Engineering Economics Monopoly Numerics
Engineering Economics Monopoly Numerics
Price Discrimination
Charging different prices to different consumers for the same product. Enables firms to charge some consumers higher prices, and to capture consumer surplus.
Since under first degree price discrimination, each customer is charged the maximum price that they are willing to pay, consumer surplus is zero.
$
D = MR
9
P*= 5.25
profit
There are also 100 low-volume consumers who value the 1st unit at $12.
The total cost of production is TC = 6 Q. (So ATC = TC/Q = 6Q/Q = 6.)
Determine the total revenue, total cost, producer surplus (profit), consumer surplus, & sum of the producer & consumer surplus for the following four options:
1. No price discrimination one unit sells for $15.
High-volume consumers value the 1st unit of a good at $15 & the 2nd unit at $10. $ 15 $
12
10 6 6
ATC ATC
Suppose firm sells all units individually for $15. The 100 low-volume The 100 high-volume consumers will buy 0 units. consumers will buy 1unit. $ $ 15 12
10
6
profit
6
ATC ATC
TR = PQ = 15(100) = 1500, TC = 6 Q = 6 (100) = 600, & Producer Surplus or = TR TC = 1500 600 = 900. Consumer surplus = 0(100) = 0. PS + CS = 900 + 0 = 900
Suppose firm sells all units individually for $12. The 100 low-volume The 100 high-volume consumers will buy 1 unit. consumers will buy 1unit. $ $ 15 12 10 6
ATC
CS
12
profit
profit
6
ATC
TR = 12(200) = 2400, TC = 6 Q = 6(200) = 1200, & Producer Surplus or = TR TC = 2400 1200 = 1200. Consumer Surplus = 3(100) + 0(100) = 300 PS + CS = 1200 + 300 = 1500
Suppose firm sells all units individually for $10. The 100 low-volume The 100 high-volume consumers will buy 1 units. consumers will buy 2 units. $ $ 15
CS
10
profit profit
12 10 6
ATC
CS
profit ATC
TR = PQ = 10(300) = 3000, TC = 6 Q = 6 (300) = 1800, & Producer Surplus or = TR TC = 3000 1800 = 1200. Consumer surplus = 5(100) + 2(100) = 700. PS + CS = 1200 + 700 = 1900
Suppose firm sells 1-unit packs for $12 & 2-unit packs for $20. The low-volume consumers The high-volume consumers will buy a 1-unit pack. will buy a 2-unit pack. $ $ 15
CS
12
profit profit ATC
10 6
6 1
ATC
TR = PQ = 12(100) + 20(100)= 3200, TC = 6 Q = 6 (300) = 1800, & Producer Surplus or = TR TC = 3200 1800 = 1400. Consumer surplus = 5(100) + 0(100) = 500. PS + CS = 1400 + 500 = 1900
In our 2nd degree price discrimination case, the firm offered two sizes of packages, 1 unit for $12 & 2 units for $20.
The 100 high-volume consumers value the 1st unit of a good at $15 & the 2nd unit at $10. However, notice that if the firm tried to charge $25 for the 2-pack, the high-volume consumers would only buy a 1-pack. This is because they would be better off with consumer surplus of $15 $12 = 3 with a 1-pack than consumer surplus of $25 $25 = 0 with a 2-pack. The profit with 2nd order price discrimination is more than the profit for the one-price options. PS+CS is the same as for the unit price of $10, but the producer has captured the $200 lowvolume CS as PS or profit.
Charging different prices to different groups. Example: Charging lower movie admissions to students & senior citizens than to other moviegoers.
Suppose the demand functions for two groups of consumers are D1: P = 101 13Q and D2: P = 53 7 Q. Notice that D1 is steeper and so less elastic than D2 . (So group 1 will pay a higher price than group 2.) The total cost function is TC = 90 + 128Q 22Q2 + Q3 . If the firm is able to price discriminate between the two groups, determine the prices that should be charged, the quantities that will be purchased, total revenue, total cost, and profit. We need to equate the two MR functions to the MC function. MC = dTC/dQ = 128 44Q + 3Q2. Group 1: TR1 = PQ = (101 13Q)Q = 101Q 13Q2 , and MR1 = dTR1/dQ = 101 26 Q Group 2: TR2 = PQ = (53 7Q)Q = 53Q 7Q2 , and MR2 = dTR2/dQ = 53 14 Q
Our Group 1 Demand function was P = 101 13 Q, and the MR function was MR1 = 101 26 Q. The MC function was MC = 128 44Q + 3Q2.
