Lecture 4
Lecture 4
comparative advantage:
Factor Endowment
theory
CHAPTER 3
Factor Endowment Theory, also known as the Heckscher-
Ohlin Model (H-O model), explains international trade
patterns based on the differences in countries' factor
endowments—such as labor, land, and capital. The theory,
developed by Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin, suggests that
countries will export goods that use their abundant and
relatively cheap factors of production intensively, while
importing goods that require factors that are scarce and
expensive domestically
•Factor Endowments: The relative abundance or scarcity of factors of production
(like labor, capital, and land) in different countries. A country might have a large
supply of labor but limited capital, or vice versa.
•Factor Intensity: Different industries or goods require different proportions of
factors of production. For instance, producing textiles might require a lot of labor but
little capital, while producing machinery might need more capital and less labor.
•Core Predictions of the Model:
•Countries that are rich in labor will specialize in producing and exporting labor-
intensive goods.
•Countries that are capital-rich will specialize in producing and exporting capital-
intensive goods.
•Factor Price Equalization: Over time, free trade in goods will lead to an
equalization of the prices of factors of production (wages, return on capital) across
countries. As countries trade, demand for the abundant factor will rise in the
exporting country, driving up wages or capital returns, while the opposite happens in
the importing country. This will narrow the wage or capital-return gap between
countries.
Assumptions:
Example:
•Country A (labor-abundant) will export labor-intensive goods, like textiles.
•Country B (capital-abundant) will export capital-intensive goods, like cars or
machinery.
Theoretical Implications:
The Heckscher-Ohlin theory helps explain why a country like China
(which has an abundance of labor) tends to export labor-intensive goods,
while a country like Germany (which has abundant capital) tends to
export capital-intensive machinery. It contrasts with Ricardian theory,
which focuses on comparative advantage due to productivity differences,
by emphasizing the role of factor endowments in shaping trade patterns.
Limitations:
•The model assumes that production technologies are identical across
countries, which is not always true.
•The "Leontief Paradox" found that the U.S., a capital-abundant country,
was exporting labor-intensive goods, challenging the predictions of the H-
O model.
When applied to U.S.-China trade, this theory highlights the different endowments of
each country:
1.United States: The U.S. is relatively rich in human capital, specifically skilled labor in
scientific, engineering, and technological fields. Thus, the U.S. tends to specialize in
producing goods that are intensive in skilled labor, technology, and innovation. Exports
to China include:
1. Aircraft, ,software, Pharmaceuticals, High-tech machinery and components (like
semiconductors and medical equipment)
2.China: China, on the other hand, has an abundance of unskilled labor but is relatively
scarce in technological and scientific expertise compared to the U.S. As a result, China
tends to specialize in labor-intensive industries, and its exports to the U.S. consist of:
Apparel, Footwear, Toys, Final assembly of electronic goods (e.g., consumer
electronics like smartphones)
Empirical Evidence: The trade patterns observed between the U.S. and China,
particularly in the early 2000s (as noted with data from 2007), align broadly with these
predictions:
•The U.S. exported products that were high in skilled labor and technology.
•China exported products that relied heavily on unskilled labor.
• However, it's important to recognize that while the general
trends fit the theory, these patterns are influenced by many
other factors such as government trade policies, multinational
corporations, and global value chains.
However, if France imports labor-intensive goods from Poland, Polish industries grow,
raising wages in Poland without the need for workers to physically migrate.
NAFTA Example: The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), signed in 1995,
aimed to reduce wage gaps between Mexico and the U.S. by boosting trade. The idea
was that economic growth in Mexico, driven by trade, would increase Mexican
workers' incomes and reduce the need for them to migrate to the U.S. While NAFTA
did help mitigate migration to some extent, other factors like high birth rates and
economic crises in Mexico kept migration levels high
Limitations and Complements to Trade as a Substitute
However, international trade and migration are not always perfect
substitutes; they may even be complements, especially in the short run:
1.Displacement from Trade: Trade can lead to job losses in certain sectors of an
economy as industries face competition from imports. Workers displaced by
trade may seek jobs abroad where opportunities are better, resulting in an
increase in migration. For instance, Mexico lost many jobs to China in the
2000s due to China's lower wage rates and competitive exports. This job loss
incentivized further migration of Mexican workers to the U.S.
