Advanced Micro
Advanced Micro
Technology
The Standard Theory of the Firm
Introduction
• This is the supply side of economy
• The supply side is viewed as composed of a number of productive
units, or firms. The firm is viewed merely as a “black box,” able
to transform inputs into outputs
• We begin by introducing a firm’s production set, a set that
represents the production activities, or production plans, that are
technologically feasible for the firm.
• The most general way is to think of the firm as having a
production possibility set, Y ⊂ RL, where each vector y = (y1, . . . ,
yl) ∈ Y is a production plan whose components indicate the
amounts of the various inputs and outputs. y ∈ Y so that yi < 0 if
resource i is used up in the production plan, and yi > 0 if resource i
is produced in the production plan.
Technology
• A technology is a process by w/c inputs are converted to an output.
Technology is typically summarized using a production function
that transforms inputs into a maximal level of output that can be
produced from a given combination of inputs.
The firm produces outputs by using inputs (both measured in
terms of flow amounts per unit time).
• Thus, the simplest and most common way to describe the
technology of a firm is the production function, which is
generally studied in intermediate courses.
e.g: A production function is given by f with values:
q = f(k; l); where k - capital, l for labor and q for output.
The set of inputs and outputs that are possible to produce using
technology f is called a production possibilities set and given
by: Y = f( -k; -l; y ) : y ≤ f(k; l); k ≥0; l ≥ 0.
• The minus signs are supposed to capture that k; l are (net) inputs
while y is an (net) output.
Production sets: Exogenously given technology applies over L
commodities (both inputs and outputs).
Production is the process of transforming inputs into outputs.
• Technological feasibility: the state of technology determines and
restricts what is possible in combining inputs to produce output.
Measurement of inputs and outputs
• This is done, for example, in labour hours per week, capital services
in hours per week, etc, and the production of output in units per
week
Specifications of technologies
– this consists of all feasible net output bundles consistent with the
constraint level z.
S
u
p
p
o
s
e
,
f
o
r
e
x
a
mp
l
e
,
t
h
a
tf
a
c
t
o
r
n
i
s
f
ix
e
d
a
t
y
ni
n
t
h
e
s
h
o
rt
r
u
n
.
– Note that Y(z) is a subset of Y, since it consists of all production plans that are
feasible-which means that they are in Y-and that also satisfy some additional
E.g. 1. Input requirement set (A special feature of a
technology)
• Suppose a firm produces only one output.
• In this case we write the net output bundle as (y, -x) where x is a vector of inputs.
• We can then define a special case of a restricted production possibilities set, the
input requirement set (restricted in the sense that the quantity of output y is
given and is only feasible in the long run):
• The input requirement set is the set of all input bundles that produce at least y
units of output.
• Note that the input requirement set, as defined here, measures inputs as positive
numbers rather than negative numbers as used in the production possibilities set.
Fig: Input requirement set
Specification (Cont’d)
E.g 2: lsoquant
In the above case we can also define an isoquant
We define also the isoquant to be the set all input bundles that allow
the firm to produce exactly y
E.g. 3: Short-run production possibilities set
Suppose a firm produces some output from labor and some kind of
machine which we will refer to as "capital.”
• Production plans then look like (y, -1, -k) where y is the level of
output.
We imagine that labor can be varied immediately but that capital is fixed
at the level k in the short run. Then
For a firm with only a single output y (and inputs -x), defined as
f (x) ≡ max y such that (y, -x) ∈ Y .
Y = {(y, -x) f: y(x)
≤ f=(x)}, in R : y free
{y assuming Y}.disposal
The production function, f, is therefore a mapping from R L+ → R+ with a
generic element y = f(x). (f : RL + → R+ ).
Specification (Cont’d)
• E.g 5: Transformation function
Let for
Activity analysis
• The most straightforward way of describing production sets or input
requirement sets is simply to list the feasible production plans.
• For example, suppose that we can produce an output good using factor inputs 1
and 2. There are two different activities or techniques by which this
production can take place:
• Technique A: one unit of factor 1 and two units of factor 2 produces one unit
of output.
