Chapter 7 - Market Structure
Chapter 7 - Market Structure
Managerial Economics
Chapter Seven
Perfect Competition,
Monopoly,
Monopolistic competition,
oligopoly.
Market structure
• The type of market structure - has an important implication for strategy decision
• more helpful in price output decisions
• determination of price of the product.
• Managers always try to find out the optimum combination of price and output
which offers the maximum profit to the firm.
• Thus pricing occupies on important place in economic analysis of firms and it
depends on Market structure
• Market structures are different market forms based on the degree of competition
prevailing in the market.
• Broadly the market forms are perfectly competitive market and imperfectly
competitive market.
• The imperfect market is divided into monopoly market, monopolistic competition
market, oligopoly market and duopoly market.
Market structure
MARKET PERFECT MONOPOLY MONOPOLISTIC OLIGOPOLY
STRUCTURE COMPETITION COMPETITION
Number Of Sellers Many One Many Few
Information Complete and free Less information Less information Restricted access to
information price and product
information
Non Price None Advertising Advert and product Heavy advert and
Competition differentiation product
differentiation
Market structure
• The market structures characteristics:
• number of sellers, type of product, barriers to entry, power to affect price and the
extent and type of non-price competition.
• Perfect competition is invariably used as a benchmark for comparison,
• in terms of price, output, profit and efficiency that represents an ideal in certain
respects.
• Perfect competition represents one extreme of the competition spectrum (maximum
competition), while monopoly represents the other (no competition)
• Monopoly firms rare in practice, but does tend to occur in public utilities like gas,
water and electricity supply
• Most real-world firms are along the range of imperfect competition.
• Monopolistic competition and oligopoly are intermediate cases, and are more
frequently found in practice
• for example restaurants and the car industry respectively.
Perfect Competition Market
Short-run equilibrium
• A firm will tend to produce more output as the
market price increases, and its supply curve will
be its marginal cost curve,
• In the short- run, firms’ positive or zero or
negative profit depends on the level of ATC at
equilibrium.
• Depending on the relationship between price
and ATC, the firm in the short-run may earn
economic profit, normal profit or incur
loss and decide to shut-down business.
I. Economic/positive profit - If the AC is below
the market price at equilibrium, the firm earns
a positive profit equal to the area between the
ATC curve and the price line up to the profit
maximizing output.
Perfect Competition Market
Short-run equilibrium
ii. Loss - If the AC is above the market price
at equilibrium, the firm earns a negative
profit (incurs a loss) equal to the area
between the AC curve and the price line.
• If P < ATC, then it should leave the industry in the
long run since the owners of the business can
use the resources more profitably elsewhere.
• If P < AVC then the firm should shut down in the
short run since it cannot even cover its variable
costs, let alone make any contribution to fixed
costs.
Perfect Competition Market
Short-run equilibrium
iii. Normal Profit (zero profit) or break- even
point - If the AC is equal to the market price
at equilibrium, the firm gets zero profit or
normal profit.
• This is the profit that a firm must make
to remain in its current business.
■ Since the perfectly competitive firm
always produces where P =MR=MC (as
long as P exceeds AVC),
• the firm‘s short-run supply curve is given
by the rising portion of its MC curve above
its AVC, or shutdown point
Perfect Competition Market
Short-run equilibrium
iii. Shutdown point - A firm will not stop
production simply because AC exceeds price in
the short-run. The firm will continue to produce
irrespective of the existing loss as far as the price
is sufficient to cover the average variable costs.
• But if P is smaller than AVC, the firm minimizes
total losses by shutting down. Thus, P = AVC is
the shutdown point for the firm.
• Economic losses motivate some to exit (shut
down) from the industry.
• industry supply decreases - market price
increases and all the firms will adjust their
output in order to maximize their profit.
Perfect Competition Market
Solution =0; -4 + 2Q = 0 ; Q = 2
So, AVC is minimum when Q=2. The AVC, when output is 2,
Profit maximization
AVC = 10 – 4 (2) + (2)2 = 6
MC=MR and MC>0
To stay in the market the minimum price is 6 ETB
Monopoly Market structure
• Where only one firm sells the goods and many buyers buy.
