Merger and Acquisition Problem
Merger and Acquisition Problem
29-1
29-2
29-3
29-4
29-5
29-6
29-7
pure diversification)
To break up a inefficiently run conglomerate
In the case of spin-offs, to improve managerial efficiency in
the subsidiary, by offering a directly observable stock price
as an (admittedly imperfect) measure of managerial
performance.
Also, in the case of spin-offs, to give equity investors more
flexibility in diversifying their investment portfolios.
29-8
29-9
29-10
29-11
29-12
29-13
CAR (%)
15.00%
10.00%
EXXON
MOBIL
5.00%
0.00%
-5 -4 -3
-2 -1
-5.00%
Day relative to announcement day
29-14
29-15
29-16
WACCAB = [VA/(VA+VB)](WACCA) +
[VB/(VA+VB)](WACCB)
WACCAB = [25,000/(25,000+1250)](0.10) +
[1250/(25,000+1250)](0.12) = 0.100952 or 10.0952%
WSU EMBA Corporate Finance
29-17
29-18
This involves paying $1250M or $12.50 per share for all the
existing Firm B shares. Basically, Firm B shareholders are
selling at the existing Firm B stock price of $12.50 per share!
New Firm A value = (VA + Vsynergy)/500M shares or
(25,000M + 1342.04M)/500M = $52.69 per share
Firm B shareholders are unlikely to approve such an offer.
WSU EMBA Corporate Finance
29-19
29-20
Scenario 1, paying the existing $12.50 per share for Firm B, gives Firm
A shareholders all of the merger NPV or Vsynergy.
Scenario 2, paying $25.93 per share (an almost 100% premium) for Firm
B, gives Firm B shareholders all of the merger NPV or Vsynergy. Firm A
shareholders would receive no benefit.
Ideally, the rational price would be one that allocates the merger
NPV somewhat proportionally between the bidder and target
firm shareholders.
However, if history is any indicator, an price similar to scenario
2 (or even more) is the more likely outcome!
WSU EMBA Corporate Finance
29-21