We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 39
CHAPTER: 4
CLASSIC THEORIES OF ECONOMIC
GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT
Dr . Shereen Ahmed Abdallah
Main points: 4.1 Classic Theories of Economic Development: 4.2 Development as Growth and Linear-Stages Theories: 4.3 Structural-Change Models (The Lewis Theory of Economic Development) 4.4 The International-Dependence Revolution 4.5 The Solow neoclassical growth model 4.6 Components of Economic Growth 4.1 Classic Theories of Economic Development:
Linear stages of growth model.
Structural-Change Models
International-dependence revolution.
The Solow neoclassical growth model
4.2 Development as Growth and Linear-Stages Theories:
A) A Classic Statement: Rostow’s Stages
of Growth B) Harrod-Domar Growth Model (sometimes referred to as the AK model) 1- Linear stages of growth model A) Rostow’s Stages of Growth: The most influential and outspoken advocate of the
stages of growth model was the American
ecomomic historian Walt W. Rostow . The transition from underdevelopment to
development can be described in terms of a series
steps or stages through which all countries must proceed. Rostow’s Stages of Growth: The stage of growth model of development : 1- the traditional society. 2- the preconditions for takeoff into self- sustaining growth . 3-the take off. 4- the drive to maturity . 5- the age of high mass consumption . Rostow’s Stages of Growth: The advanced countries had all passed the stage of “ take off into self-sustaining growth “ and the underdeveloped countries that were still in either the traditional society or the preconditions stage had only to follow a certain set of rules of development to take off in their turn into self-sustaining growth . One of the principal strategies of development necessary for any takeoff was the mobilization of domestic and foreign saving in order to generate sufficient investment to accelerate economic growth. The economic mechanism by which more investment leads to more growth can be described in terms of the Harrod-Domar growth model B)The Harrod-Domar growth Model:
For all countries to grow, new
investment represent net additions to the capital stock are necessary and we assume There is a direct relationship between GDP (Y ) & Capital stock (K). B)The Harrod-Domar growth Model:
The famous equation in the Harrod-Domar theory of
economic growth, states simply that the rate of growth of GDP (ΔY>Y) is determined jointly by: 1- The net national savings ratio, s, and 2- the national capital-output ratio, c. More specifically, it says that in the absence of government, the growth rate of national income will be directly or positively related to the savings ratio (i.e., the more an economy is able to save—and invest—out of a given GDP, the greater the growth of that GDP will be) and inversely or negatively related to the economy’s capital-output ratio (i.e., the higher c is, the lower the rate of GDP growth will be). Criticisms of the Stages Model More savings and investment is a necessary condition for increasing rate of economic growth but rather it is not sufficient condition . There must be the necessary structural, institutional, and attitudinal conditions (e.g., well-integrated commodity and money markets, highly developed transport facilities, a well-trained and educated workforce, the motivation to succeed, an efficient government bureaucracy) 4.3 Structural-Change Models (The Lewis Theory of Economic Development)
Structural-change theory focuses on the
mechanism by which underdeveloped economies transform their domestic economic structures from a heavy emphasis on traditional subsistence agriculture to a more modern, more urbanized, and more industrially diverse manufacturing and service economy. one well-known representative example of the structural-change approach is the “two-sector surplus labor” theoretical model of W. Arthur Lewis (The Lewis Theory of Economic Development)
Lewis two-sector model A theory of
development in which surplus labor from the traditional agricultural sector is transferred to the modern industrial sector, the growth of which absorbs the surplus labor, promotes industrialization, and stimulates sustained development. Surplus labor The excess supply of labor over and above the quantity demanded at the going free-market wage rate. In the Lewis two-sector model of economic development, surplus labor refers to the portion of the rural labor force whose marginal productivity is zero or negative. In the Lewis model, the underdeveloped economy consists of two sectors: a traditional, overpopulated, rural subsistence sector characterized by zero marginal labor productivity—a situation that permits Lewis to classify this as surplus labor in the sense that it can be withdrawn from the traditional agricultural sector without any loss of output—and a high-productivity modern, urban industrial sector into which labor from the subsistence sector is gradually transferred. The primary focus of the model is on both the process of labor transfer and the growth of output and employment in the modern sector. Both labor transfer and modernsector employment growth are brought about by output expansion in that sector. The speed with which this expansion occurs is determined by the rate of industrial investment and capital accumulation in the modern sector. Such investment is made possible by the excess of modern-sector profits over wages on the assumption that capitalists reinvest all their profits. Finally, Lewis assumed that the level of wages in the urban industrial sector was constant, determined as a given premium over a fixed average subsistence level of wages in the traditional