Lecture 6: Compensating Wage Differentials
Lecture 6: Compensating Wage Differentials
Wage Differentials
The model of competitive labor markets
implies that as long as workers or firms can
freely enter and exit the marketplace, there
will be a single wage in the economy if all
jobs are alike and all workers are alike.
All jobs are not the same. Adam Smith in 1776
argued that compensating wage differentials arise to
compensate workers for the nonwage characteristics
of jobs. It is not the wage that is equated across jobs
in a competitive market, but the “whole of the
advantages and disadvantages” of the job.
Workers differ in their preferences for job
characteristics and firms differ in the working
conditions that they offer. The theory of
compensating differentials tells a story of how
workers and firms “match and mate” in the labor
market.
1. Workers’ and Firms’ Choice with Risky Jobs
E.g. Employer X: NT.$100 per hour, clean, safe work conditions
Employer Y: NT.$100 per hour, dirty, noisy factory
→ Most workers would undoubtedly choose employer X.
If employer Y decides not to alter working conditions, it must
pay wage above NT.$100 to be competitive in the labor market.
→ The extra wage it must pay to attract workers is called a
compensating wage differential because the higher wage is paid
to compensate workers for the undesirable working conditions.
After the wage rise of firm Y, if both firms could obtain the
quantity and quality of works they wanted, the wage differential
would be an equilibrium differential, in the sense that there be no
forces causing the differential to change.
* The compensating wage differential
serves two purposes:
1. It serves a social need by giving people an incentive
to voluntarily do dirty, dangerous, or unpleasant
work or a financial penalty on employers offering
unfavorable working conditions.
2. At an individual level, it serves as a reward to
workers who accept unpleasant jobs by paying them
more than comparable workers in more pleasant
jobs. Those who opt for more pleasant conditions
have to buy them by accepting lower pay.
→ Compensating wage differentials provide the key to
the valuation of the nonpecuniary aspects of
employment.
Note:
The predicted outcome of the compensating wage
differential theory of job choice is not that employees
working under “bad” conditions receive more than
those working in “good” conditions. The prediction is
that, holding worker characteristics constant,
employees in bad jobs receive higher wages than
those working under more pleasant conditions.
* The compensating wage differential
theory is based on three assumptions:
1. Utility Maximization
Workers seek to maximize their utility, not their
income. Compensating wage differentials will only
arise if some people do not choose the highest-
paying job offered, preferring instead a lower-
paying but more pleasant job.
→ Wages do not equalize in this case. The net
advantage – the overall utility from the pay and the
psychic aspects of the job – tend to equalize for the
marginal workers.
2. Worker Information
Workers are aware of the job characteristics of
potential importance to them.
→ Company offering a “bad” job with no compensating
wage differential would have trouble recruiting or
retaining workers, trouble that would eventually
force it to raise its wage.
Note: Our predictions about compensating wage
differentials hold only for job characteristics that
workers know about.
3. Workers Mobility
Workers have a range of job offers from which to
choose. It is the act of choosing safe jobs over
dangerous ones that forces employers offering
dangerous work to raise wages.
2. The Hedonic Wage Function
A wage theory based on the assumption of
philosophical hedonism that workers strive to
maximize utility.
To simplify our discussion, we shall analyze just one
dimension –risk of injury on the job – and assume
that the compensating wage differentials for every
other dimension have already been established.
→ To obtain a complete understanding of the job
selection process and the outcomes of that process, it
is necessary to consider both the employer and
employee sides of the market.
(1) Employee Considerations
Some combinations of wage rates and risk levels that would yield
the same level of utility can be represented by indifference curve
map.
Risk
W Highly Averse to Risk People differ in their aversion to
Moderately
the risk of being injured. Those
Averse to Risk who are very sensitive to this
risk will require large wage
increases for any increase in risk
(UH), while those who are less
UL sensitive will require smaller
wage increases to hold utility
UH constant (UL).
Risk
(2) Employer Considerations
Assumptions:
a. It is presumably costly to reduce the risk of
injury facing employees.
b. Perfect competition → Firms operate at zero
profits.
c. All other job characteristics are presumably
given or already determined.
→ If a firm undertakes a program to reduce the
risk of injury, it must reduce wages to remain
competitive.
Forces on the employer side of the market tent
to cause low risk to be associated with low
wages and high risk to be associated with high
wages, holding other things constant.
Example: