Perfect Competition and Monopoly
Perfect Competition and Monopoly
AND MONOPOLY
UNIT 3
Perfect Competition:
• What is perfect competition?
• A Perfect Competition market is that type of market in which the
number of buyers and sellers is very large, all are engaged in buying
and selling a homogeneous product without any artificial restrictions
and possessing perfect knowledge of the market at a time.
• According to Boulding—”A Perfect Competition market may be
defined as a large number of buyers and sellers all engaged in the
purchase and sale of identically similar commodities, who are in close
contact with one another and who buy and sell freely among
themselves.”
Characteristics/Assumptions of Perfect
Competition:
The following characteristics are essential for the existence of Perfect Competition :
• 1. Large Number of Buyers and Sellers:
• The first condition is that the number of buyers and sellers must be so large
that none of them individually is in a position to influence the price and
output of the industry as a whole. In the market the position of a purchaser
or a seller is just like a drop of water in an ocean.
• The short run means a period of time within which the firms can alter their level of output only by
increasing or decreasing the amounts of variable factors such as labour and raw materials, while
fixed factors like capital equipment, machinery etc. remain unchanged. In short run the firm’s output
supply can be changed only by the variable factors
• Moreover, in the short run, new firms can neither enter the industry, nor the existing firms can leave
it. If the demand is increased the supply can be increased only up to its existing production capacity.
• Under perfect competition, an individual firm is a price taker, that is, it has to accept the prevailing
price as a given datum. It cannot influence the price by its individual action. As a result, demand curve
or average revenue curve of the firm is a horizontal straight line (i.e., perfectly elastic) at the level of
the prevailing price.
• Since perfectly competitive firm sells additional units of output at the same price, marginal revenue
curve coincides with average revenue curve. Marginal cost curve, as usual, is U-shaped. We shall
explain the equilibrium of a perfectly competitive firm by assuming that all firms are working under
identical cost conditions.
• Now, in order to decide about its equilibrium output, the firm will compare marginal cost with
marginal revenue. It will be in equilibrium at the level of output at which marginal cost equals
marginal revenue and marginal cost curve is cutting marginal revenue curve from below.
• Since marginal revenue is the same as price (or average revenue) under perfect
competition, the firm will equalise marginal cost with price to attain equilibrium
output.
• Consider Fig. 23.2 in which price OP is prevailing in the market. PL would then
be the demand curve or the average and marginal revenue curve of the firm. It
will be seen from Fig. 23.2 that marginal cost curve cuts average and marginal
revenue curve at two different points, F and E.
• F cannot be the position of equilibrium, since at F second order condition of
firm’s equilibrium, namely, that marginal cost curve must cut marginal revenue
curve from below at the point of equilibrium, is not satisfied. The firm will be
increasing its profits by increasing production beyond F because marginal
revenue is greater than marginal cost.
• The firm will be in equilibrium at point E or output OM since at E marginal cost
equals marginal revenue (or price) as well as marginal cost curve is cutting
marginal revenue curve from below. As under perfect competition marginal
revenue curve is a horizontal straight line, the marginal cost curve must be
rising so as to cut the marginal revenue curve from below.
• Therefore, in case of perfect competition the second order condition of firm’s
equilibrium requires that marginal cost curve must be rising at the point of
equilibrium.
• Hence the twin conditions of firm’s equilibrium under perfect competition are:
• (1) MC=MR = Price
• (2) MC curve must be rising at the point of equilibrium.
• But the fulfillment of the above two conditions does not guarantee
that the profits will be earned by the firm. In order to know whether
the firm is making profits or losses and how much of them, average
cost curve must be introduced in the figure. This has been done in
next fig where SAC and SMC curves are short-run average cost and
short-run marginal cost curves respectively.
• A firm may face following situations
• Abnormal Profit, Normal Profit, Abnormal Loss and Shutdown Point.
(i) Abnormal/Supernormal Profit
• A firm will earn super normal profit in short run if its SAC is less
than the AR at the point of equilibrium. Such a firm has been
depicted in Figure.
