working Paper, AQR Capital Management.
Asness, C. S., A. Frazzini, and L. H. Pedersen. 2019. Quality minus junk. Review of
Accounting Studies 24:34–112.
Asness, C. S., R. B. Porter, and R. Stevens. 2000. Predicting stock returns using industry-
relative firm characteristics. Working Paper, AQR Capital Management.
Avramov, D., T. Chordia, and A. Goyal. 2006. Liquidity and autocorrelations in individual
stock returns. Journal of Finance 61:2365–94.
Ball, R., J. Gerakos, J. T. Linnainmaa, and V. V. Nikolaev. 2016. Accruals, cash flows,
and operating profitability in the cross section of stock returns. Journal of Financial
Economics 121:28–45.
Bandarchuk, P., and J. Hilscher. 2013. Sources of momentum profits: Evidence on the
irrelevance of characteristics. Review of Finance 1:809–45.
Banerjee, S. 2011. Learning from prices and the dispersion in beliefs. Review of Financial
Studies 24:3025–68.
Bollerslev, T., B. Hood, J. Huss, and L. H. Pedersen. 2018. Risk everywhere: Modeling
and managing volatility. Review of Financial Studies 31:2729–73.
Campbell, J. Y., S. J. Grossman, and J. Wang. 1993. Trading volume and serial correlation
in stock returns. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108:905–39.
Cen, L., K. C. J. Wei, and L. Yang. 2017. Disagreement, underreaction, and stock returns.
Management Science 63:1214–31.
Cespa, G., A. Gargano, S. J. Riddiough, and L. Sarno. 2020. Foreign exchange volume.
Working Paper, Cass Business School.
Conrad, J. S., A. Hameed, and C. Niden. 1994. Volume and autocovariances in short-
horizon individual security returns. Journal of Finance 49:1305–29.
Cooper, M. 1999. Filter rules based on price and volume in individual security
overreaction. Review of Financial Studies 12:901–35.
Cujean, J., and M. Hasler. 2017. Why does return predictability concentrate in bad times?
Journal of Finance 72:2717–58.
Da, Z., Q. Liu, and E. Schaumburg. 2012. A closer look at the short-term return reversal.
Management Science 60:658–74.
Daniel, K., and D. Hirshleifer. 2015. Overconfident investors, predictable returns, and
excessive trading. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29:61–88.
Daniel, K., D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam. 1998. Investor psychology and security
market under- and overreactions. Journal of Finance 53:1839–85.
De Bondt, W., and R. Thaler. 1985. Does the stock market overreact? Journal of
Finance 40:793–805.
Diether, K. B., C. J. Malloy, and A. Scherbina. 2002. Di↵erences of opinion and the cross
section of stock returns. Journal of Finance 57:2113–41.
49
Drechsler, I., A. Moreira, and A. Savov. 2018. Liquidity creation as volatility risk.
Working Paper, Wharton School.
Ehsani, S., and J. Linnainmaa. 2020. Factor momentum and the momentum factor.
Working Paper, Northern Illinois University.
Etula, E., K. Rinne, M. Suominen, and L. Vaittinen. 2020. Dash for cash: Monthly market
impact of institutional liquidity needs. Review of Financial Studies 33:76–111.
Eyster, E., M. Rabin, and D. Vayanos. 2019. Financial markets where traders neglect the
informational content of prices. Journal of Finance 71:371–99.
———. 1998. Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance. Journal of
Financial Economics 49:283–306.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal
of Finance 47:427–465.
———. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of
Financial Economics 33:3–56.
———. 2015. A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial Economics 1:1–22.
———. 2017. International tests of a five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial
Economics 123:441–63.
Fama, E. F. and J. D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests.
Journal of Political Economy 81:607–36.
Frazzini, A., R. Israel, and T. J. Moskowitz. 2015. Trading costs of asset pricing anomalies.
Working Paper, AQR Capital Management.
Gao, X., and J. Ritter. 2010. The marketing of seasoned equity o↵erings. Journal of
Financial Economics 97:33–52.
Gervais, S., R. Kaniel, and D. H. Mingelgrin. 2001. The high-volume return premium.
Journal of Finance 56:877–919.
