0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views64 pages

7 Technology

This document discusses key concepts related to technologies and production functions. It defines a technology as a process that converts inputs into outputs. Production functions describe the maximum output possible from different input combinations. The marginal product of an input is how output changes with small changes in that input. Returns to scale refers to how output changes when all inputs change proportionally. Constant returns to scale means a proportional increase in all inputs leads to a proportional increase in output.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
16 views64 pages

7 Technology

This document discusses key concepts related to technologies and production functions. It defines a technology as a process that converts inputs into outputs. Production functions describe the maximum output possible from different input combinations. The marginal product of an input is how output changes with small changes in that input. Returns to scale refers to how output changes when all inputs change proportionally. Constant returns to scale means a proportional increase in all inputs leads to a proportional increase in output.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 64

Lecture 7

Technology
Technologies

A technology is a process by which


inputs are converted to an output
 E.g., labour, a computer, electricity,
software and cloud storage are being
combined to produce this lecture
Technologies
 Usually,
several technologies will
produce the same product
 E.g.,
a whiteboard and pens can be
used instead of software
 Which technology is “best”?
 How do we compare technologies?
Input Bundles

 xi denotes the amount used of input i


 An input bundle is a vector of the
input levels (x1, x2, … , xn)
 E.g. (x1, x2, x3) = (6, 0, 93)
Production Functions

y denotes the output level


 The production function states the
maximum amount of output
technologically possible from an
input bundle

y  f ( x1 , , xn )
Production Functions
One input, one output
Output Level y = f(x) is the
production
y’ function
y’ = f(x’) is the maximal
output level obtainable
from x’ input units

x’ x
Input Level
Technology Sets

A production plan is an input bundle


and an output level (x1, … , xn, y)
A production plan is feasible if
y  f ( x1 , , xn )

 Thecollection of all feasible


production plans is the production set
Production Sets
One input, one output
Output Level

Technically
y’ efficient plans
The production
y” Technically set
inefficient
plans
x’ x
Input Level
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
 What does a technology look like
when there is more than one input?
 The two-input case: A production
plan is a vector (x1,x2, y)
 Suppose the production function is

y  f ( x 1 , x 2 )  2x 1/ 3 1/ 3
1 x2 .
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
 E.g., the maximal output level possible
from the input bundle
(x1, x2) = (8, 1) is

1/3 1/3 1/3 1/3


y  2x 1 x 2  2  8  1  2  2  1  4.
 And the maximal output level possible
from (x1, x2) = (8, 8) is

1/3 1/3 1/3 1/3


y 2x 1 x 2  28 8  2  2  2  8.
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
Output, y

x2
(8,8)
(8,1)
x1
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
Technologies with Multiple Inputs

 Because representing two input


technologies in 3D is hard for the
human eye, we use instead a version
of level curves
 The y output unit isoquant is the set
of all input bundles that yield the
same output level y
Isoquants with Two Variable Inputs
x2

y 

y 
x1
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
 The complete collection of isoquants
is the isoquant map
 The isoquant map is a convenient
way to represent the production
function
1/3 1/3
 E.g. y  f(x 1, x 2 )  2x 1 x 2
Technologies with Multiple Inputs
x2

y
x1
Fixed-Proportions Technologies
A fixed-proportions (or Leontieff)
production function is of the form

y  min{ a 1 x 1 , a 2 x 2 ,  , a n x n }.

E.g. y  min{ x 1 , 2x 2 }
E.g.

with
Fixed-Proportions Technologies
x2 y  min{ x 1 , 2x 2 }

x1 = 2x2

7 min{x1,2x2 } = 14
4 min{x1,2x2 } = 8
2 min{x1,2x2 } = 4
4 8 14 x1
Perfect-Substitutes Technologies
A perfect-substitutes production
function is of the form

y  a 1 x 1  a 2x 2    a n x n .

E.g.E.g. y  x 1  3x 2

with
Perfect-Substitutes Technologies
y  x 1  3x 2
x2
x1 + 3x2 = 9
x1 + 3x2 = 18
x1 + 3x2 = 24
8
6
Isoquants are linear
3
and parallel
9 18 24 x1
Marginal Products
y  f ( x1 , , xn )
 The marginal product of input i is the
rate-of-change of the output level as
the level of input i changes, holding
all other input levels fixed
 That is,
y
MPi 
 xi
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y  f ( x1 , x 2 )  x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y  f ( x1 , x 2 )  x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
 y 1  2/ 3 2/ 3
MP1   x1 x 2
 x1 3
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y  f ( x1 , x 2 )  x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
 y 1  2/ 3 2/ 3
MP1   x1 x 2
 x1 3
and the marginal product of input 2 is
Marginal Products
E.g., if
1/ 3 2 / 3
y  f ( x1 , x 2 )  x1 x 2
then the marginal product of input 1 is
 y 1  2/ 3 2/ 3
MP1   x1 x 2
 x1 3
and the marginal product of input 2 is
 y 2 1/ 3  1/ 3
MP2   x1 x 2 .
 x2 3
Marginal Products
Unless inputs are perfect substitutes, the
marginal product of one input depends
on the amount used of other inputs

E.g., MP1  1/3x 1 2/3 x 2/3


2

Then if x2 = 8, MP1  1/3x 1 2/3 8 2/3  4/3x 1 2/3


and if x2 = 27 then
 2/3 2/3  2/3
M P1  1/3x 1 27  3x 1 .
Marginal Products

 The marginal product of input i is


diminishing if it becomes smaller as
the level of input i increases.
 That is, if
 MPi
 0.
 xi
Marginal Products
1/ 3 2 / 3
E.g., if y  x 1 x 2 then
1  2/ 3 2/ 3 2 1/ 3  1/ 3
MP1  x1 x 2 and MP2  x1 x 2
3 3
Marginal Products
1/ 3 2 / 3
E.g., if y  x 1 x 2 then
1  2/ 3 2/ 3 2 1/ 3  1/ 3
MP1  x1 x 2 and MP2  x1 x 2
3 3
so  MP1 2  5 / 3 2/ 3
  x1 x 2  0
 x1 9
Marginal Products
1/ 3 2 / 3
E.g., if y  x 1 x 2 then
1  2/ 3 2/ 3 2 1/ 3  1/ 3
MP1  x1 x 2 and MP2  x1 x 2
3 3
so  MP1 2  5 / 3 2/ 3
  x1 x 2  0
 x1 9
and  MP
2   2 x1/ 3x  4 / 3  0 .
1 2
 x2 9
Both marginal products are diminishing
Returns-to-Scale

 Marginal products describe the


change in output level as a single
input level changes
 Returns-to-scale describes how the
output level changes as all input
levels change in the same proportion
 E.g., all input levels doubled, or
halved
Returns-to-Scale
If, for any input bundle (x1,…,xn),
f (kx 1 , kx 2 ,  , kx n )  kf ( x 1 , x 2 ,  , x n )
for any k > 1, then the technology described
by the production function f exhibits
constant returns-to-scale

E.g., If k = 2, then doubling all input levels


has doubled the output level
Returns-to-Scale
One input, one output
Output Level
y = f(x)
2y’

Constant
y’ returns-to-scale

x’ 2x’ x
Input Level
Returns-to-Scale
If, for any input bundle (x1,…,xn),

f (kx 1 , kx 2 ,  , kx n )  kf ( x 1 , x 2 ,  , x n )

For any k > 1 then the technology exhibits


diminishing returns-to-scale

E.g., If k = 2, then doubling all input levels


has less than doubled the output level
Returns-to-Scale
One input, one output
Output Level

2f(x’) y = f(x)

f(2x’)
Decreasing
f(x’) returns-to-scale

x’ 2x’ x
Input Level
Returns-to-Scale
If, for any input bundle (x1,…,xn),

f (kx 1 , kx 2 ,  , kx n )  kf ( x 1 , x 2 ,  , x n )

for any k > 1, then the technology exhibits


increasing returns-to-scale

E.g., If k = 2, then doubling all input levels


has more than doubled the output level
Returns-to-Scale
One input, one output
Output Level
Increasing y = f(x)
returns-to-scale
f(2x’)

2f(x’)
f(x’)

x’ 2x’ x
Input Level
Returns-to-Scale

A single technology can ‘locally’


exhibit different returns-to-scale
Returns-to-Scale
One input, one output
Output Level

y = f(x)
Increasing
returns-to-scale
Decreasing
returns-to-scale

x
Input Level
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y  x 1a 1 x a2 2  x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
a1 a2 an
(kx 1 ) (kx 2 )  (kx n )
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y  x 1a 1 x a2 2  x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
a1 a2 an
(kx1 ) (kx 2 )  (kxn )
a1 a 2 an a1 a 2 an
 k k k x x  x
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y  x 1a 1 x a2 2  x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
(kx1 ) a1 (kx 2 ) a 2 (kxn ) an
 k a1k a 2 k an x a1 x a 2 x an
 k a1  a 2  an x1a1 x a
2
2 x an
n
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y  x 1a 1 x a2 2  x n
an
.
Scale up all input levels proportionately
by k. The output level becomes
a1 a2 an
(kx1 ) (kx 2 ) (kxn )
a1 a 2 an a1 a 2 an
 k k k x x x
a1  a 2  an a1 a 2 an
k x1 x 2  xn
a1  an
k y.
Examples of Returns-to-Scale
The Cobb-Douglas production function is
y  x 1a 1 x a2 2  x n
an
.

