Chapter 4
Chapter 4
in Human Capital
Decision Rule: r = i
• The investment criterion or decision rule appropriate to this approach
involves a comparison of the internal rate of return r with the interest
rate i. If r exceeds the market i, the investment is profitable and should
be undertaken. For example, if one can borrow funds at a 10 percent
interest rate and make an investment that yields 15 percent, it is
profitable to do so. But if r is less than i, the investment is unprofitable
and should not be undertaken.
Generalizations and Implications
Length of Income Stream
• Other things being equal, the longer the stream of post-investment
incremental earnings, the more likely the net present value of an
investment in human capital will be positive. Alternatively, the longer
the earnings stream, the higher the internal rate of return. A human
capital investment made later in life will have a lower net present
value (and a lower r) simply because fewer years of work life and,
hence, of positive incremental earnings will remain after completion
of the investment.
Costs
• Other things being equal, the lower the cost of a human capital
investment, the larger the number of people who will find that
investment to be profitable.
Generalizations and Implications
Earnings Differentials
• Not only is the length of the incremental earnings stream critical in
making a human capital investment decision, but so is the size of that
differential. The generalization is that other things being equal, the
larger the college–high school earnings differential, the larger the
number of people who will invest in a college education.
Question for review
In equilibrium, the marginal rates of return, r, for those with more ability to
extract earnings from formal education and those with less ability are equal.
So why do people with greater ability get more formal education?
Answer
The marginal rate of return, r, is indeed the same for each person at the optimal
level of education. Both r’s equal the cost of borrowing, i. But the person with
more ability has a greater r at any particular level of education, leading that
person to obtain more education than the individual with less ability.
ON‐THE ‐ JOB TRAINING
Many of the usable labor market skills that workers possess are acquired not through formal schooling but rather through
on-the-job training.
Costs and Benefits
• In deciding whether to provide on-the-job training, a firm will weigh the expected added revenues generated by the
training against the costs of providing it. If the net present value of the training investment is positive, the firm will invest;
if it is negative, it won’t. Alternatively, the firm will invest if the internal rate of return of the investment exceeds the
interest cost of borrowing.
• For employers, providing training may involve such direct costs as classroom instruction or increased worker supervision,
along with such indirect costs as reduced worker output during the training period. Workers may have to accept the cost
of lower wages during the training period.
• The potential benefit to firms is that a trained workforce will be more productive and will therefore make greater
contributions to the firm’s total revenue. Similarly, trained workers can expect higher wages because of their enhanced
productivity.
• General training refers to the creation of skills or characteristics that are equally usable in all firms and industries. Stated
differently, general training enhances the productivity of workers to all firms.
• Specific training is training that can be used only in the particular firm that provides that training. Specific training
increases the worker’s productivity only in the firm providing that training.
• The distinction between general and specific training is important for at least two reasons. First, it is helpful in explaining
whether the worker or the employer is more likely to pay for on-the-job training. Second, it is useful in understanding
why employers might be particularly anxious to retain certain of their trained workers.
CRITICISMS OF HUMAN CAPITAL
Investment or Consumption?
THEORY
• it is not correct to treat all expenditures for education as investment because, in fact, a portion of such outlays are
consumption expenditures. The decision to attend college, for example, is based on broader and more complex
considerations than expected increases in labor productivity and enhanced earnings. there is no reasonable way to
determine what portion of the expense for any particular education program is investment and what part is
consumption. Ignoring the consumption component of educational expenditures and considering all such outlays as
investment, empirical researchers understate the rate of return on educational investments. In other words, by
overstating the investment costs we understate the return on that investment.
Nonwage Benefits
• The fringe benefits associated with the jobs obtained by college graduates are more generous—both absolutely and as a
percentage of earnings—than those received by high school graduates. By ignoring fringe benefits, empirical studies
understate the rate of return on a college education. Second, the jobs acquired by college graduates are generally more
pleasant and interesting than those of high school graduates. This means that a calculated rate of return based on
incremental earnings understates the total benefits accruing from a college education.
The Ability Problem
• Critics of human capital theory contend that other things in fact are not likely to be equal. It is widely acknowledged that
those who have more intelligence, more self-discipline, and greater motivation—not to mention more family wealth and
better job market connections— are more likely to go to college. One can argue that although college graduates earn
higher incomes than high school graduates, a substantial portion of that incremental income is not traceable to the
investment in a college education.
CRITICISMS OF HUMAN CAPITAL
The Screening Hypothesis
THEORY
• Education affects earnings not primarily by altering the labor market productivity of students but by grading and labeling
students in such a way as to determine their job placement and thereby their earnings.
• It is argued that employers use educational attainment—for example, the possession of a college degree—as an
inexpensive means of identifying workers who are likely to be of high quality. A college degree or other credential thus
signals trainability and competence and becomes a ticket of admission to higher-level, higher-paying jobs where
opportunities for further training and promotion are good.