• It shows firm’s equilibrium at point R where its output is OQ1. At
this point, both the equilibrium conditions are satisfied, i.e. MR =
MC and, the MC curve is positively sloped at the point of
intersection. The average cost of the firm, as represented by the
SAC curve, is OT (= SQ1) at this output level. Based on it,
• profit can be estimated as profit=Total revenue – Total cost
• Given that total revenue is OPRQ1 and total cost is OTSQ1,
• Profit = PTSR = OPRQ1 – OTSQ1
• This is the profit which the firm earns over and above the normal
profit and, hence, termed as super normal profit. It has been
shown by the shaded area in the figure.
• The long run is a period of time which is sufficiently long to allow the
firms to make changes in all factors of production.
• In the long run, all factors are variable and none fixed. The firms, in the
long run, can increase or decrease their output by changing their capital
equipment. Besides, in the long run, new firms can enter or exit the
industry.
• The long-run equilibrium then refers to the situation when free and full
adjustment in the capital equipment as well as in the number of firms
has been allowed to take place. It is therefore long-run average and
marginal cost curve which are relevant for deciding about equilibrium
output in the long run. Moreover, in the long run, it is the average total
cost which is of determining importance, since all costs are variable and
none fixed.
• fig. represents long-run equilibrium of firm under perfect
competition. The firm cannot be in the long-run equilibrium at
a price greater than OP in Fig. 23.6. This is because if price is
greater than OP, then the price line (demand curve) would lie
somewhere above the minimum point of the average cost
curve so that marginal cost and price will be equal where the
firm is earning abnormal profits.
• Since there will be tendency for new firms to enter and
compete away these abnormal profits, the firm cannot be in
long-run equilibrium at any price higher than OP. Likewise, the
firm cannot be in long-run equilibrium at a price lower than OP
in Fig. 23.6 under perfect competition.
• If price is lower than OP, the average and marginal revenue
curve will lie below the average cost curve so that the marginal
cost and price will be equal at the point where the firm is
making losses. Therefore, there will be tendency for some of
the firms in the industry to go out with the result that price
will rise and the firms left in the industry make normal profits.
• We therefore conclude that the firm can be in long-run equilibrium under
perfect competition only when price is at such a level that the horizontal
demand curve (that is, AR curve) is tangent to the average cost curve so that
price equals average cost and firm makes only normal profits.
• It should be noted that a horizontal demand curve can be tangent to a U-
shaped average cost curve only at the latter’s minimum point. Since at the
minimum point of the average cost curve the marginal cost and average cost
are equal, price in long-run equilibrium is equal to both marginal cost and
average cost. In other words, double condition of long-run equilibrium is
fulfilled at the minimum point of the average cost curve.
• It is clear from above that long-run equilibrium of the firm under perfect
competition is established at the minimum point of the long-run average cost
curve. Working at the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve
signifies that the firm is of optimum size, that is, it is producing output at the
lowest possible cost.
Measuring Producer’s Surplus under Perfect Competition
i. The firm earns normal profits – If the average cost = the average
revenue
ii. It earns super-normal profits – If the average cost < the average
revenue
iii. It incurs losses – If the average cost > the average revenue
Normal Profits
• A firm earns normal profits when the
average cost of production is equal to the
average revenue for the corresponding
output.
• Equilibrium in Monopoly
• In the figure above, you can see that the
MC curve cuts the MR curve at the
equilibrium point E. Also, the AC curve
touches the AR curve at a point
corresponding to the same point.
Therefore, the firm earns normal profits.
Supernormal Profits
• A firm earns super-normal profits when the
average cost of production is less than the
average revenue for the corresponding output.
• Equilibrium in Monopoly
• In the figure above, you can see that the price
per unit = OP = QA. Also, the cost per unit = OP’.
Therefore, the firm is earning more and
incurring a lesser cost. In this case, the per unit
profit is
• OP – OP’ = PP’
• Also, the total profit earned by the monopolist
is PP’BA.
Losses
• A firm earns losses when the average cost of
production is higher than the average
revenue for the corresponding output.
• Equilibrium in Monopoly
• In the figure above, you can see that the
average cost curve lies above the average
revenue curve for the same quantity. The
average revenue = OP and the average cost =
OP’. Therefore, the firm is incurring an
average loss of PP’ and the total loss is
PP’BA. In the short-run, a monopolist
sometimes sets a lower price and incurs
losses to keep new firms away.