• Monopoly is the extreme opposite of perfect competition on the market
structure.
• a firm that has the power to earn supernormal profit in the long run.
• this ability depends on the conditions of lack of substitutes for the product and
barriers to entry or exit.
1. Lack of substitutes for the product – any existing products are not very close in
terms of their perceived functions and characteristics.
2. Barriers to entry or exit - important in the long run in order to prevent firms
entering the industry and competing away the supernormal profit.
there are factors that allow incumbent firms to earn supernormal profits in the long
run by making it unprofitable for new firms to enter the industry.
Thus, there exist structural and strategic barriers.
Monopoly Market structure
A. Structural barriers - the structural barriers are natural barriers, occur because of factors
outside the firm’s control,
i. Control of essential resources - due to the concentration of resources in certain geographic
areas. E.g oil, gas and diamonds and the expertise of owners.
ii. Economies of scale and scope - new firms to compete in terms of cost they will have to enter
on a large scale. E.g. public utilities, like gas, water and electricity supply - such industries are
sometimes referred to as natural monopolies.
iii. Marketing advantages – this is due to brand awareness and image of industries with
consumers being unwilling to buy unknown brands.
iv. Financial barriers - New firms without a track record find it more difficult and more costly to
raise money - greater risk they impose on the lender.
v. Information costs - market research needs to be carried out to investigate the potential
profitability of such entry - imposes a cost.
vi. Government regulations - Patent laws in pharmaceutical industry - where it takes a long time
to get approval. Licensing system - public utilities and postal services in many countries
operate as legally protected monopolies
Monopoly Market structure
• Some of the structural barriers also serve as barriers to exit, which are in the form of
sunk costs - advertising costs, market research costs, loss on the resale of assets,
redundancy payments that have to be paid to workers, and so on. The existence of
such costs increases the risk of entering a new industry.
B. Strategic barriers
■ Strategic barriers occur when an incumbent firm deliberately deters entry, using
various restrictive practices, some of which may be illegal
i. Limit pricing - an incumbent firm tries to discourage entry by charging a low price
before any new firm enters. - only works if the potential entrant does not know the
cost structure of the incumbent.
ii. Predatory pricing - tries to encourage exit or drive firms out of the industry by
charging a low price after any new firms enter - only work if the new entrant does
not know the cost structure of the incumbent. – in some countries predatory
pricing is prohibited by law.
Monopoly Market structure
iii. Excess capacity - serve as a credible threat to potential entrants –
it is easy for incumbents to expand output with little extra cost, thus forcing down
the market price and post-entry profits
if these profits are less than the sunk costs of entry, the entrant will be deterred
from entering the market.
This would apply even if the potential entrant had full knowledge of the incumbent’s
cost structure.
iv. Heavy advertising - This forces the potential entrant to respond by itself spending more
on advertising, which has the effect of increasing its fixed costs, thus increasing the
minimum efficient scale in the industry.
It also adds to the marketing advantages of the incumbent.
These practices will not be possible if the market is contestable.
i.e if there are an unlimited number of potential firms that can produce a
homogeneous product, consumers respond quickly to price changes,
incumbent firms cannot respond quickly to entry by reducing price, and
entry into the market does not involve any sunk costs. Example - a firm could
enter on a hit-and-run basis, by undercutting the incumbent, and exiting quickly if
the incumbent reacts
Monopoly Market structure
iii. Excess capacity - serve as a credible threat to potential entrants –
it is easy for incumbents to expand output with little extra cost, thus forcing down
the market price and post-entry profits
if these profits are less than the sunk costs of entry, the entrant will be deterred
from entering the market.
This would apply even if the potential entrant had full knowledge of the incumbent’s
cost structure.
iv. Heavy advertising - This forces the potential entrant to respond by itself spending more
on advertising, which has the effect of increasing its fixed costs, thus increasing the
minimum efficient scale in the industry.
It also adds to the marketing advantages of the incumbent.
