MM Model
MM Model
Firms finance themselves through retained earnings (internal financing) and selling securities in the market (external financing) Internal financing (retained earnings) biggest source of financing for firms
Firms in countries with less developed financial markets use particularly little external financing
3. The external financing is done by issues of debt, equity and hybrid securities (such as convertible debt and preferred equity)
Private sources: Private equity, bank debt, private placements of bonds and equity Public sources: IPOs, Seasoned equity issues; public bond issues
Equity issues increase when stock market returns have been high for some period of time Debt/borrowing issues less cyclical
Equipment
Retailers Chemicals Computer Software Average over all industries
19.1
21.7 17.3 3.5 21.5%
until debt paid off Equity gets whatever is left after debt has been paid Equity holders control firm as long as not bankrupt Debt holders control firm when firm is bankrupt
D(V)
V Face of debt
One way to thing about it: what role does capital structure have in a neoclassical fully competitive model with frictionless markets Answer: None!
Like the CAPM
Why is MM so important?
We dont believe it, literally
Since markets are not perfect, frictionless, and fully competitive
Strength of theorem is that by showing when capital structure is irrelevant, it also implies when it is relevant.
But we cant have too much debt, because then we go bankrupt Optimal capital structure
V = E(FCF)/(1+R) Capital structure is just one way of splitting cash flows between different investors, but the total value of the firm remains the same Although the required returns of debtholders and equityholders may differ, the weighted average cost of capital to the firm will always equal R
Miller and Modigliani claim that VA = VB, otherwise there would be an arbitrage opportunity
Instead suppose you buy all of As equity, but borrow on own account D of the purchase pries.
- So cost to you is EA D. - You get CF D(1+RD) = companys whole cash flow less personal interest you owe.
Since strategies yield same net cash flow to you, must cost the same to assemble: EB = EA D, of VB = VA.
- Otherwise there would be an arbitrage opportunity.
D E ra rD rE DE DE
rE
rA rD
Debt/Equity
There are 3 conditions for this to be true. The first two are: Financial markets are competitive.
Financial markets are complete:
II.
Investors can choose any consumption pattern by borrowing, lending, and hedging.
If not, the firm may be able to make money by offering a cash flow stream with attractive risk characteristics to certain clientele.
Making profits from pure financial engineering is better left to the investment banks than regular corporations!
But there is a third condition as well: 3. Prices reflect all existing information (strong form efficiency)
- BUT: if the manager has private information about prospects of the firm, MM does not hold! Could potentially issue misvalued securities and make money!
1. 2. 3.
4.
As we will see, all of these assumptions may not always hold in real world.
No taxes (or no asymmetric tax treatments) There are no extra costs of financial distress. There are no transaction costs from issuing securities (or the same costs for debt and equity) Managers and employees always work to maximize the value of the firm
Indeed, the proof applies to all financial transactions because they are all zero NPV transactions.
(dividends) (net proceeds from new financing) = (cash flow from operations) (new investment) In other words: think about the choice of whether to pay a dividend or not.
If we increase our dividend we can always issue new equity (or debt) to offset this shortfall If we decrease our dividend we can always repurchase some shares (or pay down some debt) to offset.
We know that value is given by discounting the right hand side Free Cash Flows
LHS does not matter for value, if RHS given
As long as excess cash retained earns a market return, net payments to financial markets do not matter.
$ 100 of excess cash today is worth $ 100 regardless of whether pay out now or later. Although the return on the firms assets may go down if you keep cash on your balance sheet, required return also goes down since firm cash flows become less risky
under MM, as long as retained cash flow earns a fair market return and is paid out at some future point.
Essentially the payout policy argument is the same as the debt irrelevance argument. Important principle: Deciding how much debt to take on and deciding how much cash to pay out is essentially the same decision Cash = Negative debt!
This is why we should consider Net Debt = Debt Excess Cash when we evaluate capital structure and unlever betas.
Bottom line
Using the MM theorem, we can understand what does (and
doesnt) matter for financial policy. To understand capital structure and payout policy in the real world we will now see what happens when we relax some of the MM assumptions: What if there are corporate and personal taxes? Costs of financial distress? Conflicts of interest among managers, equity holders, and debt holders? Managers are better informed than investors?
2. Now: How does the M world differ from the real world?
1. 2. 3. Almost true
Financial markets are competitive. Markets are strong form efficient. Markets are complete.
Not true 4. 5. 6. 7.
No differential tax treatment. No costs of financial distress. No issuance costs. Managers and employees do not have an incentive to deviate from +NPV rule.
The financial policy does not change the free cash flow from real investment policy.
The debt is risk-free debt holders require 10% $ 50M coupon What is the value of the equity? Each period equity holders get the Net Income of the firm: (1-0.40)*(10050) = 30 Value of equity = 30 / 0.10 = 300
Since the value of debt is $ 500, firm value is V = E + D = $ 500 + $ 300 = $ 800 The firm value has increased by $ 200!
Another way to think about this:
VL = VU + PVTS
VL = value of the levered firm VU = value of the unlevered firm PVTS = PV of the Interest Tax Shield
Each period the firm saves TC*I in taxes where TC is the corporate tax rate and I is the interest payment
I.e. yearly tax savings are 40%*$50 = $20M
Hence, the Present Value of the Tax Shield is PVTS - $ 20 / 0.10 = $ 200M.
D is constant (ta shield is a perpetuity) Taz shield and debt payments have same systematic risk can discount the tax shield at RD What is the optimal level of debt for this company?
(1) The firm raises $500 in debt. Firm now consist of the PV of future firm cash flows plus $500 in cash The value of firm is Cash + VU + PVTS= $500 + 600 + 200 = $1300
The value of equity is E = $1300 - $500 = $800 Share price increased from $0.60 to $0.80
equity gets the whole $200 gain of the new debt tax shield!
PV = CF/r = $6/0.1 = $60 Keeping $100 of excess cash in the firm, rather than paying it out, reduces value of cash to $60! if we keep excess cash of C in the firm rather than paying it out, this cash is only worth (1- TC)*C I.e. cash has a negative tax shield of TC*C!
Here (and in general) keeping excess cash in firm is like having negative debt!
Seems extreme:
Either CFOs are missing something, or something must be missing from our analysis.
- Average debt ratio has been around 35% in lastD/E decades. - Many firms (Microsoft, Intel) hoard large amount of cash.
In addition, most firms effectively pay less than the statutory rate in corporate taxes
Will not make profits every year Net operating losses (NOLs) can be carried back and forward to offset profits in other years. Some firms have large non-debt tax shields, such as depreciation, investment tax credits, etc.
John Graham (Journal. of Fin. -00) estimated the U.S. effective corporate tax rate at about 30%
Bottom line: the effect of personal taxes and NOLs on the value of the interest tax shield is complex. Depends on
% of firms securities held by institutions and individuals whether investors adjust portfolios in a tax-efficient way the volatility of the firms profits, NOLs, and tax shelters
Still, clear that even after accounting for personal taxes and effective corporate tax rate, a substantial debt tax shield remains in the U.S.
Back-of-the envelope calculations of T in the U.S. typically come in around 10-20% Will vary from company to company, however
As low as 2% vs. as high as 35%
We have used rd which is true if the risk of the tax shield is the same as the risk of the debt. In many instances, e.g. highly levered firms, the tax shield is likely to be riskier than the debt makes sense to use a higher discount rate, closer to rA
To summarize
If the only MM assumption we relax is taxes, we get the following
Firm should finance themselves with 100% debt All excess cash should be paid out to shareholders
MM and bankruptcy
Note: the possibility that a firm defaults on its debt obligations does not in itself violate MM as long as this does not impose any additional costs on the business! In the MM world, when the value of equity falls to zero, debt holders take over the firm. There should be no costs to bankruptcy no reduction in cash flows generated by the company.
What are the costs of financial distress and how big are they?
Most obvious: Direct costs of bankruptcy
Legal expenses, court costs, advisory fees Example: K-Mart spent more than $ 100 million on lawyers, accountants, investment bankers, and other advisors wile in bankruptcy.
And that would be incurred even if the distressed firm is able to avoid outright bankruptcy or default!
A simple example
Firm has assets in place which will pay off next period:
Boom: Worth 100 with Probability = 0.5 Bust: Worth 20 with Probability = 0.5
Assume everyone risk neutral, discount rates are zero, and there are no taxes
This is not important, but makes things simple The value of the firm is then simply expected cash flows next period
Assume this firm has debt outstanding with a face value F = 50 What is the value of equity and debt? The payoffs for debt and equity: So in the boom, the debt will be paid off in full, in the bust the firm will default
Boom: D = F = 50, E = 50 Bust: D = V = 20, E = 0 So today: D = 35, E = 25 Debt = min(V,F), Equity = max(V-F,0)
Assume firm has no liquid assets and needs to raise cash to invest Will equity-holders put in the money to invest?
If invests: V = 75
The firm increases in value by 15, which is more than the 10 the equity holders put in good thing!
Today:
D = 42.5, increased by 7,5 E = 32,5, increased by 7,5
Intuition:
Wealth transfer to debt holders!