• Summary of Short-run Equilibrium in
Monopoly
• In the short-run, a monopolist firm cannot vary all its factors of
production as its cost curves are similar to a firm operating in
perfect competition. Also, in the short-run, a monopolist might
incur losses but will shut down only if the losses exceed its fixed
costs. Further, if the demand for his product is high, then the
monopolist can also make super-normal profits.
• 1. Learner’s Measure
• It is the oldest measure and is based on the difference between the price charged by the
monopolist and his marginal cost. Bober gives the formula 1/E. Thus, degree of
monopoly power varies inversely with the elasticity of demand for the commodity.
However, the more commonly used formula is:
Degree of monopoly power = (P-MC) / P
Where P is price charged by the monopolist and MC his marginal cost.
In perfect competition,
P = MC and the formula (P-MC)/P gives zero answer indicating no monopoly power.
If the monopolized product is a free good, MC = 0 and the formula registers unity. The
index of monopoly power thus varies from zero to unity. Since monopolized goods are
seldom free, monopoly power is seldom as high as unity.
• 2. Profit-Rate as a Measure:
• J.S. Bain used profit-rate as a measure of monopoly power. By high profits, economists mean returns
sufficiently in excess of all opportunity costs which potential new entrants desire for entering the industry size
of super-normal profits which a firm is able to earn is an indication of its monopoly power. In perfect
competition, a firm earns only normal profits. In monopoly, new entrants will not normally compete away
monopoly profits. But there will be some level of profits at which new firms will find it worth taking the risk of
trying to break the monopoly.
• The stronger the monopolists position, the greater the profits he will be able to earn without attracting new
rivals
• 3. Concentration Ratio:
• Concentration ratio refers to the fraction of total market sales controlled by the largest group of sellers. The
inclusion of the market shares of several firms in the concentration ratio rests upon the possibility that large
firms will adopt a common price- output policy which may not be very different from the one they would
adopt if they were under unified management. But here difficulty arises that they may not do so. Therefore, a
high concentration ratio may be necessary for the exercise of monopoly power but it is not sufficient.
• In short, it is said that neither concentration ratio nor profit-rate are ideal measures of the degree of
monopoly power, both are of some value nor both are widely used.
Price Discrimination In Price
Under Monopoly
• A monopoly firm can charge different prices from different buyers for its
product. This act selling the same product at different prices to other buyers
is known as price discrimination, and it differentiates the pricing under
monopoly.
A monopoly that pursues the policy of price discrimination is called a
discriminating monopoly. Pricing under monopoly is different prices from
different individuals in the same market or can charge different prices in other
markets. Also, it can charge different fees based on the use of goods.
Accordingly, there may be different types of price discrimination such as
personal price discrimination, geographical price discrimination. Price
discrimination based on time and price discrimination which differentiate
pricing under monopoly frim.
Degrees Of Price Discrimination
In Pricing Under Monopoly
Price Discrimination Of First Degree
• First-degree price discrimination is where a business charges each customer the maximum they are
willing to pay, the monopoly firm may differentiate every consumer in the market in terms of price.
Pricing under monopoly may charge one price from one consumer and another price from others. It
can also set the maximum price for a consumer if the consumer is willing to pay. Thus, in the case of
the first degree of price discrimination, the consumer surplus is zero.
Price Discrimination Of Second Degree
• When a monopoly is able to sell different units of a commodity at different prices to other buyers, it
is a case of second-degree price discrimination. Electricity tariff in India is a classic example of
second-degree price discrimination.
Price Discrimination Of Third Degree
• In the case of third-degree pricing under monopoly, the firm divides the market into different sub-
markets and charges different price into other submarkets. However, the submarket where the
monopolist will charge more, the submarket where it will charge less depends on the price elasticity
of demand for the commodity produced by it in different sub-market.
Horizontal and Vertical
Integration of Firms
• There are two major forms of integration,
• i. Horizontal Integration
• Ii. Vertical Integration.
Horizontal Integration is a kind of business expansion strategy, wherein the
company acquires same business line or at the same level of value chain so as to
eliminate competition to a greater extent.
Vertical Integration is used to rule over the entire industry by covering the supply
chain. It implies the integration of various entities engaged in different stages of
the distribution chain.