Modern Labor Economics: Inequality in Earnings
Modern Labor Economics: Inequality in Earnings
CHAPTER 15
Inequality in Earnings
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Chapter Outline
Measuring Inequality
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Workers as individuals, and society as a whole, are
concerned with both the level and the dispersion of income
in the economy.
• Concerns about the level of income stem from income being an important
determinant of the consumption of goods and services by individuals.
• Concerns about the distribution/dispersion of income stem from the
importance that we, as individuals, place on our relative standing in society
and the importance that our society places on equity.
The distribution of family incomes (both earned and
unearned) or earnings is important in assessing the issues
of poverty and relative consumption opportunities.
• Earnings, as part of overall incomes, are a reflection of:
- marginal productivity,
- investment in (and returns to) education,
- training,
- migration activities, and
- access to opportunities.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.1 Measuring Inequality
For example, if everyone had the same earnings, say
$20,000 per year, there would be no dispersion – see
Figure 15.1
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Figure 15.1 Earnings Distribution with Perfect Equality
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Figure 15.2 Distributions of Earnings with Different Degrees of Dispersion
Distribution A
shows small
dispersion
around the
mean/average
income of
$20,000
Distribution B
shows large
dispersion
around the
mean/average
income of
$20,000
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.1 Measuring Inequality
Distribution A exhibits smaller dispersion than Distribution B,
that is, earnings B exhibit a greater degree of inequality.
Graphs (Figures 15.1 and 15.2) can help illustrate the concepts
of dispersion, but they are a clumsy tool for measuring
inequality.
There are various quantitative indicators of earnings inequality,
and the most obvious measure of inequality is the variance of
the distribution. This is expressed as: 2
(E E)
i
Variance i
(15.1)
n
where
Ei = the earnings of person i in the population
= the mean (average) level of earnings in the population
E = the summation sign indicating the sum over all persons in the population
n = the number of people in the population
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.1 Measuring Inequality
One problem with the use of variance is that it tends to rise as
earnings grow larger – thus variance is a better measure of
the absolute than of the relative dispersion of earnings.
An alternative to the variance is the coefficient of variation
(CV): the square root of the variance (or the standard
deviation, σ) divided by the mean (μ):
E
2
i E
i
n Standard Deviation
CV =
Mean
• If all earnings were to double, the coefficient of variation, unlike the
variance, would remain unchanged.
The most widely used measures of earnings inequality involve
ranking the population by earnings level and then classifying
them into percentiles to which a given level of earnings falls.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.1 Measuring Inequality
Classification of earnings levels into percentile will enable us
to either compare the earnings levels associated with each
given percentile or compare the share of total earnings
received by each.
Comparing shares of total income received by the top and
bottom fifth (or “quintiles”) of households in the population is a
widely used measure of income inequality.
• Another commonly used measure is comparing the ratio of earnings
at, say, the 80th (90th) percentile to earnings at the 20th (10th) percentile.
• For example, in 2011: earnings of men in the 20th percentile =
$21,361
earnings of men in the 80th percentile = $80,561
$80,561
3.77
$21,361
Ratio of earnings =
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.2 Earnings Inequality Since 1980: Some
Descriptive Data
Earnings distributions for both men and women, using the
80:20 ratio, showed that both earnings and the ratios for the
80th: 20th varied throughout the period – see Table 15.1
Other ratios (apart from the 80:20) are: 80:50, 50:20, 90:10,
90:50, and 50:10
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Table 15.2
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.2 Earnings Inequality Since 1980: Some
Descriptive Data
From 1980 to 1990, the 80:20; 80:50; 50:20; 90:10; 90:50;
and 50:10 ratios tell the same story for men and women –
earnings inequality clearly grew among men and women.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.2 Earnings Inequality Since 1980: Some
Descriptive Data
The Increased Returns to Higher Education
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Table 15.3
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.2 Earnings Inequality Since 1980: Some
Descriptive Data
Growth of Earnings Dispersion within Human-Capital Groups
Earnings within narrowly defined human-capital groups
became more diverse, if for example, those at the top of the
earnings distribution are older workers with college
educations (and are better-paid), while those at the bottom
are younger workers who dropped out of high school
(unskilled group with lower wages) – increase in the overall
80:20 or 90:10 ratio.
Division of men into different groups by age cohorts and
education (college and high school) revealed that earnings
disparities grew among each human-capital group since
the1980s – see Table 15.4.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Table 15.4
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.3 The Underlying Causes of Growing Inequality
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.3 The Underlying Causes of Growing Inequality
Changes in Supply
The changes in supply (increase and/or decrease) can be
the dominant force/cause of the wage changes or the
increasing gap and thus the growth of wage inequality in
recent years – see Figure 15.3.
