Wal-Mart Welfare?: Business Power and The Politics of Work Support in The American States
Wal-Mart Welfare?: Business Power and The Politics of Work Support in The American States
:
Business Power and the Politics of Work Support in the American States
Nicole D. Kazee
Yale University
Contact: [email protected]
January 2007
Abstract
2
Since the 1970s, American social policy has undergone a
The two policy areas that perhaps best represent this shift are
public health care (including Medicaid and the State Children’s Health
Insurance Program, or SCHIP) and the federal and state earned income
tax credits (EITCs). These programs, combined with both federal and
state minimum wage laws, constitute the bulk of support for low-
among the public and elites that work support programs are an ideal
3
amount and kind of work support available for low-income workers.
Twenty states have consistently high or low work support (in some
cases very high or very low), while the other thirty states offer
raise prices. I call this new system of public benefits for low-wage
employees “Wal-Mart Welfare” for its implications for both workers and
their employers. However, not all businesses are affected equally, and
not all policies have the same effects, creating multiple sources of
4
Through cross-sectional regression analysis, I find that there is a
politics of work support, though not in the sense that a uniform set of
factors affects all work support policies in the same way. State wealth
is the only factor shared by all five policies, regardless of whether the
policy requires state spending. Race – that is, the percent of the state
not the most effective form of political power in this policy domain, and
working parents can access public health care. In some cases, this is
5
for employers outweigh the costs, the business community does not
seem to be shaping the policy process in a way that best serves its
accordingly.
varying in how they are financed, which families they benefit, and how
they are perceived. But they share two important characteristics: they
in Medicaid, the public health care program for the poor. Due to a
for the very poor and employer provision for the middle and upper
6
families. To address this, the federal government made gradual
An even more crucial federal policy change that has affected the
with a parent who worked . States had the ability to design their own
insurance gap .
In both Medicaid and SCHIP, the new state autonomy has led to
health care. This is partly because state health policy decisions often
families constitute only one needy group, and compete with other
7
unemployed single mothers. And because federal benefit standards
are extremely low, states can choose how to allocate their resources;
states will expand health programs to give access to workers and their
families.
The earned income tax credit (EITC) differs from public health
benefit), it is funded through the tax code (which tends to hide costs),
and federal and state programs are separate (states can choose to
enact their own EITCs, and fund them entirely themselves). The
federal credit, which had modest beginnings with its quiet enactment
The EITC is basically a wage subsidy, paid for by taxpayers, which adds
increased the marginal return to work for very low income families .1
1
The effect is strongest on the labor force participation rates of single mothers, who
are most likely to find jobs in the low-wage service industry .
8
Because of its popularity and its bipartisan support, states began
to follow the federal model, starting with Rhode Island in 1986. Like so
Today, twenty states and the District of Columbia have their own
earned income credits, all of which are linked to the federal credit but
Despite the fact that minimum wages are not generally thought
nothing when minimum wages are enacted; the costs are borne by
1912 and followed by 14 other states over the next decade. (A federal
wage floor wasn’t enacted until after the Great Depression in 1938.)
eventually holding its lowest real value in over fifty years. Over the
9
course of those ten years, inflation increased 26 percent, dramatically
wages above the federal level as of January 2007 (before the most
highest. Minimum wage increases are highly salient among the public
wages. How are they different from the politics of tax credits and
toward greater support for workers will affect the politics behind
minimum wage, but now have a material interest in the other choices
states are making. The question is what role do businesses and their
10
political organizations play in state antipoverty choices – does their
will be chosen?
and does have the potential to influence the political process when it
issue at hand.
11
This semi-consistent conservative ideology has been beneficial, as
business gets much of its power and access from its alliance with the
As long as they are involved in the political process and have the
additional funds, work support policies are often packaged with other
Medicaid and SCHIP expansions are expensive, and bills will often be
combined with tax breaks or other benefits for small business owners
12
costs. Regardless of how vehemently local business groups have
employers to back away. Given that employers are often the primary
effect, or read the signals sent by the business community, and make
state level, where differing economic and tax policies make the threat
13
of capital flight sufficiently credible to constrain the policy choices
available to politicians.
systemic features that allow other groups – and voters – to have voice .
business has had the capacity to shape outcomes in the past, although
insurance, since these are the policies with which employers have
has little to say about business and antipoverty policy. In fact, these
studies have tended to rehash the same variables in study after study,
14
groups at all. The only known study to empirically test the effect of
policies, the final task is to establish that work support programs are
indeed relevant for employers today. The policy with the clearest
effect on business – and the policy with which business has historically
largely opposed the minimum wage ,2 believing that they will have to
options: raise prices, reduce work hours for current employees, or hire
contracts .
that they are funded with taxes, which can be seen as a cost (though
15
potentially reduce labor costs. First, access to Medicaid and earned
income credits has been shown to reduce worker demand for increased
3
The question that arises is whether employers’ labor costs will decrease if they
reduce spending on benefits, or whether these costs will be shifted to wages.