2.Time Lag in Effects: While trade can help reduce migration in the long run by
equalizing resource prices and wages, the effects are not immediate. Economic
growth in developing countries through trade might take decades before
significantly reducing the incentive for migration, especially if other economic
and social challenges persist, such as high birth rates or economic instability.
Does Trade Make the Poor Even Poorer?
Immigration:
•The influx of unskilled immigrant labor increases the supply of unskilled workers, which can
lower wages in sectors that rely on such labor. As more unskilled workers enter the
workforce, the relative scarcity of skilled labor increases, driving up the wages of skilled
workers even more. This dynamic again reinforces income inequality.
Interindustry Trade:
•Nature: It involves the exchange of goods between industries, such as trading
computers for textiles or raw materials for finished goods.
•Factor Requirements: Nations with different resource endowments engage in
this trade. For instance, a country rich in natural resources exports resource-
intensive goods, while a country with skilled labor exports technology-
intensive goods.
•Comparative Advantage: This trade follows the Heckscher-Ohlin model,
where each country specializes in industries that align with its comparative
advantage, leading to the exchange of goods that have different factor
requirements.
Intra-industry Trade:
•Nature: It refers to two-way trade within the same industry, where countries
export and import similar goods. For example, the U.S. exports and imports
vehicles or computers from different manufacturers.
•Post-WWII Specialization: Intra-industry trade has become more significant
among industrialized nations, especially in areas like manufactured goods such as
machinery, chemicals, and vehicles. This trade doesn't eliminate entire industries
but rather allows countries to specialize in specific products or segments within an
industry.
•Product Differentiation: This trade occurs due to the differentiation of products
within a broad category (e.g., different car models or varieties of wines). This
allows consumers more choice and can satisfy niche market segments that might
not be catered to by domestic producers.
•For instance, U.S. consumers may prefer IBM computers, while also purchasing
Hitachi computers from Japan, or California exporting wine while importing French
Key Points of Intra-Industry Trade:
1.Similar Factor Requirements: Unlike interindustry trade, intra-industry trade
involves products that have similar factor requirements. It is mostly practiced
among industrialized nations with similar levels of development and resource
endowments, such as Western Europe.
2.Market Segmentation: Overlapping market segments, such as the preference
for luxury cars among high-income buyers, facilitate intra-industry trade,
explained by Linder’s theory of overlapping demand. Industrial countries, with
similar income levels, have similar tastes, driving this form of trade.
3.Economies of Scale: Intra-industry trade is also driven by economies of scale.
Specializing in a narrow segment of a product range (e.g., subcompact cars with
specific features) allows firms to lower costs through longer production runs,
while their foreign competitors do the same with different variations. This
specialization reduces unit costs and promotes two-way trade in similar goods.
Intra-Industry Trade vs. Interindustry Trade:
• TECHNOLGY
• INDUSTRIAL POLICY
• REGULATIONS
• TRANSPORTATION
Technology as a Source of Comparative Advantage:The Product
Cycle Theory
Regulatory Agencies:
•In the United States, agencies like the Occupational Safety and Health Administration
(OSHA), Consumer Product Safety Commission (CPSC), and the Environmental Protection
Agency (EPA) impose regulations on businesses to ensure safety standards and environmental
protection.
•Although these regulations benefit society by ensuring safer workplaces, product reliability,
and a healthier environment, they often result in higher costs for domestic producers, which
can hinder their competitiveness, especially in industries like steel manufacturing.
Impact on Competitiveness:
•U.S. steel producers, despite being technologically advanced and environmentally
responsible, face significant regulatory burdens that may impair their global competitiveness.
•Higher costs due to stringent regulations can erode competitive advantages for U.S. firms
compared to countries with less stringent regulatory requirements, such as South Korea or
China. These additional costs can make U.S. products more expensive, reducing their ability to
compete in both domestic and international markets.
Trade and Comparative Advantage: