Ch-3 Property Right
Ch-3 Property Right
of resources
1. Markets exist for all goods and services produced and
consumed
2. All markets are assumed to be perfectly competitive.
3. All transactors have perfect information
4. Private property rights are fully assigned in all resources and
commodities.
5. No existence of externalities.
6. All goods and services are private goods. That is, there are
no public goods.
7. All utility and production functions are 'well behaved'.
8. All agents are maximizers.
• If a market neglects one of the above condition results
inefficiency in allocation of resources.
05/17/2024 1
3.2.Property rights
• It is defined as a set of entitlement defining the owners’ rights and privileges
and limitations for the use of resources.
• The seller has the right to prevent the buyer from consuming
the products in the absence of payment; i.e, the buyer must
pay to receive the products.
05/17/2024 3
• In a competitive market price level determined by supply & demand.
• Given the price, both consumers and producers maximize their surpluses and the
market clears.
producer’s dd
surplus
Qd Quantity
• In this case, the allocation is efficient because according to static efficiency, the net
benefit is maximized by the market allocation and is equal to the sum of consumers
and producers surpluses.
• In the system, with well defined property rights and competitive markets,
producers try to maximize their surpluses and consumers try to maximize their
surpluses.
• The price system then induces those self interested parties to make choices which
are efficient from the point of view of society as a whole.
05/17/2024 4
Characteristics of Property Rights
• Property rights result efficient allocation of resource in a well functioning
market economy has four main characteristics.
05/17/2024 6
Classification of externalities
• External effects can be positive or negative. If the utility or production of
some party is decreased by the decision taken by the other party, this
externality can be called as external diseconomy or negative externality.
• And, If the utility or production of some will have a benefit to other, it is
called external economy or positive externality. In this case, the market
will under supply the resources. Lets see type of externality ,Table 3.1
05/17/2024 7
• In Table 3.1 above, we are concerned only to set out the forms that unintended
interdependence between agents could take. Some examples will be provided
shortly.
• Row 5 has the production of Y determining, for given capital and labour inputs,
the amount of X produced.
05/17/2024 8
• In case of positive externality, the market will under supply the resources.
There is another class of externality called pecuniary externality (pseudo
externality).
• This type of externality occurs when an individual’s activity level affect the
financial circumstances of others but it need not produce misallocation of
resources in pure competition.
• When there is negative externality, marginal social costs (MSC) are higher
than marginal private costs (MPC).
U B U B (M B , S A)
05/17/2024 11
The bargaining solution to an externality problem
•Given that A does not in fact have to pay anything to play her
saxophone in her flat, she will increase her hours of playing up
to the level M0, where MB is equal to zero.
• At that level, A’s total benefit from playing is given by the sum
of the areas of the triangles a, b and d, and B’s total suffering is
measured in money terms by the sum of the areas b,d and c.
12
• This is not an efficient outcome, because at M0, MEC >MB. The
efficient outcome is at M* where MEC =MB.
• In addition, he favored the idea that an efficient outcome can also be attained by vesting
the property right in the generator of the external effect- a victim will offer money for
generator of the externality to reduce the externality and lead to the efficient level.
• As can be seen from the above graph, B is willing to pay for the possible reduction of
externality until MEC > MB. However, externality to the left of M* makes B unwilling to
pay and A will not reduce the externality.
• Hence, at M* efficiency is achieved.
• NB. It needs to be explicitly and carefully noted that there are two things that
are not being claimed.
– First, that it is not being said that the outcome will be the same in both
cases.
– Second, that it is not being said that either way of assigning property rights
necessarily promotes equity.
05/17/2024 15
– For the case where B gets the property right –there is an M reduction
of (M0−M*) and A pays to B an amount equal to the area of triangle
‘b’, the money value of B’s suffering at the efficient outcome M*.
– For the case where A gets the property right – there is an M reduction
of (M0−M*) and B pays to A an amount equal to the area of triangle
‘d’, the money value of A’s loss as compared with the no-property-
rights situation.
• Clearly, which way the property right is assigned affects the wealth of A or
B. in neither cases does the increase in wealth affect the receiving
individual’s tastes.
05/17/2024 16
Production–production externality
• Consider two firms with production functions of;
X X(K X , LX , S)
Y Y(K Y , LY , S)
• where S stands for pollutant emissions arising in the production of Y,
which emissions affect the output of X for given levels of K and L input
there.
• Then, the assumption is that ∂Y/∂S >0, so that for given levels of KY and LY
lower S emissions means lower Y output, and that ∂X/∂S<0, so that for
given levels of KX and LX higher S means lower X.
05/17/2024 17
• Profits in the production of X is given by
πX =PxX(KX, LX, S) −PKKX−PLLX
• where ∂πX/∂S<0. The impact of a small increase in S on profits in the
production of X is similar to terminology of figure above, marginal external
cost, MEC.
• Profits in the production of Y is given by
πY=PyY(KY, LY, S) −PKKY−PLLY
• where ∂πY/∂S>0. The impact of a small increase in S on profits in the
production of Y is similar to terminology of Figure above, marginal benefit,
MB.
• To the producer-to-producer case; in the absence of a well-defined
property right S will be too large for efficiency,
• while an efficient outcome can result from bargaining based on a property
right assigned to either the producer of X or the producer of Y.
• In collusion joint profits maximization will only occur if both firms believe
that their share of maximized joint profits will be larger than the profits
earned separately.
18
Production–consumption externality
• Consider that the external effect impact on two agents, and with respect
to them is non-rival and non-excludable in consumption.
U A U A ( X A U A
A
,Y
with 0
,S )
S
B B B B
U U ( X ,Y , S ) U B
with 0
S
X X ( K X , LX )
Y Y ( K Y , LY , S ) with Y 0
S
05/17/2024 19
• Emissions arise in the production of Y and adversely affect the
utilities of A and B. The pollution experienced by A and B is non-
rival and non-excludable.
• Example: fossil-fuel-burning and electricity plant located in an urban
area..etc.
• However:
– private bargaining based on assignment of property rights will
not deal with the externality problem.
– joint profit maximisation solution is not relevant.
• Hence:
– correcting the market failure requires some kind of ongoing
intervention in the workings of the market by some government
agency through:
– use of taxation
Given cost function as: C PK K Y PL LY C (Y )
PMC C
05/17/2024 Y 20
• Where, PMC stands for private marginal cost. Private costs are the input
costs that the Y producer actually takes account of in determining output
level that maximizing its profit.
• Given there are two sufferers, the MEC is equal to the sum of willingness
to pay of each of them, as consumption of suffering is non-rival and non-
excludable. So that, Social marginal cost : SMC =PMC +MEC
• From graph below to maximize profit, Y firm will produce at Y0, where
PMC is equal to the output price PY.
• This is not that, Y output goes with efficiency, as balancing costs and
benefits at the margin it is ignoring the costs borne by A and B. However,
efficiency requires balancing at the margin of benefits and costs which
include the external costs borne by A and B, i.e., SMC=PY.
• In the absence of any correction of the market failure that is the external
costs imposed on A and B, the market-determined level of Y output will be
too high for efficiency, as will the corresponding level of S.
• Graphically is seen as: 21
Taxation for externality correction
• Non-excludability: once the resources are provided, even those who fail
to pay for it cannot be excluded from consumption of the goods or
services.
05/17/2024 25
Characteristics of private and public goods
05/17/2024 26
• Congestible resources exhibit excludability but not rivalry. Example,
the services to visitors provided by a wilderness area.
• The fact that MRUSA is 1/5 means that A could suffer a loss of 1 unit of
X, and still be as well off if she received 1/5th of a unit of Y by way of
compensation.
• Similarly, the fact that MRUSB is 2/5 means that B could suffer a loss of 1
unit of X, and still be as well off if he received 2/5 of a unit of Y by way of
compensation.
05/17/2024 29
• Markets cannot provide public goods in the amounts that go with allocative
efficiency. In fact, markets cannot supply public goods at all. This follows from
their non-excludability characteristic.