(kx 1 ) a 1 (kx 2 ) a 2  (kx n ) a n  k a 1    a n y .

The Cobb-Douglas technology’s returns-


to-scale depends on the sum of indices:
constant if a1+ … + an = 1
increasing if a1+ … + an > 1
decreasing if a1+ … + an < 1
(All this because the Cobb-Douglas function is homogeneous
of degree a1+ … + an )
Returns-to-Scale

 Q: Can a technology exhibit


increasing returns-to-scale even if all
its marginal products are
diminishing?
Returns-to-Scale

 Q: Can a technology exhibit


increasing returns-to-scale even if all
its marginal products are diminishing?
 A: Yes
 Why?
Returns-to-Scale
A marginal product is the rate-of-
change of output as one input level
increases, holding all other input
levels fixed
 Marginal product diminishes because
the other input levels are fixed
 The new input’s units have each less
and less of other inputs to work with
Returns-to-Scale
 When all input levels are increased
proportionately, new input units will
always have the same amount of
other inputs to work with
 Input productivities need not fall
 So returns-to-scale can be constant
or increasing
Technical Rate of Substitution

 At
what rate can a firm substitute
one input for another without
changing its output level?
Technical Rate of Substitution
x2

x'2

y

x'1 x1
Technical Rate of Substitution
The slope of the isoquant is the
x2 rate at which input 2 must be
substituted by input 1 so as not
to change the output level.

x'2 It is the
Technical Rate of Substitution

y

x'1 x1
Technical Rate of Substitution
 How is the TRS computed?
 Same as always
 Use total differentiation on y  f ( x 1 , x 2 ).
 We want to introduce a small change
(dx1, dx2) in the input bundle such that
the output does not change
y y
0 dx1  dx 2 .
 x1  x2
Technical Rate of Substitution
y y
0 dx1  dx 2
 x1  x2
rearranges to
y y
dx 1   dx 2
 x1  x2
so
dx 2  y/ x 1

dx 1  y/ x 2
Technical Rate of Substitution
dx 2  y/ x 1 MP1
 
dx 1  y/ x 2 MP2

It is the rate at which input 2 must be


given up as input 1 increases to keep
the output level constant

It is the slope of the isoquant, as well as


the ratio of the marginal products
Technical Rate of Substitution; A
Cobb-Douglas Example
a b
y  f ( x1 , x 2 )  x1 x 2
MPs are
 y/ x 1  ax 1a 1x b2 an  y/ x 2  a b 1
bx 1 x 2 .
d
The TRS is

dx 2  y /  x1 ax1a  1xb2 ax 2
   .
dx1  y /  x2 a b1 bx1
bx1 x 2
Technical Rate of Substitution; A
Cobb-Douglas Example
x2 1/ 3 2 / 3 1 2
y  x1 x 2 ; a  and b 
3 3
ax 2 (1 / 3)x 2 x2
TRS    
bx1 ( 2 / 3 ) x1 2x 1

8 x2 8
TRS     1
2x 1 24

4 x1
Technical Rate of Substitution; A
Cobb-Douglas Example
x2 1/ 3 2 / 3 1 2
y  x1 x 2 ; a  and b 
3 3
ax 2 (1 / 3)x 2 x2
TRS    
bx1 ( 2 / 3 ) x1 2x 1
x2 6 1
TRS    
2x 1 2  12 4
6

12 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies

Awell-behaved technology is
monotonic, and
convex
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Monotonicity
 Monotonicity:More of any input
always generates more output

y y
monotonic
not
monotonic

x x
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
 Convexity: If the input bundles x’
and x” both provide y units of output
then the mixture tx’ + (1-t)x”
provides at least y units of output,
for any 0 < t < 1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2

x'2

x"2
y
x'1 x"1 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2

x'2
 tx'1  ( 1  t ) x"1 , tx'2  ( 1  t ) x"2 
x"2
y
x'1 x"1 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2

x'2
 tx'1  ( 1  t ) x"1 , tx'2  ( 1  t ) x"2 
x"2 y
y
x'1 x"1 x1
Well-Behaved Technologies -
Convexity
x2 Convexity in technology
implies that the TRS
x'2 decreases (in absolute value)
as x1 increases

Combining inputs
x"2 increases output
x'1 x"1 x1

You might also like