agricultural sector. At the constant urban wage, the supply curve of rural labor to the modern sector is considered to be perfectly elastic. Lewis makes two assumptions about the traditional sector. First, there is surplus labor in the sense that MPLA is zero, and second, all rural workers share equally in the output so that the rural real wage is determined by the average and not the marginal product of labor (as will be the case in the modern sector). This process of modern-sector self-sustaining growth and employment expansion is assumed to continue until all surplus rural labor is absorbed in the new industrial sector. Thereafter, additional workers can be withdrawn from the agricultural sector only at a higher cost of lost food production because the declining labor-to-land ratio means that the marginal product of rural labor is no longer zero. This is known as the “Lewis turning point.” Thus, the labor supply curve becomes positively sloped as modern-sector wages and employment continue to grow. The structural transformation of the economy will have taken place, with the balance of economic activity shifting from traditional rural agriculture to modern urban industry. Criticisms of the Lewis Model Although the Lewis two-sector development model is simple and roughly reflects the historical experience of economic growth in the West, four of its key assumptions do not fit the institutional and economic realities of most contemporary developing countries. First, the model implicitly assumes that the rate of labor transfer and employment creation in the modern sector is proportional to the rate of modern-sector capital accumulation. The faster the rate of capital accumulation, the higher the growth rate of the modern sector and the faster the rate of new job creation. But what if capitalist profits are reinvested in more sophisticated laborsaving capital equipment rather than just duplicating the existing capital, as is implicitly assumed in the Lewis model? In this case a process called “antidevelopmental” economic growth might happen —where all the extra income and output growth are distributed to the few owners of capital, while income and employment levels for the masses of workers remain largely unchanged. Although total GDP would rise, there would be little or no improvement in aggregate social welfare measured, say, in terms of more widely distributed gains in income and employment. The second questionable assumption of the Lewis model is the notion that surplus labor exists in rural areas while there is full employment in the urban areas. Most contemporary research indicates that there is little surplus labor in rural locations. True, there are both seasonal and geographic exceptions to this rule (e.g., at least until recently in parts of China and the Asian subcontinent, some Caribbean islands, and isolated regions of Latin America where land ownership is very unequal), but by and large, development economists today agree that Lewis’s assumption of rural surplus labor is generally not valid. The third dubious assumption is the notion of a competitive modern-sector labor market that guarantees the continued existence of constant real urban wages up to the point where the supply of rural surplus labor is exhausted. Prior to the 1980s, a striking feature of urban labor markets and wage determination in almost all developing countries was the tendency for these wages to rise substantially over time, both in absolute terms and relative to average rural incomes, even in the presence of rising levels of open modern- sector unemployment and low or zero marginal productivity in agriculture. Institutional factors such as union bargaining power, civil service wage scales, andmultinational corporations’ hiring practices tend to negate competitive forces in The fourth concern with the Lewis model is its assumption of diminishing returns in the modern industrial sector. Yet there is much evidence that increasing returns prevail in that sector, posing special problems for development policymaking that we will examine in coming chapters. The model is widely considered relevant to recent experiences in China, where labor has been steadily absorbed from farming into manufacturing, and to a few other countries with similar growth patterns. The Lewis turning point at which wages in manufacturing start to rise was widely identified with China’s wage increases starting in 2010 we must acknowledge that the Lewis two-sector model— though valuable as an early conceptual portrayal of the development process of sectoral interaction and structural change and a description of some historical experiences, including some recent ones such as China —requires considerable modification in assumptions and analysis to fit the reality of most contemporary developing nations. 4.4 The International-Dependence Revolution
The International-Dependence models view
developing countries as beset by institutional ,political and economic rigidities and caught up in a dependence and dominance relationships with rich countries . Dependence :The reliance of developing countries on developed-country economic policies to stimulate their own economic growth. Dependence can also mean that the developing countries adopt developed-country education systems, technology, economic and political systems, attitudes, consumption patterns, dress, and so on. The International-Dependence Revolution:
Dominance: a situation in which the developed
countries have much greater power than the less developed countries in decisions affecting important international economic issues, such as the prices of agricultural commodities and raw materials in world markets.