Set MR1 = MC: 101 26 Q = 128 44Q + 3Q2 0 = 3Q2 18Q + 27 Dividing by 3 to simplify: 0 = Q2 6Q + 9 0 = (Q 3) (Q 3) Q3=0 So for Group 1, Q = 3 From Group 1s demand function, P1 = 101 13 (3) = 62. The revenue from Group 1 will be PQ = (62)(3) = 186.
Our Group 2 Demand function was P = 53 7 Q, and the MR function was MR2 = 53 14 Q. The MC function was MC = 128 44Q + 3Q2.
Set MR2 = MC: 53 14 Q = 128 44Q + 3Q2 0 = 3Q2 30Q + 75 Dividing by 3 to simplify: 0 = Q2 10Q + 25 0 = (Q 5) (Q 5) Q5=0 So for Group 2, Q = 5 From Group 2s demand function, P2 = 53 7 (5) = 18. The revenue from Group 2 will be PQ = (18)(5) = 90
Adding the revenues from the two groups together, we get TR = 186 + 90 = 276. Since we produced 3 units for Group 1 and 5 for Group 2, our production level is 8. Plugging 8 into our total cost function, TC = 90 + 128Q 22Q2 + Q3 = 218. So our profit is = TR TC = 276 218 = 58.
Suppose that a firm has constant average and marginal costs as shown. Also, each customer has the indicated demand curve.
Suppose that the firm charges price P* per unit. Based on the per unit charge, the firm earns revenues equal to the area of the blue box.
P* ATC=MC
D
Q Q*
The firm can also pick up the consumer surplus, if it charges a membership fee equal to the area of the green triangle.
P*
ATC=MC D Q Q*
The firms total revenue (from each customer) is the combined areas of the blue box and the green triangle. Recall that ATC = TC/Q.
P
So, TC = ATCQ. So, the total cost (from each customer) is the purple box.
P*
ATC=MC D Q Q*
The firms profit from this two-part tariff strategy will be greatest if it produces where the Demand and ATC = MC curves intersect, or P = ATC = MC.
P
P*
ATC=MC D Q Q*
P 35
5 D 30
ATC=MC
Combining the membership fee of $450 with the per unit sales revenues of $150 that we found earlier, we have total revenues per customer of $450 + $150 = $600. From the total cost function, the total production cost for the 30 units per customer is TC = 5Q = 5(30) = 150. So our profit per customer is = TR TC = 600 150 = $450.
Bundling
Bundling is packaging two or more products to gain a pricing advantage. Conditions necessary for bundling to be the appropriate pricing alternative: Customers are heterogeneous. Price discrimination is not possible. Demands for the two products are negatively correlated.
Consider the following reservations prices, for two buyers: Alan and Beth
Stereo Alan $225 TV $375 Sum of reservation prices $600
Beth
Maximum price for both to buy the good
$325 $225
$275 $275
$600
To get both people to buy both goods without bundling, you can only charge $225 + $275 = $500, & each person would have consumer surplus of $600 $500 = $100. If you bundle, you can charge $600 & consumer surplus = 0.
The effectiveness of bundling as a pricing strategy depends upon the degree of negative correlation between the demands for the two goods.
Example: Suppose that elasticity of demand with respect to advertising is 0.10, and elasticity of demand with respect to price is -0.50. What percent of sales revenues should the advertising budget should be? A/(P*Q) = - A / D = -0.10 / -0.50 = 0.20 or 20%
Cost-Plus Pricing
The price charged by the firm is the average total cost of production plus a percentage of that cost. Example: If the average total cost of production is $50, and the firm uses a 10% markup, the firm will sell the product for $55.
