ECN 301 - Lecture 3
ECN 301 - Lecture 3
Intermediate
Microeconomics
Instructor: Nabila Maruf
Independent University, Bangladesh
Lecture Note: 3
Chapter 3: Preferences
Preferences
This chapter will be devoted to clarifying the economic
concept of “best things.”
Neutrals
A good is a neutral good if the consumer doesn’t care
about it one way or the other.
3.4 Examples of Preferences
3.4 Examples of Preferences
3.4 Examples of Preferences
Satiation
There is some overall best bundle for the consumer,
and the “closer” he is to that best bundle, the better off
he is in terms of his own preferences.
Suppose that the consumer has some most preferred
bundle of goods (x ,x ), and the farther away he is
1 2
a bliss point.
3.4 Examples of Preferences
3.4 Examples of Preferences
The indifference curves have a negative slope when
the consumer has “too little” or “too much” of both
goods, and a positive slope when he has “too much”
of one of the goods.
When he has too much of one of the goods, it becomes
a bad
Discrete Goods
Discrete good is a good that is only available in integer
amounts
3.4 Examples of Preferences
3.5 Well-Behaved Preferences
Defining features for well-behaved indifference
curves:
First we assume more goods are better
That is, if we take two bundles of goods (x1, x2) and (y1,
y2) on the same indifference curve and take a weighted
average of the two bundles such as
(1/2x1+ 1/2y1, 1/2x2+ 1/2y2)
Suppose that (y1, y2) and (x1, x2) are indifferent bundles.
A convex set has the property that if you take any two points in the
set and draw the line segment connecting those two points, that line
segment lies entirely in the set.
3.5 Well-Behaved Preferences
3.5 Well-Behaved Preferences
One extension of the assumption of convexity is the
assumption of strict convexity.
For Example:
Perfect substitutes: MRS = -1
Neutrals: MRS is everywhere infinite
Perfect Complements: MRS is zero or infinity
3.8 Behavior of the MRS
The assumption of monotonicity implies that indifference curves
must have a negative slope