We have 3 major models :
1- The neocolonial dependence model 2- The false-paradigm model 3- The dualistic-development thesis 1- The neocolonial dependence model:
It attributes the existence and
continuance of underdevelopment to 1-the unequal international capitalist system of rich-poor countries relationships. 2- unequal power relationships which couse attempts by poor nation to be self- reliant and independent more difficult or impossible . 1- The Neocolonial Dependence Model
Neocolonial view of underdevelopment attributes a large
part of the developing world’s continuing poverty to the existence and policies of the industrial capitalist countries of the northern hemisphere and their extensions in the form of small but powerful elite or comprador groups in the less developed countries Underdevelopment is thus seen as an externally induced phenomenon, in contrast to the linear-stages and structural-change theories’ stress on internal constraints, such as insufficient savings and investment or lack of education and skills. We have to restructure the capitalist system to free developing nations from direct and indirect economic control of developed world. 2-The false-paradigm model Underdevelopment attributes due to faulty and inappropriate advice provided by international advisers in developed countries. These experts provide misleading models of development that lead to incorrect policies. Because of institutional factors such as the central and remarkably resilient role of traditional social structures (tribe, caste, class, etc.), the highly unequal ownership of land and other property rights, the disproportionate control by local elites over domestic and international financial assets, and the very unequal access to credit, these policies, merely serve the vested interests of existing power groups, both domestic and international 2-The false-paradigm model In addition, according to this argument, leading university intellectuals, trade unionists, high-level government economists, and other civil servants all get their training in developed-country institutions where they are unwittingly served an unhealthy dose of alien concepts and elegant but inapplicable theoretical models. As a result, proponents argue that desirable institutional and structural reforms, are neglected or given only cursory attention. 3-The dualistic-development thesis
Dualism :is the existence and increasing
divergences between rich and poor nations and rich and poor peoples on various levels. The coexistence of two situations or phenomena (one desirable and the other not) that are mutually exclusive to different groups of society —for example, extreme poverty and affluence, modern and traditional economic sectors, growth and stagnation, and higher education among a few amid large-scale illiteracy 3-The Dualistic- Development Thesis The traditional concept of dualism contains 4 key arguments: 1- different sets of conditions : some are superior and other are inferior .as the coexistence of modern and traditional methods of production , the coexistence of wealthy, highly educated elites with masses of illiterate poor people. 2- the coexistence is chronic not transitional .It is not due to temporary phenomenon ,in which case, time could eliminate the discrepancy between superior and inferior elements. 3- The Dualistic- Development Thesis 3- not only the degree of of superiority or inferiority fail to show any signs of diminishing but they even have tendency to increase, for example the productivity gap between the workres in developed and developing countries increased . 4- The interrelations between the superior and inferior elements are such that the existence of the superior elements does little or nothing to pull up the inferior element, In fact, it may actually serve to push it down to “develop its underdevelopment.” Criticisms of Dependence theories they have two major weaknesses: 1-although they offer an explanation of why many poor countries remain underdeveloped, they give no insight into how countries initiate and sustain development. 2- the actual economic experience of developing countries that have revolutionary campaigns of industrial nationalization and state-run production has been mostly negative. If we are to take dependence theory at face value, we would conclude that the best course for developing countries is to become entangled as little as possible with the developed countries and instead pursue a policy of autarky(A closed economy that attempts to be completely self-reliant.), or inwardly directed development, or at most trade only with other developing countries. But large countries that embarked on autarkic policies, such as China and, to a significant extent, India, experienced stagnant growth and ultimately decided to open their economies, China beginning this process after 1978 and India, after 1990. 4.5 The Solow neoclassical growth model
This model founded by Robert Solow . It
differed from the Harrod-Domar formulation by adding a second factor, labor, and introducing a third independent variable, technology, to the growth equation.
where Y is gross domestic product,
K is the stock of capital (which may include human capital as well as physical capital), L is labor, and A represents the productivity of labor, which grows at an exogenous rate According to traditional neoclassical growth theory, output growth results from one or more of three factors: increases in labor quantity and quality (through population growth and education), increases in capital (through saving and investment), and improvements in technology 4.6 Components of Economic Growth
Three components of economic growth
are of prime importance: 1. Capital accumulation, including all new investments in land, physical equipment, and human resources through improvements in health, education, and job skills 2. Growth in population and hence eventual growth in the labor force 3. Technological progress—new ways of accomplishing tasks Questions on chapter 4 1. What are the main differences between the linear stages and international dependency models of development? 2. Describe one important criticism of Rostow’s stages of economic growth theory. 3. Does it follow from the false-paradigm model that World Bank economists are intentionally trying to keep developing countries from realizing genuine development? Why or why not? 4. What are the key assumptions of the Lewis model that give rise to its conclusions? How would the theory’s conclusions differ if these assumptions do not hold?
Ending The Predatory Corporate Capitalist War on the American Middle Class: The American Entrepreneurial Alternative to Totalitarian Corporate Globalism