Chapter I Theory of Consumer Behaviour
Chapter I Theory of Consumer Behaviour
ECON 2011
0 10 16 20 22 22 20
utils utils utils utils utils utils
0 10 6 4 2 0 -2
utils utils utils utils utils utils
Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility
cX 1c X 2d
X1
MRS
dX 1c X 2d
X2
cX 1c X 2d X 2
MRS
dX 1c X 2d X 1
c X2
MRS
d x1
Thus,
Types of Indifference Curves
Given a utility function it is relatively easy to draw
the indifference curves by plotting all the points
such that equals a constant.
For different values of utility we get different
indifference curves.
i) ICs for Cobb-Douglas Utility Function
Suppose the utility function is given by .
For this utility function the indifference curve is
convex to the origin.
The indifference curve consist of a set of X1 and X2
such that K = for some constant K.
…CONT’D
Solving for results in
We can draw ICs for different values of and (& their
exact shapes depend on the values of c and d).
Pane A: Panel B:
Fig 1.7: ICs for Cobb-Douglas Preference
ii) ICs for Quasilinear utility function
This is for a utility function that is linear in good
2, but possibly non-linear in good 1.
As the name implies it is partly linear utility
function.
In general, ICs for such utility function of
preference is given by
Example:
The indifference curve for these utility
functions are vertical translates of each
other or one indifference curve.
…CONT’D
The equation for the IC is .
Higher values of K indicate higher indifference curves.
Example:
Now lets draw the ICs for different values of K.
Where is a parameter .
This utility function gives rise to three special cases
depending on the value of .
If it equals 1, it becomes linear utility function i.e.
as for perfect substitute.
If it equals 0 its ICs look like those of Cobb-
Douglas.
If it equals -, the ICs look like those of Leontief
utility function(Perfect Complement).
Special Indifference Curves
Convexity or down ward sloping is among the
characteristics of indifference curve and this shape
of indifference curve is for most goods.
In this situation, we assume that two commodities
such as X and Y can substitute one another to a
certain extent but are not perfect substitutes.
However, the shape of the indifference curve will be
different if commodities have some other unique
relationship.
Here, are some of the ways in which indifference
curves/maps might be used to reflect preferences for
some special cases.
1) ICs for Perfect substitutes
Two products are perfect substitutes if the consumer
is willing to substitute one for the other at a constant
rate.
The simplest case is when the consumer is willing to
substitute the two goods on one – to – one basis.
Thus, IC will be characterized by constant MRS.
• for
Example: Blue pencil and Red pencil
P2 d X1
From (3) P1dX1 = P2cX2
P2 c
X1 X 2 ..................................(4)
P1 d
• Substitute equation (4) in the budget constraint (equation (2))
P1 c
P1 ( X 2 ) P2 X 2 m
P2 d
c
P2 X 2 P2 X 2 m
d
md
X2
p 2 c P2 d
d m
X2 optimal consumptio n of x 2
(c d ) P2
• From (3)
P1 d
X2 X 1 ..............................(6)
P2 c
P1 d
P1 X 1 P2 ( X1) m
P2 c
By solving it we arrive at,
c m
X2 optimal consumptio n of x1
(c d ) P1
• Note that c
and d
cd cd
X1
Perfect Complements
• The optimal choice always lies at the sharp point
where the budget line passes through the vertex no
matter what the prices are (Figure 1.25)
Figure 1.25
• Example: The utility function U(X,Y) = min (X, 4Y)
• The person will consume goods so that,
• X = 4 Y Y = X / 4
• I = Px X + Py Y = Px X + Py X/4
= (Px + 0.25 Py) X
• The demand function for X is therefore,
I
X*=
Px 0.25 Py
• Similarly I = Px X + Py Y = (Px 4Y + Py Y)
=(4 Px + Py) Y
I
Y* =
4 Px Py
• Since the result we obtained is positive we can conclude that the good
is a normal good.
Total change in demand (x)
• x is substitution effect plus the income effect, or it is the change in
demand due to the change in price holding nominal income constant
x = x(p’1,m)-x(p1,m) (m is constant).
In terms of substitution and income effects
x = xs + xn, where xs = SE, and xn = IE
OR,
x(p’1,m)-x(p1,m) = [x(p’1,m’)-x(p1,m)]+[x(p’1,m) -
x(p’1,m’)]
This equation is called the Slutsky identity (Named
for Eugen Slutsky (1880-1948), a Russian
Economist who investigated demand theory).
Generally,
If the total change of a good resulting from a
change in its price is opposite to the direction of
price change, the good is called Ordinary good
and,
If they move in the same direction, the good is
called a Giffen good.
Consumer Surplus
• The consumer’s surplus is defined as the
difference between the amount of money that a
consumer actually pays to buy a certain quantity
of a commodity X and the amount that he would
be willing to pay for this quantity.
• Graphically, the consumer’s surplus can be found
by the area below the demand curve and above
the market price.
• Assume that the consumer’s demand for a good is a
straight line (Figure 1.40).
• The demand curve measures the amount of good
that will be demanded at each price.
p
A
P2
P1
P C
O q2 q1 Q B q
A
P1
B C
P
Q2 Q1 q