Goyal, A., and N. Jegadeesh. 2018. Cross-sectional and time-series tests of return
predictability: What is the di↵erence? Review of Financial Studies 31:1785–824.
Harvey, C. R., and A. Siddique. 2000. Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests. Journal
of Finance 55:1263–96.
Hasbrouck, J. 2009. Trading costs and returns for U.S. equities: Estimating e↵ective costs
from daily data. Journal of Finance 64:1445–77.
50
Hirshleifer, D. A., S. S. Lim, and S. H. Teoh. 2011. Limited investor attention and stock
market misreactions to accounting information. Review of Asset Pricing Studies 1:35–73.
Hong, H., T. Lim, and J. C. Stein. 2000. Bad news travels slowly: Size, analyst coverage,
and the profitability of momentum strategies. Journal of Finance 55:265-295.
Hong, H., and J. C. Stein. 1999. A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading,
and overreaction in asset markets. Journal of Finance 54:2143–84.
———. 2007. Disagreement and the stock market. Journal of Economic Perspec-
tives 21:109–28.
Hou, K., C. Xue, and L. Zhang. 2015. Digesting anomalies: An investment approach.
Review of Financial Studies 28:650–705.
Huang, D., J. Li, L. Wang, and G. Zhou. 2020. Time-series momentum: Is it there?
Journal of Financial Economics 135:774–94.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman. 1993. Returns to buying winners and selling losers:
Implications for stock market efficiency. Journal of Finance 48:65–91.
Johnson, T. C. 2004. Forecast dispersion and the cross section of expected returns.
Journal of Finance 59:1957–78.
Lee, C. M. C., and B. Swaminathan. 2000. Price momentum and trading volume. Journal
of Finance 55:2017–69.
Llorente, G., R. Michaely, G. Saar, and J. Wang. 2002. Dynamic volume-return relation
of individual stocks. Review of Financial Studies 15:1005–47.
Lo, A. W., and J. Wang. 2000. Trading Volume: Definitions, Data Analysis, and
Implications of Portfolio Theory. Review of Financial Studies 13:257–300.
Loh, R. K., and R. M. Stulz. 2018. Is sell-side research more valuable in bad times?
Journal of Finance 73:959–1013.
Medhat, M., and M. Schmeling. 2018. Dissecting announcement returns. Working Paper.
Mondria, J., X. Vives, and L. Yang. 2020. Costly interpretation of asset prices. Working
Paper, University of Navarra.
51
Novy-Marx, R. 2013. The other side of value: The gross profitability premium. Journal
of Financial Economics 108:1–28.
Novy-Marx, R., and M. Velikov. 2015. A taxonomy of anomalies and their trading costs.
Review of Financial Studies 29:104–47.
Odean, T. 1998. Volume, volatility, price, and profit when all traders are above average.
Journal of Finance 53:1887–934.
Pástor, L., and R. F. Stambaugh. 2003. Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. Journal
of Political Economy 111:642–85.
52
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 1 — #1
Short-term Momentum
— Internet Appendix
Mamdouh Medhat
Cass Business School, City, University of London
Maik Schmeling
Goethe University Frankfurt and Centre for Economic Policy Research
(CEPR)
doi:10.1093/rfs/Sample
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 2 — #2
Table IA.1
Portfolio characteristics for independent double sorts on the previous month’s
return and turnover
r1,0 deciles
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 3 — #3
Internet Appendix
Table IA.2
Short-term momentum and size: Robustness checks
A B
Performance of r1,0 strategies Performance of r1,0 strategies
within TO 1,0 ? M deciles within size deciles
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 4 — #4
Short-term momentum
-5
-10
1 6 12 18 24 30 36
B
500
Short-term momentum
Short-term reversal*
Short-term reversal
Cumulative excess return (%)
-500
-1000
Figure IA.1
International short-term momentum returns: Persistence and historical
performance Panel A shows the average cumulative sums of post-formation excess
returns to each of the international short-term momentum (STMOM) and international
short-term reversal* (STREV*) strategies along with 95% confidence bands. Panel B shows
a time-series plot of cumulative sums of excess returns to the international STMOM and
STREV* strategies as well as a conventional short-term reversal strategy. Data are at the
monthly frequency and cover January 1993 to December 2018.