These practices will not be possible if the market is contestable.
i.e if there are an unlimited number of potential firms that can produce a
homogeneous product, consumers respond quickly to price changes,
incumbent firms cannot respond quickly to entry by reducing price, and
entry into the market does not involve any sunk costs. Example - a firm could
enter on a hit-and-run basis, by undercutting the incumbent, and exiting quickly if
the incumbent reacts
Monopoly Market
• the demand curve is less than perfectly elastic, i.e downward sloping.
• This is because in order to sell more of the product the firm must reduce its price
not just on the additional products sold but also on all the other units.
• This means that marginal revenue will always be less than average revenue.
• There is a specific relationship between AR and MR,
• i.e. the slope of MR is twice that of AR.
• That is, given the linear demand function, marginal revenue curve is twice as steep
as the average revenue curve.
• Note that the slope of the demand curve or the price function equals b, whereas the
slope of MR function equals 2b.
Monopoly Market
Profit Maximization equilibrium in Monopoly
• The profit-maximizing output is given by OQ, where
MC = MR and MC is rising.
• Based on the equilibrium point, the output is
the optimum level of production i.e., OQ
quantity. The price of the commodity is
determined as OP.
• The total revenue of selling OQ quantity gives
OPBQ amount of total revenue (OQ quantity x
OP price).
• The firm has spent AC as an average cost to
produce OQ quantity and the total cost of
production is OAQC (OQ quantity x AC cost per
unit).
• Thus, the monopolist firm is given as:
Profit = TR – TC = OPBQ – OACQ
= PABC (the shaded portion
Monopoly Market
Profit Maximization equilibrium in Monopoly
• In the short run, the monopoly firm will earn profit
continuously even with various returns.
• However, a monopoly firm may not avoid a loss as long as
the AC curve lies above the demand curve. In this case
there is no output where the monopoly can cover its costs
unless such a firm is state-subsidized.
• It will not stay in business in the long run with loss, given
by (A – P )Q i.e. the shaded area of APGF
• In the long run, a monopoly firm is protected from external
competition by the barriers to entry.
• The firm is free to choose between the alternatives
whether to close down in case of losses or to continue in
the business.
• a monopolist firm may produce at under capacity, over
capacity or full capacity.
• Utilization of capacity is defined with reference to the
optimum capacity of the plant size of the firm.
Monopoly Market
Algebraic analysis of equilibrium
Example
Suppose that the demand and the total cost functions of a monopolist are and respectively. Find the
optimum quantity, price and profit on these levels.
Solution
Given: Demand function - and Cost function
Required: Profit maximization output (Q), Price (P) and Profit ( ℼ) levels?
Hence, products with more elastic demand should have a lower profit
margin.
in a perfectly competitive firm, when PED is infinite or perfectly elastic,
there will be no profit margin as P = MC
Pricing and price elasticity of demand under monopoly
2. Mark-up
• Mark-up refers to as the difference
between the price and the marginal
cost, expressed as a percentage of the
marginal cost.
It can be written as
Hence,
;
;
Pricing and price elasticity of demand under monopoly
• products with more elastic demand should have a lower mark-up.
• if PED is (-10), mark-up (MU) will be 11 percent, if PED is (-3), mark-up (MU) will
be 50 percent, and if PED is (-1), mark-up (MU) will be ∞.
• It does not follow that firms or industries with higher margins and mark-ups are
more profitable.
• A high mark-up does not necessarily indicate high profit, because it does not take into
account the level of fixed costs.
• In some industries, fixed costs and mark-ups are very high.
• For example, in the airline industry capital costs are very high and in the
pharmaceutical industry huge amounts are spent on R&D.
Pricing and price elasticity of demand under monopoly
• There arise two common misconceptions regarding monopoly firms.
• Monopolists always make large profits.
• However, monopolist firms do not always make large profits.
• In Ethiopia and other countries, you may have observed the performance of
monopolist State Owned Enterprises (SOE) making considerable losses.
• Loss is unavoidable for monopolists if their AC curve lies above the demand
curve. Unless such a firm is state-subsidized it will not stay in business in the long
run
• Monopolies have inelastic demand.
• monopolies having inelastic demand can be seen as false as a firm will always
maximize profit by charging a price where demand is elastic.
• no reason for a firm to charge a price where demand has less than unit elasticity,
in other words where demand is inelastic.
Comparison between Perfect and Monopoly Market
• both forms of market structure in the long
run on the same graph.
• It is assumed that long-run marginal costs are
constant, indicating constant returns to scale,
a. Price –monopoly price (Pm) higher than Pc
b. Output –monopoly output (Qm) is lower
than Qc
c. Profit - there is a supernormal profit in
monopoly (BCED) Whereas, the perfect
competition earning only a normal profit.
d. Efficiency –productive and allocative
efficiency.
Comparison between Perfect and Monopoly Market
• Productive efficiency –
•both the monopolist and a perfectly competitive firm are achieving productive efficiency, since
they both have a constant level of LAC.
•if the monopolist has a rising LMC, it will not be producing at the minimum point of its LAC
curve, but at a lower level.
•It will therefore not be achieving productive efficiency.
•monopolist will be producing at a small scale, less than its optimal capacity
•Allocative efficiency –
•the optimal allocation of resources in the economy as a whole.
•Using concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus.
•Consumer surplus - the total amount of money that consumers are prepared to pay for
a certain output above the amount that they have to pay for this output.
•It is given by the area between the demand curve and the price line.
•In perfect competition the consumer surplus is given by the area of triangle AFD
Comparison between Perfect and Monopoly Market
•Producer surplus - the total amount of money that producers receive for selling a certain output over
and above the amount that they need to receive to stay in the long run for all factors of production.
•given by the area between the marginal cost curve and the price line.
•Where MC is constant, producer surplus is equal to supernormal profit BCED
•the total economic welfare of a change from perfect competition to monopoly -
•In perfect competition, total welfare is maximized because output is such that price equals marginal cost.
•total welfare cannot be increased by any reallocation of resources; any gain for producers will be more
than offset by a greater loss for consumers.
•In monopoly, output is such that price exceeds marginal cost;
•consumers would value any additional output more than it would cost the monopolist to produce it.
•the size of the consumer surplus will be reduced from AFD to ACB –
•an overall loss of welfare, a deadweight loss, of CFE.
•Therefore, in terms of allocative efficiency, the monopoly causes loss of social welfare and distortions in
resource allocation. It takes away part of the consumer surplus by charging higher price than the
perfectly competitive firm.
Comparison between Perfect and Monopoly Market
• As managerial decision maker in a business, you might ask the relevance of the total
economic welfare for managerial decision-making.
• Since after all, managers are only concerned with the welfare of the firm.
• However, governments monitor monopolistic industries and take an active role in
discouraging restrictive practices that impact firms’ strategies and profits.
• Generally, monopoly is considered as an unfavourable.
• However, in industries like public utilities a monopoly may be able to produce more
output more cheaply than firms in perfect competition, since firms can avoid the
wasteful duplication of infrastructure like pipelines, railway tracks and cable lines.
• R&D and innovation, are much more important than efficiency as far as long-run
growth in productivity and living standards is concerned.
• it is not possible to estimate the incentive effects that monopoly may have on R&D
and innovation.
• Since a monopoly has the ability to profit from these over the long run, it may have
a greater incentive to conduct R&D and develop new products than a firm in PC
Exercise
1. Assume there is a tendency of moving from competitive to monopoly
output. If the demand and total functions are Q=100-2P and TC=14Q+2Q2,
respectively
a. Determine Pc, Qc, Pm, and Qm.
b. Show the equilibrium Q and P you obtained in A above graphically.
c. Calculate the CS and PS under competitive and monopoly market
structure.
d. Calculate part of CS transferred to the monopolist due to inefficiency of
monopoly.
e. Calculate the social cost (net loos or DWL) of monopoly
A. Determine the optimal level of output and price in the short run.
B. Calculate the economic profit (loss) the firm will obtain (incur).
8Q+15 = 48
B. Profit/Loss; and
C. Show in a graph
Optimal level of Q and Price;
• firms will typically operate to the left of output where LAC is minimised. This
implies that there is misallocation of resources for P is greater than the minimum
of LAC.