Product-Line Pricing Example: A company has 3 product lines. deluxe: TC = 70 + 40Q + Q2 & demand function is P = 90 4Q regular: TC = 65 + 30Q + Q2 & demand function is P = 84 2Q economy: TC = 50 + 20Q + Q2 & demand function is P = 60 Q Determine the profit-maximizing price for each line. For each product line, we want MR = MC. So for each line, we need to calculate MC = dTC/dQ, TR = PQ, & MR = dTR/dQ. deluxe: MC = 40 + 2 Q TR = (90 4Q)Q = 90 Q 4Q2 MR = 90 8Q MC = 30 + 2 Q TR = (84 2Q)Q = 84 Q 2Q2 MR = 84 4Q
regular:
For our product-line pricing example, we have so far: deluxe: P = 90 4Q, MR = 90 8 Q MC = 40 + 2 Q, regular: P = 84 2Q, MR = 84 4Q MC = 30 + 2 Q, economy: P = 60 Q, MR = 60 2Q MC = 20 + 2 Q,
For each line we set MR = MC. So,
For the deluxe line, 90 8 Q = 40 + 2 Q 50 = 10 Q & Q = 5. From the demand function, the deluxe price is P = 90 4 Q = 90 4(5) = 90 20 = 70. For the regular line, 84 4 Q = 30 + 2 Q 54 = 6Q & Q = 9. The regular price is P = 84 2(9) = 84 18 = 66. For the economy line, 60 2 Q = 20 + 2 Q 40 = 4 Q & Q = 10. The economy price is P = 60 10 = 60 10 = 50.
Peak-Load Pricing
When demand is not evenly distributed, a firm needs to have facilities to accommodate periods of high demand. Even with large facilities, the firm may experience times when the demand is greater than can be handled. Then the firm may experience costly computer system crashes. During off-peak times (periods of lower demand), there is excess capacity. The firm charges less at off-peak times. Example: More phone calls are made during business hours than in the evenings and on weekends. So the phone companies charge more during business hours.
Peak-Load Pricing Example: Suppose the demand function for a firms service is Peak times (days): P = 74 5 Q Off-peak times (nights): P = 26 5 Q The marginal cost of providing the service is MC = 2 + 2Q . Determine the day & night profit-maximizing prices. We need to find when MR = MC for days & for nights. For days, TR = PQ = (74 5 Q) Q = 74 Q 5 Q2 So MR = dTR/dQ = 74 10 Q . MR = MC implies 74 10 Q = 2 + 2 Q , or 72 = 12 Q. So Q = 6 & peak price is P = 74 5 Q = 74 5(6) = $44 per unit.
Next we need to do the same thing for nights to find the off-peak price. We had these demand functions: Peak times (days): P = 74 5 Q Off-peak times (nights): P = 26 5 Q and the marginal cost function was MC = 2 + 2Q . For nights, TR = PQ = (26 5 Q) Q = 26 Q 5 Q2 So MR = dTR/dQ = 26 10 Q . MR = MC implies 26 10 Q = 2 + 2 Q , or 24 = 12 Q. So Q = 2 & off-peak price is P = 26 5 Q = 26 5(2) = $16 per unit (instead of $44 per unit as it was for peak times).
Transfer Pricing
Sometimes firms are organized into separate divisions. One division may produce an intermediate product and supply it to another division to produce the final product. How does the firm determine the efficient price at which the intermediate product should be sold. That is, what is the transfer price?
How do we determine the optimal quantity & price for the final product (the auto)?
First, find the companys (total) marginal cost MCT, which is the marginal cost of division Es producing an engine (MCE) plus the marginal cost of division As producing an auto (MCA). That is, MCT = MCA + MCE .
Then, produce the amount of output (autos) so that the marginal revenue from selling an auto (MR) is equal to the marginal cost of production (MCT).
The appropriate price of the auto for that quantity of output is determined from the demand curve for the firms autos.
So what is the transfer price at which division E sells the intermediate product to division A?
If the company determines the price of the engine, then division E is a price taker. So, PE and MRE will be equal.
The firm should set the price of the intermediate product (the engine) so that PE = MRE = MCE at the profit-maximizing output level previously determined.
Continuing, we have demand for the final product: Pf = 100 0.001 Q . TCp = 70,000 + 15Q + 0.005 Q2 ; TCm = 30,000 + 10 Q . MCp = dTCp/dQ = 15 + 0.01 Q; MCm = dTCm/dQ = 10 MC = MCp + MCm = 25 + 0.01 Q ; MR = 100 0.002 Q Equating MR & MC, we have 100 0.002 Q = 25 + 0.01 Q . So 75 = 0.012 Q & Q = 75/0.012 = 6,250 . So the price of the intermediate product is Pi = MCp = 15 + 0.01 (6,250) = $77.50 . The price of the final product is Pf = 100 0.001 Q = 100 0.001 (6,250) = $93.75 . Plugging the quantity 6,250 into the two total cost functions & adding, we find TC = TCp + TCm = $451,562.50 . The total revenue is TR = Pf Q = (93.75) (6250) = $585,937.50 . So the firms profit is TR TC = $134,375 .