• Because of the direct link between payment and access is broken by non-
excludability, goods and services that have such characteristic have to be
supplied by some entity that can get the revenue required to cover the costs of
production from some source other than the sale of such goods and services.
• Such an entity is government, which has the power to levy taxes so as to raise
revenue.
• The supply of public goods is part of the business of government. The existence
of public goods is one of the reasons why all economists see a role for
government in economic activity.
05/17/2024 30
• Given that it is the government that must supply a public good, the question
which naturally arises for an economist is:
• what rule should government follow so as to supply it in amounts that
correspond to efficiency?
• In a two-person, two commodity economy, the efficient level of supply of public
good is: MRUS A
MRUS B
MRT
• Given more public and private goods, efficiency is attained when the above
condition is satisfied across all goods and services.
• MRT is the marginal cost in terms of forgone private goods consumption, so that
the rule becomes the supply the public good at the level where the sum of all
the MRUS is equal to the marginal cost.
• Now, it follows from its definition that the MRUS is the same as marginal
willingness to pay(MWTP), so this rule can be stated as; supply the public good
at the level where aggregate marginal willingness to pay is equal to marginal
cost.
• Graphically:
05/17/2024 31
The efficient level of supply for a public good
05/17/2024 32
Preference revelation and the free rider problem
• In order to apply the rule of efficiency for the supply public goods, the
government needs to know the preferences, in terms of marginal willingness
to pay, of all relevant individuals.
• It is in the nature of the case that those preferences are not exposed in
markets.
• Given that all consume equal amounts of a public good, and that exclusion
from consumption on account of non-payment is impossible, individuals will
try to ‘free-ride’ with respect to public goods provision.
• For two ‘Don’t buy’ responses, the street lighting is not bought and
installed.
• In the event of one ‘Buy’ and one ‘Don’t buy’, the street lighting is
bought and the individual who voted ‘Buy’ pays the entire cost.
05/17/2024 34
The preference revelation problem
•Clearly both are better off if both write ‘Buy’ and the street lighting is
bought. But, either will be even better off if, as in the bottom left or top
right cell, they can ‘free-ride’.
•While installing the lighting and sharing the cost equally is a Pareto
improvement, it will not come about where both individuals act
independently to serve their own self-interest.
• Hence, given there are only two individuals, if they express their WTP
is £60, the street lighting will go ahead and each will pay £50 in tax.
This represents a Pareto improvement .
• The problem is that the incentives facing each individual are not such
as to guarantee truthful preference revelation.
05/17/2024 36
• Given that tax liability will be proportional to
stated willingness to pay, there is an incentive to
understate it so as to reduce the tax liability if the
street lighting goes ahead, and to get something
of a free ride.
• The problem which arises from the use of common property resources is the tragedy
of commons.
• Example: as the grazing land is free for each member, individual will tend to over
graze the pasture.
• The result is that the property will rapidly deteriorate and this unregulated self
interest behaviour of each individual produces a less than optimal solution for the
group as a whole.
• This problem resulted from indivisibility of the common property and the size of the
beneficiary group.
05/17/2024 38
• Common property rights are desirable where there are no scarce
resources.
• However, these rights will lead to misuse of resources such as over
grazing, over hunting, over fishing etc.
• David Hume observed that it was government’s role to regulate
individual behavior there by reducing the tragedy of commons.
• There are two characteristics of open access allocation of resources.
Those are
– in the presence of excess demand, open access causes resources to be over
exploited.
– The scarcity rent is dissolute; no one appropriates the rent, so it is lost.
• Open access to resources promotes an inefficient allocation.
• These are the possible solutions suggested for tragedy of commons.
05/17/2024 40
Methods of Correcting market failure
• Redefining the property rights: The problems of over exploitation of resources
can be solved through property rights.
• Regulation: There is a general consensus that there are some problems
particularly those concerning the environment which needs government
intervention.
• Taxes and subsidies: Taxes imposed on pollution are costs and thereby can
discourage pollution.
• Subsidies are another way of giving incentive for the producer to reduce
pollution, may be in credit but are not as such economically efficient.
• Marketable permit: Companies buy a permit from the government that allows
them to discharge a certain amount of pollution
05/17/2024 41