Problem arises because debt is risky
Debt is senior and will get part of surplus junior claimants will not contribute capital Risk-less debt no wealth transfer, since debt is already as safe as it can be E.g. if F=20 D=20, regardless of investment
I.e. the debt overhang the problem arises when there is a significant probability that the debt will not be paid off = firm is in financial distress!
Then we could issue risk-free debt with a face value of 10 to finance the investment. Boom: Cash flows of 115. New D = 10, Old D = 50, E = 55 Bust: Cash flows of 35. New D= 10, Old D = 25, E = 0
In the real world, debt typically has covenants preventing issues of new debt of the same (pari passu) or higher seniority Although one would think that the existing creditors would be willing to renegotiate these terms since the investment makes everyone better off, this may be hard and take time
Why do you think this is? We will get back to this question.
the Debtor in possession (DIP) financing rule in U.S. chapter 11 bankruptcy is meant to alleviate the debt overhang problem
Allows a bankrupt firm to issue new senior debt.
So we understand why firms have a hard time getting new funds in financial distress. What are the costs when this happens? Having to cut profitable new investment
Lots of evidence that financially distressed firms cut capital expenditures and R&D while in distress
Harder to say how much value was permanently lost as a result. Or maybe this could even be a good thing in some cases?
E.g. GM and Ford?
As in the example above This is probably the most common and obvious problem firms experience in distress.
Firms with high-skilled labor that is hard to retrain Firms with long-term supplier relationships Firms with durable goods
Some assets, like R&D and intangibles, that may be so specific that not possible to sell them Can explain why tech firms (semiconductor, software, biotech) have extremely low leverage
Especially problematic when have to sell assets fast, and other industry firms are also facing problems
Other industry firms are also constrained and cannot pay as much Have to sell to a nonindustry, financial buyer As a result, cyclical industries face higher firesale costs for this reason (airlines, cars)
E.g. airlines sell aircraft at a 15% discount when the average airline is in financial distress
Often used as an argument to have a bankruptcy code that allows firms to reorganize rather than liquidate assets (such as the U.S. Chapter 11 code)
Bankruptcy liquidations experience fire-sale discounts of 30-50%
An option analogy
Equitys claim: a call option with a strike price equal to the face value of debt, F.
Equity gets man(V-F,0) Equity gets the upside, but does not bear the full downside Debt gets F-max(F-V,0)=min(V,F)
Firm
Equity Debt
Face Value
Consequences
1. Equity holders prefer riskier projects, even when they may have negative NPV:
2. Equity holders are reluctant to contribute capital to safe projects, even when they have positive NPV: Underinvestment / 3. Anything that increases risk of debt without destroying value decreases value of debt and increases value of equity
Debt overhang
Costs 10 as before, but pays off 18 in good state, 0 in bad state Negative NPV = 9-10 = -1 should not invest!
Risk-shifting problem: shareholders like risky projects where they get upside, and debt holders pay on the downside.
What if firm did not have any cash lying around, but that there was no covenant preventing the firm from issuing senior debt. Equity holders decide to issue 10 in senior debt to invest in project. New debt has face value of 10.
Boom: V = 100 + 118 = 108, new D = 10, old D = 50, E = 58 Bust: V = 20, new D = 10, old D = 10, E = 0 Same thing happens:
New D = 10. They get their money back. Old D = 30, decrease by 5; E = 29, increase by 4
This is also a reason why the U.S. Chapter 11 code has been criticized:
Although such covenants make the debt overhang problem worse, it curbs the riskshifting problem
Allows equity to continue the firm for too long in bankruptcy, in the hope that firm is luck and equity gets in the money Famous example of this: Eastern Airlines bankruptcy.
Spin-offs of safer part of business (Marriott) Play for time: Postpone efficient liquidation in hope of a miracle (Eastern Airlines). Making excessive dividends or share repurchases Using cash or senior debt to take over a (risky) firm.
In 1988, RJR Nabisco announced intention to acquire company in a leveraged buyout with new debt. KB Toys and Bain Capital article
How can creditors know whether funds will be used for a good project? What if the firm is really risk-shifting? In addition, creditors are often dispersed and face conflicts of interest among themselves
Andrade & Kaplan (Journal of Fin. 1997) look at a sample of financially distressed firms
That had previously undergone leveraged buyouts (LBOs) and recapitalizations, But operations were still generating positive cash flows
Probably best estimates we have. So if these firms expected a 10% chance of going into distress, say: E(COFD) = 10%*20%=2% Seems low, still, relative to tax benefits. Which kind of firms are likely to undergo highly leveraged transactions, such as LBOs?
Probability of distress increases with leverage and decreases with excess cash. PV (costs of distress) increases with leverage and decreases with excess cash.
Practical Implications
Companies with low expected distress costs and high tax benefits should load up on debt to get tax benefits.