If supply shifts are primarily responsible for the increasing
gap between the wages of highly educated (skilled) and less-
educated workers, we should observe that the employment of
less-educated workers increased relative to the employment
of the college-educated workforce.
Table 15.4 contains data indicating that supply shifts could
not have been the primary cause – shows earnings and
employment were positively correlated.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Figure 15.3 Changes in Supply as the Dominant Cause of Wage Changes
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Table 15.5
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.3 The Underlying Causes of Growing Inequality
Changes in Demand: Technological Change
Shifts in labor demand curves were a prominent factor
raising inequality since 1980.
•Rightward shifts in labor demand curve will ↑W and ↑E for university
educated workers.
•Leftward shifts in labor demand curve will ↓W and ↓E for high school
education or less.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.3 The Underlying Causes of Growing Inequality
Changes in Demand: Earnings Instability
Given technological change and coupled with growing
competition within the product markets through deregulation
and the globalization of production, also may have led to a
growth in the instability of earnings for individual workers –
thus growth in earnings inequality.
Product-market changes that contribute to employment or
unemployment of those workers in the lowest quintile would
cause their earnings to fluctuate if:
• Some workers in this group may be unlucky to experience
unemployment that reduces their earnings.
• Other workers in this group may be lucky enough to experience
temporary earnings increases through overtime work or profit-
sharing bonuses.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
15.3 The Underlying Causes of Growing Inequality
Changes in Institutional Forces
Two other causes of growing earnings inequality come from:
• The decline in unions, and this could have caused the increase in the
80:50 or 90:50 ratios.
• Minimum wage remained constant over much of the period since
1980, while wages in general rose, thus the falling real minimum
wage could have reduced wages at the very bottom of the earning
distribution.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
MODERN LABOR ECONOMICS
THEORY AND PUBLIC POLICY 12TH EDITION
CHAPTER 15A
Lorenz Curves and
Gini Coefficients
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
The most commonly used measures of distributional inequality
involve grouping the distribution into deciles or quintiles and
comparing the earnings (or income) received by each.
It is assumed that:
• Each household in the population has the same income
• Each fifth of the population receives a fifth of the total income
The equality shown in the table above will yield the straight line
AB in Figure 15A.1, its slope is 1, and the area of the ∆ is 0.5
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
As indicated in the table below, the distribution of income is not
perfectly equal.
Actual Share Cumulative Share Cumulative Share
Quintiles of Income of Households of Income
First Fifth 3.5 % 20 % or 0.2 3.5 % or 0.035
Second Fifth 8.8 % 40 % or 0.4 12.3 % or 0.123
Third Fifth 14.8 % 60 % or 0.6 27.1 % or 0.271
Fourth Fifth 23.3 % 80 % or 0.8 50.4 % or 0.504
Highest Fifth 49.6 % 100 % or 1.0 100 % or 1.0
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Figure 15A.2 Lorenz Curves That Cross
If two Lorenz curves
cross, it is not
possible to conclude
which one represents
a greater/better
equality.
Lorenz curve A
shows a lower
proportion of total
income received by
the poorest quintile
than does the
distribution shown by
Lorenz curve B. For
B, the other
remaining quintiles
are lower in
comparison to those
of A.
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
A popularly known measure of inequality is the Gini coefficient,
which is a measure of the ratio of the area between the Lorenz curve
and line AB – line of perfect equality.
An easy way to calculate the Gini coefficient is to split the area
under the Lorenz curve into a series of triangles and rectangles and
compute as below:
Triangles Rectangles
0.5 x 0.2 x 0.035 = 0.0035
0.5 x 0.2 x 0.088 = 0.0088 0.2 x 0.035 = 0.0070
0.5 x 0.2 x 0.148 = 0.0148 0.2 x 0.123 = 0.0246
0.5 x 0.2 x 0.233 = 0.0233 0.2 x 0.271 = 0.0542
0.5 x 0.2 x 0.496 = 0.0496 0.2 x 0.504 = 0.1008
Total 0.1 0.1866
The sum of the areas of the five triangles and four rectangles yield
0.2866 (note that the sum of the triangles will also be 0.1, so the
focus should be on finding the areas of the four rectangles).
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
Figure 15A.3 Calculating the Gini Coefficient for the 2002 Distribution of Household Income
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.
0.5 0.2866
Gini Coefficient 0.4268 (15A.1)
0.5
Gini coefficient (GC) is generally between 0 and 1
•GC = 0 → perfect equality
•GC = 1 → perfect inequality
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, Twelfth Edition Copyright ©2015 by Pearson Education, Inc.
Ronald G. Ehrenberg • Robert S. Smith All rights reserved.