Business is likely to reap at least short-term gains because an individual employee
who opts out of employer-based insurance will not see a corresponding increase in
wages. That is, total compensation for the employee will decrease. In the long term,
however, most economic models assume that market forces are likely to bring total
compensation back to equilibrium levels, with no change in labor costs regardless of
the distribution between wages and benefits. These economic assumptions are not
universally accepted , and most importantly do not resonate with business managers,
who believe quite strongly that their labor costs will decrease if they spend less on
health care .
16
The fact that these programs can potentially lower employer
labor costs becomes even more important when we consider that they
are often alternatives for policies that have similar effects on workers
but raise labor costs for employers. For example, the EITC is often
This paper does not claim that business will dominate the
the factors that affect state policy decisions will vary depending on a
incomes have a greater tax base from which to finance programs.4 For
4
It is conceivable that the condition of state budgets would be more likely to affect
Medicaid, SCHIP, and the EITC, given that states would be more likely to expand
programs in times of surplus regardless of median income. However, this would be
17
example, more prosperous states have been found to have higher
welfare benefits and public health coverage for workers .5 But state
wealth will also likely affect the minimum wage, which requires no
workers earning very low wages, which means there will be less
opposition to an increase.
factors will come into play during policy battles. The four policies in
benefit the poor and near poor. However, even within this category of
policies there are three key distinctions that affect policy choices:
that this is an ideal way to provide incentives for the poor to get and
retain jobs. In this situation, the only factor that should matter is
18
whether the state can afford it. A policy that almost everyone supports
will not face opposition from either party (unless the size is extreme),
that the only factor to shape state EITC decisions will be state wealth.
earnings of or providing health care for the poor and their families.
Other factors then come into play. First is whether the policy is salient
Organized labor has also been shown to positively affect general state
spending , but there has been little evidence that they have had any
unions has been waning for some time, which reduces the likelihood
19
Policies that are salient to the public and parties will be less open
issues with low public salience will be more open to interest group
less restrictive .
not just legislative party control) will affect minimum wages directly,
6
Ideology among the electorate has also been shown to affect policy choices, both in
general and with respect to welfare policies , but with the exception of the minimum
wage (when it is passed by referendum) the effect is indirect. That is, policy reflects
the preferences of the public because electorates choose representatives that mirror
their own ideological preferences.
20
given that in many states increases can be enacted through referenda.
SCHIP has historically been less ideological than these two policies
(and was highly bipartisan at its inception), but debates over eligibility
been closely tied with race; many people believe that welfare
welfare will have similar racial effects. Medicaid is the most likely to
the program, and it is expected that race will still negatively affect the
hypotheses:
21
• EITC – The policy is theoretically uncontroversial, so only state
salience.
22
The dependent variables measure the extent to which workers
benefit from each policy. For Medicaid and SCHIP, eligibility thresholds
the federal poverty level (FPL) under which household income must fall
their own programs in the late 1990s following the federal allocation of
funds. The recommended level was 200 percent of the federal poverty
level, but in 2005, 15 states had thresholds higher than 200 percent,
which is based on whether the state has an EITC. If so, a state receives
have tax liabilities due to low earnings to claim the credit) and level of
7
2005 eligibility limits ranged from 18 percent of the poverty level (Alabama) to 275
percent (Minnesota). The average threshold was 86 percent.
8
The average SCHIP threshold was around 226 percent, ranging from 140 (North
Dakota) to 400 percent (Massachusetts).
23
This scale ranges from 0 to 5, with 0 indicating no state credit and 5
states had federal minimums above the federal level, while 15 states
Only one state, Kansas, had a state minimum wage below the federal.
was computed that takes into account both houses of the legislature
9
The mean score is 1.42. Eight states have no income tax and were assigned the
mean value. Results did not change when these states were dropped from the
analysis.
10
This coding decision is supported by state legislative data (collected by author)
showing that many of these states have rejected bills that would set the state
minimum wage to that of the federal level. In these states, workers not covered by
the federal minimum are not subject to a wage floor. Thus, there is a substantive
difference between these states and those that have enacted state minimum wages
equal to the federal level.
11
Most independent variables are calculated as the average of three data points:
1986 (the year the first state EITC was enacted), 1996, and 2004. Specific years
used vary depending on data availability. The averages are taken to account for
change over time and lags in time between the phenomena measured and policy
changes. They also minimize one-year spikes in the data.
12
Average of 1986, 1996, and 2005, all adjusted to 2005 dollars. Data from the
Bureau of Economic Analysis, Regional Economic Accounts. Mean: $29,373; standard
deviation: $4,151.
13
This is a 4-point scale created by Robert D. Brown that takes into account partisan
majorities in each house of the legislature and in the governor’s office. Higher scores
24
executive leadership can determine the fate of many of these issues.
and the percent of large firms that are in low-wage service industries.
rates have been tested in previous iterations and have been found to
have no effect (or they are strongly correlated with other independent
25
measures. First, state election campaign contributions are employed
measuring the proportion of large firms (those with more than 1000
employees) that come from these industries.17 This accounts for the
fact that low-wage service industry employers are much more likely to
care about antipoverty policy because they will be most affected. This
power (these employees could be scattered throughout the state in various small
businesses, which may not have any political power as a group). The variable also
had no effect on the results when included in the model. Finally, the percent of a
state’s employees who work at Wal-Mart was tested but had no effect.
16
Average percentage from 1996 and 2004 (or nearest year available). The business
percentage includes general business; finance, insurance, and real estate;
agriculture; transportation; construction; health; and communications and
electronics. Two separate measures of contributions from low-wage industries and
from business associations were tested and rejected for their extremely small
percentages and the lack of any independent effects. Percentages were calculated
from the Institute on Money in State Politics. Business mean: 28.64%; business
standard deviation: 8.98%. Labor mean: 4.96%; labor standard deviation: 2.96%.
17
Includes two industry categories: retail trade, and accommodation and food
services. From the average of 1998 and 2004. From County Business Patterns data.
Mean: 3.97%; standard deviation: 9.77%.
26
policymakers would be more likely to take their actual or potential
eligibility levels (i.e., Medicaid work support). There are two extremely
27
well over one standard deviation. The effect of party is slightly less
percentage points.
Model 3 (table 4), which considers the factors that affect state
value of 0.20. The results here are clear: only income has a significant
at the .01 percent level). (This finding held through multiple variations
median income would raise the EITC score by more than one standard
associated with EITC score, at the .01 percent level. However, in this
model 4 (table 5). This model has good explanatory power (the
18
The correlation between income and EITC cost (which is primarily a measure of
poverty in the state) is -0.62, excluding the possibility of keeping both variables in
the model. EITC cost is per resident, calculated based on 2003 federal EITC claims
from state residents. From “A Hand Up,” table 8 .
28
The most important of these is race: the percent black in the
when substituting state poverty for income.19 (Both could not be used
Discussion
unbiased) due to the small sample size and the inherent difficulties in
this question. First, table 1 demonstrates how the four work support
19
This is a measure of the percent of the state population with income below 200
percent of the federal poverty level. Data from 2004-5. Ranges from 23 to 48
percent.
29
either high or low work support states. That is, they demonstrate clear
income workers. That these states follow one of these two patterns
reveals that all four policies follow broadly similar political logics. To
some extent, states have characteristics that lead them either to use
Moreover, the states that fall into these categories would surprise no
one. The nine “high work support states,” which have above average
percent, earned income credits, and minimum wages above the federal
Illinois), historically liberal, and quite wealthy. Eleven states are “low
low work support states are southern, five are western, and all are
relatively poor and conservative. Many of these are the same states
support.
this goal. These states are less predictable, and represent ten different
30
patterns. The most common pattern is for states to have a higher
minimum wage than the federal level, while remaining at lower levels
on the other three policies. In this category, all but Michigan are
moderate work support states fall into eight different patterns, none of
which are followed by more than three states. This implies that 16
analysis.
finding from the models is that income matters substantially across all
four policies—it is, as the theory predicts, the only variable that is
control would affect the policies that were theoretical controversial and
31
salient to the public and political parties, a category that includes
SCHIP and minimum wages. The only policy for which partisanship
the effect was stronger with public liberalism, reflecting the fact that
box. In other words, public opinion matters substantially more for this
policy than for the other three, where public opinion is always filtered
The third clear finding from the analyses is that race does matter.
proxy for liberal public opinion. First, and most importantly, percent
wages remains.
