0% found this document useful (0 votes)
43 views64 pages

INTERMIC LPPT Ch4 Lecture Addition 14sept

This document discusses utility functions and indifference curves. It provides examples of different types of utility functions including perfect substitution, perfect complementarity, quasi-linear, and Cobb-Douglas functions. It also discusses concepts of marginal utility and marginal rates of substitution. Illustrations are provided to visualize indifference curves corresponding to different utility functions.

Uploaded by

Uzair Arif
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
43 views64 pages

INTERMIC LPPT Ch4 Lecture Addition 14sept

This document discusses utility functions and indifference curves. It provides examples of different types of utility functions including perfect substitution, perfect complementarity, quasi-linear, and Cobb-Douglas functions. It also discusses concepts of marginal utility and marginal rates of substitution. Illustrations are provided to visualize indifference curves corresponding to different utility functions.

Uploaded by

Uzair Arif
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 64

CHAPTER 4

Utility

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Preferences: A Reminder
x ≻ y: x is preferred strictly to y.
x ~ y: x and y are equally preferred.
x ≿ y: x is preferred at least as much as y.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 1
A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive, and continuous can
be represented by a continuous utility function.
 Continuity means that small changes to a consumption bundle cause
only small changes to the preference level.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 2
A utility function u(x) represents a preference relation if and
only if:

xʹ ≿ xʺ ⇔ u(xʹ) ≥ u(xʺ)

xʹ ≻ xʺ ⇔ u(xʹ) > u(xʺ)

xʹ ~ xʺ ⇔ u(xʹ) = u(xʺ)

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 3
Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept.
 E.g., if u(x) = 6 and u(y) = 2 then bundle x is strictly preferred to bundle
y.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 1
• Consider the bundles (4, 1), (2, 3), and (2, 2).
• Suppose (2, 3) ≻ (4, 1) ~ (2, 2).
• Assign to these bundles any numbers that preserve the preference
ordering; e.g.,
• Call these numbers utility levels.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 2
• An indifference curve contains equally preferred bundles.
• Equal preference  same utility level.
• Therefore, all bundles on an indifference curve have the same utility level.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 3
• So the bundles (4, 1) and (2, 2) are on the indifference curve with utility
level u = 4.
• But the bundle (2, 3) is on the indifference curve with utility level u = 6.
• In an indifference curve diagram, this preference information looks as
follows:

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 4

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 5
Another way to visualize this same information is to plot the utility level on a
vertical axis.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 6

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 7
This 3D visualization of preferences can be made more informative by adding
into it the two indifference curves.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 8

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 9
Comparing more bundles will create a larger collection of all indifference
curves and a better description of the consumer’s preferences.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 10

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 11
As before, this can be visualized in 3D by plotting each indifference curve at
the height of its utility index.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 12

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 13
• Comparing all possible consumption bundles gives the complete collection
of the consumer’s indifference curves, each with its assigned utility level.
• This complete collection of indifference curves completely represents the
consumer’s preferences.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 14
The following eight diagrams illustrate the connection between the two-
dimensional look at utility functions and indifference curves to the three-
dimensional look.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 15

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 16

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 17

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 18

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 19

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 20

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 21

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 22

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions & Indifference Curves – 23
The collection of all indifference curves for a given preference relation is an
“indifference map.”
 An indifference map is equivalent to a utility function.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 4
There is no unique utility function representation of a preference relation.
 Suppose represents a preference relation.
 Again consider the bundles (4, 1), (2, 3), and (2, 2).

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 5

 Since

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 6

• Define
 Then,
 So again,
• V preserves the same order as u and therefore represents the same
preferences.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 7

• Define
 Then,
 So again,
W preserves the same order as u and therefore represents the same
preferences.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Utility Functions – 8
If
• u is a utility function that represents a preference relation
and
• f is a strictly increasing function,
then V = f (u) is also a utility function representing the same preference
relation. This is known as a “monotonic transformation.”

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Goods, Bads, and Neutrals – 1
• A good is a commodity which increases utility with additional consumption.
• A bad is a commodity which decreases utility with additional consumption.
• A neutral is a commodity which does not change utility with additional
consumption.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Goods, Bads, and Neutrals – 2

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves – 1
Instead of consider

This utility function is an example of two goods that are perfect substitutes.
What do the indifference curves for this “perfect substitution” utility
function look like?

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Perfect Substitution Indifference Curves

All are linear and parallel.


Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian
Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves – 2
Instead of consider

This utility function is an example of two goods that are perfect complements.
What do the indifference curves for this “perfect complementarity” utility
function look like?

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Perfect-Complementarity Indifference Curves

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves – 3
A utility function of the form is linear in just x2
and is called “quasi-linear.”
E.g.,

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Quasi-linear Indifference Curves

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves – 4
Any utility function of the form with a > 0 and b > 0
is called a “Cobb-Douglas” utility function.
• E.g.,

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Cobb-Douglas Indifference Curves

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Marginal Utilities – 1
Marginal means “incremental.”
The marginal utility of commodity i is the rate of change of total utility as the
quantity of commodity i consumed changes.
 I.e.,

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Marginal Utilities – 2
E.g., if then

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of Substitution – 1
• The general equation for an indifference curve is
k is a constant.
• Totally differentiating this identity gives

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of Substitution – 2

can be rearranged algebraically to be:

 This is the MRS.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


MU and MRS: An Example – 1
Suppose Then

and

So,

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


MU and MRS: An Example – 2

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions – 1
A quasi-linear utility function is of the form
and

So,

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions – 2
MRS = −f’ (x1) does not depend upon x2 so the slope of indifference curves for
a quasi-linear utility function is constant along any line for which x 1 is
constant. What does that make the indifference map for a quasi-linear utility
function look like?

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions – 3

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates of Substitution – 1

As previously discussed, applying a monotonic transformation to a utility


function representing a preference relation simply creates another utility
function representing the same preference relation.
 What happens to marginal rates of substitution when a monotonic
transformation is applied?

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates of Substitution – 2

For the
Create What is the MRS for V?

 Which is the same as the MRS for u.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates of Substitution – 3

More generally, if V = f (u) where f is a strictly increasing function, then the


MRS is unchanged by this positive monotonic transformation.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4
Q1: The text said that raising a number to an odd power was a monotonic
transformation. What about raising a number to an even power? Is this a
monotonic transformation? (Hint: consider the case f(u) = u^2 .)

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4
3. We claimed in the text that if preferences were monotonic, then a diagonal
line through the origin would intersect each indifference curve exactly once.

Can you prove this rigorously?

(Hint: what would happen if it intersected some indifference curve twice?)

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Review Questions: Chapter 4

Q7: Can you explain why taking a monotonic transformation of a utility function
doesn’t change the marginal rate of substitution?

Hint: Remember as we move up to the better zones, indifference curves have


higher utility, but MRS is just multiplying.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Question: Chapter 5

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian


Question related to Chapter 5
In the case of convex preferences, any point that satisfies the tangency condition
must be an optimal point.

This is clear geometrically: since convex indifference curves must curve away
from the budget line, they can’t bend back to touch it again.

Hint: Read chapter 5: Choice, page number 77.

Copyright © 2019 Hal R. Varian

You might also like