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 5 — #5
Internet Appendix
Table IA.3
Short-term momentum controlling for size: International evidence
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 6 — #6
Table IA.4
Short-term momentum and end-of-month e↵ects: International evidence
A B
Performance of r1,0 EOM strategies Performance of rEOM strategies
within TO 1,0 EOM deciles within TO EOM deciles
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 7 — #7
Internet Appendix
Table IA.5
Short-term momentum and other stock-level momentum strategies: Additional
results
A: Characteristic tilts
Time-series average of long-short di↵erence in monthly
portfolio characteristics and equal-weighted market capitalization
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 8 — #8
Table IA.6
Short-term momentum excluding earnings announcements
A B
This table shows the performance of long-short strategies that buy the previous month’s
winners and sell the previous month’s losers among stocks with di↵erent share turnover in
the previous month. In panel A, the sorts exclude earnings announcers, i.e., excluding
firms whose most recent earnings announcement date (Compustat’s RDQ) fell in the
previous month. In panel B, the sorting variables exclude their values for the three
days around earnings announcement dates (r[1,0]\EAD and TO [1,0]\EAD ). Portfolios are
from conditional sorts into deciles based on NYSE breakpoints, first on returns and then
on turnover, and are value weighted and rebalanced at the end of each month. Test-
statistics (in parentheses) are adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. The
sample excludes financial firms. Data are at the monthly frequency and cover January
1972 to December 2018, where the start date is determined by the availability of data on
quarterly earnings announcement dates in Compustat.
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 9 — #9
Internet Appendix
Table IA.7
Short-term momentum and industry momentum
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 10 — #10
Table IA.8
Short-term momentum and factor momentum
10
i i
i
i
Table IA.9
Short-term momentum and longer formation periods
Independent (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
variable
Intercept 0.99 0.02 1.00 0.15 1.06 0.38 1.24 0.64 1.19 0.62
(2.95) (0.08) (3.11) (0.57) (3.16) (1.36) (3.78) (1.93) (3.25) (1.80)
STMOM 0.71 0.62 0.50 0.45 0.42
(15.12) (13.70) (13.38) (9.50) (7.35)
Adj. R2 46.5% 34.0% 21.5% 17.3% 14.9%
Intercept 1.07 0.13 0.88 0.02 0.49 0.33 0.48 0.27 0.49 0.24
( 4.70) ( 0.60) ( 3.78) ( 0.07) ( 2.05) (1.46) ( 1.87) (1.10) ( 1.84) (0.94)
STREV* 0.67 0.61 0.58 0.53 0.51
(12.74) (11.21) (10.02) (9.20) (6.86)
Adj. R2 36.1% 28.4% 23.9% 18.9% 16.1%
This table shows time-series regression results for alternative short-term momentum and short-term reversal* strategies constructed using longer
heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. The sample excludes financial firms. Data are at the monthly frequency and cover January 1963 to December
2018.
11
i
i
i
i
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 12 — #12
Table IA.10
Short-term momentum and volatility: Robustness checks
A B
12
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 13 — #13
Internet Appendix
Table IA.11
Short-term momentum in the pre-1963 era and across sample splits
13
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 14 — #14
Table IA.12
Short-term momentum and volatility risk
14
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 15 — #15
Internet Appendix
Table IA.13
Short-term momentum and illiquidity: Robustness checks
A B
Performance of r1,0 strategies Performance of r1,0 strategies
within TO 1,0 ? Illiq1,0 deciles within Illiq1,0 deciles
15
i i
i i
“STMOM-InternetAppendix” — 2021/4/26 — 21:54 — page 16 — #16
References
Asness, C. S., A. Frazzini, and L. H. Pedersen. 2019. Quality minus junk. Review of
Accounting Studies 24:34–112.
Ehsani, S., and J. Linnainmaa. 2020. Factor momentum and the momentum factor.
Working Paper, Northern Illinois University.
Pástor, L. and R. F. Stambaugh (2003). Liquidity risk and expected stock returns.
Journal of Political Economy 111 (3), 642–685.
16
i i