• If there were fewer firms, each could operate at a more efficient scale of
operation, which could be better for consumers. However, if there were fewer
firms there would also be less product variety, and this would tend to make
consumers worse off. Which of the two effects dominates is a difficult question to
answer. However, the extent of excess capacity depends on the condition of entry
and the degree of price competition. If there is free entry and active price
competition, the size of excess capacity (restriction of output) will be small.
• Another limitation of long run equilibrium of a firm in monopolistic competition is
that P > LMC implying welfare loss. To maximize social welfare, output should be
increased until P=LMC. However, this is not possible under monopolistic
competition for the perceived demand curve is downward sloping and P is greater
than the minimum of LAC.
Comparison between Monopolistic competition and Perfect competition
Market
• All firms in an oligopoly market benefit if they get together and set prices to maximize
industry profits.
• Cartel - a group of competitors operating under such a formal overt agreement
• Collusion - if an informal covert agreement is reached, the firms are said to be
operating in.
• Both practices are illegal in most countries.
• A cartel that has absolute control over all firms in an industry can operate as a
monopoly.
• The marginal cost curves of each firm are summed horizontally to arrive at an
industry marginal cost curve.
• the profit-maximizing output and the price - equating the cartel’s total marginal
cost with the industry marginal revenue curve
Oligopoly Market - Cartel Arrangements
• Profits are often divided among firms on the basis of their individual level of
production,
• other allocation techniques can be employed - Market share, production
capacity, and a bargained solution based on economic power
■ For a number of reasons, cartels are typically rather short-lived - subject to
disagreements among members.
• the long-run problems of changing products
• entry into the market by new producers,
• Although firms usually agree that maximizing joint profits is mutually
beneficial, they seldom agree on the equity of various profit-allocation
schemes.
Oligopoly Market - Cartel arrangements
• Two forms of cartel - Profit maximization cartel and market sharing cartel.
i. Cartel aiming at joint profit maximization: to set prices and outputs together so as
to maximize total industry (joint) profit not profit of individual firms.
• the firms act together to restrict output so as not to “spoil” the market.
• They recognize the effect on joint profits from producing more output in either
firm.
• consider two oligopoly firms (firm A and B) producing identical (homogenous)
products.
• The firms appoint a central agency (cartel) to which they delegate the authority
to decide on:
a) The total quantity and the price level so as to attain maximum joint profit
b) The allocation of production among the members of the cartel and
Oligopoly Market - Cartel arrangements
• The central agency has access to the cost figures of individual members
• it calculates the market demand and the corresponding MR.
• the cartel (monopoly) solution output and price levels that maximizes joint industry
profit is determined by allocating the production among firm A and B by equating the
MR to individual firm’s MC.
• MR = MCA and MR = MCB; MCA = MCB.
• So the two MCs will be equal in equilibrium.
• if one firm has lower cost (cost advantage) its MC curve always lies below that of the
other firm
• then it will necessarily produce more output in equilibrium in the cartel solution.
• this does not mean that the firm with lower cost will take the larger share of the joint
profit – it is distributed by the central agency of the cartel according to some agreed
upon criteria.
Oligopoly Market - Cartel arrangements
ii. Cartel aiming at sharing the market - the most common type of cartel.
• through Non price competition and the determination of quotas.
Non-price competition (price matching and competition)
• cartel members agree on a common price informally not by bargaining
• This implies that firms agree not to sell below the cartel price; but they can vary
the style of their products and their selling activities.
• Example - doctors charging the same price, barbers charging the same price,
gasoline stations charge the same price etc.
• These prices are not the result of perfect competition in the market.
• Rather, they result from tacit agreement upon price.
Oligopoly Market - Cartel arrangements
• Hence, competition among sellers is through advertising but not by price changes.
• However, cartel sharing market is loose or unstable than the complete cartel that aims
at joint profit maximization among manufacturing firms due to cost difference.
• the cartel is inherently unstable - a temptation to cheat by low cost firm.
• a strong incentive to break away from the cartel and charge lower price (give price
concession to buyers).
• other members from the cartel will soon discover such a cheating when they loose
consumers.
• use your customers to spy on the other firms.
• When firms are not sure that the other firm is not cheating on their agreement and selling
at the implicitly agreed price, price war (instability) may develop and the cartel splits.
Oligopoly Market - Cartel arrangements