That is, states with higher proportions of black residents are more likely
32
to have EITCs. It is unclear exactly how to account for this finding (and
model). At the very least, this indicates that the politics of the EITC
welfare. This may indicate that Medicaid has been effectively delinked
from AFDC and TANF, or simply that eligibility levels are not the policy
feature that racial biases affect. SCHIP was also unaffected by race,
business power.
33
Second, as expected, business has no influence on EITCs.
the material benefit a state EITC may have for low-wage employers. If
the competition for limited funds, they are not doing so in this case.
political power is having the effect that is the opposite of what would
How can we explain this effect? There is little evidence that the
business community has engaged in the debate over public health care
at the state level, so the effect must not be due to direct business
34
support these programs, despite their direct material benefit – they are
these programs are in their material self interest, and they prevent
eligibility levels despite the salience of the policy for political parties.
Most policymaking theories predict that interest groups can have little
policy features, such as eligibility levels for working parents, are simply
likely a sign that on a policy with only moderate salience to the public,
preferences.
35
The fourth conclusion about business power is that direct, noisy
not necessarily the way that business exercises its influence. From
other evidence in the analysis, it seems that the most important source
The politics of work support are clearly quite complex, and more
36
they publicly oppose) and not public health care programs (which they
generally ignore). The results of this analysis indicate that the truth
References
37
High Work
Support
States
DELAWARE 107% 200 3 $6.65
ILLINOIS 192% 400 2 $6.50
MAINE 207% 200 1 $7.00
MASSACHUSET
TS 133% 400 3 $7.50
MINNESOTA 275% 280 5 $6.15
NEW JERSEY 115% 350 4 $7.15
NEW YORK 150% 250 5 $7.15
RHODE ISLAND 192% 250 4 $7.40
VERMONT 192% 300 5 $7.25
Moderate
Work Support
States
ALASKA 81% 175 $7.15
ARIZONA 200% 200 0 $6.75
ARKANSAS 18% 200 0 $6.25
CALIFORNIA 107% 250 0 $7.50
COLORADO 67% 200 3 $6.85
CONNECTICUT 157% 300 0 $7.65
FLORIDA 58% 200 $6.67
GEORGIA 55% 235 0 $5.15
HAWAII 100% 200 0 $7.25
INDIANA 27% 200 2 $5.15
IOWA 77% 200 1 $5.15
KANSAS 36% 200 3 $2.65
MARYLAND 38% 300 5 $6.15
MICHIGAN 61% 200 0 $7.15
MISSOURI 40% 300 0 $6.50
MONTANA 62% 150 0 $6.15
NEBRASKA 58% 185 2 $5.15
NEVADA 86% 200 $6.15
NEW
HAMPSHIRE 56% 300 $5.15
NEW MEXICO 65% 235 0 $5.15
NORTH
CAROLINA 54% 200 0 $6.15
OHIO 90% 200 0 $6.85
OKLAHOMA 43% 185 2 $5.15
OREGON 100% 185 2 $7.80
PENNSYLVANIA 61% 235 0 $7.15
38
SOUTH
CAROLINA 97% 185 0 $5.15
VIRGINIA 31% 200 3 $5.15
WASHINGTON 79% 250 $7.93
WEST VIRGINIA 36% 200 0 $5.85
WISCONSIN 192% 185 5 $6.50
39
Labor campaign
contributions + 2.512 (2.930)
Large low-wage
employers +/- 0.241 (0.788)
Constant -29.481 (66.475)
Note: The significance of business campaign contributions
and large low-wage employers are tested against a two-sided
alternative. All other variables are tested against a one-sided
alternative.
* Indicates a statistically significant result (p<.05).
40
Per capita income (in
thousands) + 0.215 (0.053)*
Democratic control +/- 0.173 (0.316)
Percent black +/- -0.006 (0.028)
Business campaign
contributions + -0.009 (0.025)
Labor campaign
contributions + -0.011 (0.085)
Large low-wage
employers + -0.009 (0.023)
Constant -5.013 (1.924)
Note: The significance of Democratic control and percent
black are tested against a two-sided alternative. All other
variables are tested against a one-sided alternative.
* Indicates a statistically significant
result (p<.05).
41