Topic 3 (Ch. 8) Index Models
Topic 3 (Ch. 8) Index Models
+ +
= = =
= = =
= = =
n
i
i
n
i
n
i
M i i
n
i
i M i i
n
i
n
i
i i i p
e
n
R
n n
e R
n
R
n
R w R
1 1 1
1 1 1
1
)
1
(
1
) (
1 1
| o
| o
P M P P P
e R R + + = | o
The index model and diversification
24
The portfolio has a sensitivity to the market given by:
(the average of the individual |
i
s)
It has a nonmarket return component of a constant
(intercept):
(the average of the individual alphas)
It has a zero mean variable:
(the average of the firm-specific components)
=
=
n
i
i p
n
1
1
| |
=
=
n
i
i p
n
1
1
o o
=
=
n
i
i p
e
n
e
1
1
25
The portfolios variance is:
The systematic risk component of the portfolio variance
(the component that depends on marketwide
movements) is and depends on the sensitivity
coefficients of the individual securities.
This part of the risk depends on portfolio beta and ,
and will persist regardless of the extent of portfolio
diversification.
No matter how many stocks are held, their common
exposure to the market will be reflected in portfolio
systematic risk.
2 2
M P
o |
2
M
o
) (
2 2 2 2
p M p p
e o o | o + =
26
In contrast, the nonsystematic component of the
portfolio variance is o
2
(e
P
) and is attributable to firm-
specific components e
i
.
Because the e
i
s are uncorrelated, we have:
where : the average of the firm-specific variances.
Because this average is independent of n, when n
gets large, o
2
(e
P
) becomes negligible.
Thus, as more and more securities are added to the
portfolio, the firm-specific components tend to cancel
out, resulting in ever-smaller nonmarket risk.
) (
2
e o
) (
2
e o
) (
1
) (
1
) (
2 2
1
2
2
e
n
e
n
e
i
n
i
P
o o o =
|
.
|
\
|
=
=
27
28
Summary:
As more and more securities are combined into a
portfolio, the portfolio variance decreases because of
the diversification of firm-specific risk.
However, the power of diversification is limited.
Even for very large n, part of the risk remains because
of the exposure of virtually all assets to the common, or
market, factor.
Therefore, this systematic risk is said to be
nondiversifiable.
29
The single-index model
suggests how we might go about actually measuring
market and firm-specific risk.
Suppose that we observe the excess return on the
market index and a specific asset over a number of
holding periods.
We use as an example monthly excess returns on the
S&P 500 index and GM stock for a one-year period.
i M i i i
e R R + + = | o
Estimating the Single-Index Model
30
31
We can summarize the results for a sample period in a scatter diagram:
32
The single-index model states that the relationship
between the excess returns on GM and the S&P 500 is
given by the following regression equation:
In this single-variable regression equation, the
dependent variable plots around a straight line with an
intercept o and a slope |.
The deviations from the line (e) are assumed to be
mutually uncorrelated and uncorrelated with the
independent variable.
) ( ) ( ) ( t e t R t R
GM M GM GM GM
+ + = | o
33
The sensitivity of GM to the market, measured by |
GM
, is
the slope of the regression line.
The intercept of the regression line is o
GM
, representing
the average firm-specific return when the markets excess
return is zero.
Deviations of particular observations from the regression
line in any period are denoted e
GM
, and called residuals
(i.e. each of these residuals is the difference between the
actual security return and the return that would be
predicted from the regression equation describing the
usual relationship between the security and the market).
Thus, residuals measure the impact of firm-specific events.
34
Estimating the regression equation of the single-index
model gives us the security characteristic line (SCL).
The SCL is a plot of the typical excess return on a
security as a function of the excess return on the market.
Compute o
GM
and |
GM
:
Let y
t
: excess return on GM in month t
x
t
: excess return on the market (S&P 500) in month t
n: the total number of months.
35
The estimate of beta coefficient (i.e. the slope of the
regression line SCL):
The intercept of the regression line:
=
= =
= = =
n
t
n
t
t t
n
t
t
n
t
n
t
t t t
GM
x x n
y x y x n
1 1
2 2
1 1 1
) ( ) (
) )( ( ) (
|
n
x y
n
t
n
t
t GM t
GM
=
= = 1 1
) (
|
o
36
Month y
t
x
t
x
t
y
t
(x
t
)
2
January 5.41 7.24 39.1684 52.4176
February -3.44 0.93 -3.1992 0.8649
March -8.79 -0.38 3.3402 0.1444
April -8.08 -1.01 8.1608 1.0201
May 7.10 4.92 34.9320 24.2064
June -0.03 1.18 -0.0354 1.3924
July -2.36 -0.83 1.9588 0.6889
August -3.55 -0.91 3.2305 0.8281
September -1.16 -4.18 4.8488 17.4724
October -1.02 3.97 -4.0494 15.7609
November 6.32 6.25 39.5000 39.0625
December 2.43 3.90 9.4770 15.2100
Sum -7.17 21.08 137.3325 169.0686
37
135 . 1
) 08 . 21 ( ) 0686 . 169 ( 12
) 17 . 7 )( 08 . 21 ( ) 3325 . 137 ( 12
2
=
=
= =
= = =
n
t
n
t
t t
n
t
t
n
t
n
t
t t t
GM
x x n
y x y x n
1 1
2 2
1 1 1
) ( ) (
) )( ( ) (
|
month per % 59 . 2
12
) 08 . 21 )( 135 . 1 ( 17 . 7
=
=
n
x y
n
t
n
t
t GM t
GM
=
= = 1 1
) (
|
o
38
Compute residuals:
For each month t, our estimate of the residual is the
deviation of GMs excess return from the prediction
of the SCL:
Deviation = Actual Predicted Return
These residuals are estimates of the monthly
unexpected firm-specific component of the rate of
return on GM stock.
)] (
[ ) ( ) ( t R t R t e
M GM GM GM GM
| o + =
)] ( 135 . 1 59 . 2 [ ) ( t R t R
M GM
+ =
39
Month y
t
(actual) x
t
(actual) Predicted y
t
Residual (Residual)
2
January 5.41 7.24 5.63 -0.22 0.05
February -3.44 0.93 -1.53 -1.91 3.63
March -8.79 -0.38 -3.02 -5.77 33.28
April -8.08 -1.01 -3.74 -4.34 18.87
May 7.10 4.92 2.99 4.11 16.86
June -0.03 1.18 -1.25 1.22 1.49
July -2.36 -0.83 -3.53 1.17 1.37
August -3.55 -0.91 -3.62 0.07 0.01
September -1.16 -4.18 -7.33 6.17 38.12
October -1.02 3.97 1.92 -2.94 8.62
November 6.32 6.25 4.50 1.82 3.30
December 2.43 3.90 1.84 0.59 0.35
Sum -7.17 21.08 126
40
Hence, we can estimate the firm-specific variance:
The standard deviation of the firm-specific component
of GMs return:
which is equal to the standard deviation of the
regression residual.
=
=
12
1
2 2
6 . 12
2 12
126
)] ( [
2
1
) (
t
GM
t e
n
e o
month per e
GM
% 55 . 3 6 . 12 ) ( = = o
41
Practitioners often use a modified
index model that uses total rather than
excess returns (deviations from T-bill
rates) in the regressions:
instead of
* e br a r
M
The Industry Version of the Index Model
e r r r r
f M f
+ + = ) ( | o
42
To see the impact of this departure:
If r
f
is constant over the sample period, both
equations have the same independent variable r
M
and residual e.
Thus, the slope coefficient will be the same in the
two equations.
e r r r r
f M f
+ + + = | | o
e r r
M f
+ + + = | | o ) 1 (
43
However, the intercept is really an estimate of
The apparent justification for this procedure is
that, on a monthly basis, r
f
(1 - |) is small.
But, note that for 1, the regression intercept will
not equal the index model alpha.
). 1 ( | o +
f
r
44
Betas estimated form past data may not be the
best estimates of future betas.
This suggests that we might want a forecasting
model for beta.
One simple approach would be to collect data on
beta in different periods and then estimate a
regression equation:
Current beta = a + b (Past beta)
Given estimates of a and b, we would then forecast
future betas using the rule:
Forecast beta = a + b (Current beta)
Predicting Betas
45
However, there is no reason to limit ourselves to
such simple forecasting rules.
Why not also investigate the predictive power of
other financial variables in forecasting beta?
Rosenberg and Guy find the following variables
help predict betas:
Variance of earnings.
Variance of cash flow.
Growth in earnings per share.
Market capitalization (firm size).
Dividend yield.
Debt-to-asset ratio.
46
Rosenberg and Guy also find that even after
controlling for a firms financial
characteristics, industry group helps to
predict beta.