• Technique B: two units of factor 1 and one unit of factor 2 produces one unit
of output.
• Let the output be good 1, and the factors be goods 2 and 3. Then we can
represent the production possibilities implied by these two activities by the
production set
If such free disposal is allowed, it is reasonable to argue that if x V (y) and x’ ≥ x then
x’ V (y).
Thus, the input requirement sets should be monotonic in the following sense
MONOTONICITY. If x is in V(y) and x' > x, then x' is in V(y).
Fig:
Convex technologies (cont’d)
A similar condition may (or may not) be imposed on the production
set Y: if y; y’ Y then ty + (1 - t)y’ Y for every 0 ≤ t ≤ 1, or Y is a
convex set.
The convexity of Y implies the convexity of V(y).
set
By definition of f (x) means: tf (x) + (1 - t)f (x0) ≤ f (tx + (1 - t)x’)
for every 0 ≤ t ≤ 1, the definition of a concave f (x).
3. Regular technologies
• REGULARITY: V ( y ) = x : y ≤ f(x) is a closed, nonempty set for
all y ≥ 0.
• The assumption that V ( y ) is nonempty requires that there is some
conceivable way to produce any given level of output.
– This is simply to avoid qualifying statements by phrases like
"assuming that y can be produced.”
The possibility set Y is closed means that, whenever a sequence of
production plans yi, i = 1; 2; : : : ; are in Y and yi y, then the limit
production plan y is also in Y . It guarantees that points on the
boundary of Y are feasible. Note that Y is closed implies
that the input requirement set V (y) is a closed set for all y ‚ 0.
Roughly speaking, the input requirement set must "include its own
boundary (closed).”
Parametric Representation of Technology
(Read Varian from page 10)
The technical rate of substitution
( x 2 / x1)
x 2 / x1
TRS
TRS
It asks how the ratio of factor inputs changes as the slope of the
isoquant changes.
– If a small change in slope gives us a large change in the factor input ratio,
the isoquant is relatively flat which means that the elasticity of
substitution is large.
• In practice we think of the percent change as being very small and take
the limit of this expression as D goes to zero.
• Hence, the expression for (sigma) becomes
• Provided that x and y are positive, this derivative can be written as:
.
Assignnment
1. Check ES for Linear, CES and Fixed proportion production
technologies
2. The Cobb-Douglas production function is
The two most important "degrees" in economics are the zeroth and first
degree .
A zero-degree homogeneous function is one for which f (tx) = f(x), and a
first-degree homogeneous function is one for which f(tx) = t f ( x) .
•A function g : R R is said to be a positive monotonic
transformation if g is a strictly increasing function; that is, a function
for which x > y implies that g(x) > g(y). (The "positive" is usually
implied by the context.)
•A homothetic function is a monotonic transformation of a function that
is homogeneous of degree 1.
• In other words, f (x) is homothetic iff it can be written as f ( x ) =
g(h(x)) where h(.) is homogeneous of degree 1 and g ( . ) is a
monotonic function. See the following figure for a geometric
interpretation.
.
Homogeneous and homothetic functions are of interest due to the
simple ways that their isoquants vary as the level of output varies.
– It is easy to verify that the CES function exhibits CRS. The CES function
contains several other well-known production functions as special cases,
depending on the value of the parameter .
– These are described below and illustrated in Figure below
• In our discussion, it is convenient to set the parameters a 1 = a2 = 1
By direct calculation of a simple CES production function, we can get
FOC:
i.e. the MRTS b/n any two inputs is equated to the ratio of their prices.
i.e. output supply & input demands can be obtained directly by simple
differentiation
Property count…
• Note that convexity says profit at average prices is less than or
equal to the average of the profits at the two prices
• Note Convexity means profit increases at an increasing rate when
output price increases.
• As shown in the fig initially, price is p* and the firm uses the
production plan (y*,x*). Suppose price of output increases. If the
firm continues to use the old production plan, i.e., no increase in
output (the resulting profit function is given by the straight line,
which is called passive profit function). But if the firm increases
output in response to output price increase, the profit function
becomes convex.
Properties of output SS and input DD functions
• Suppose that f(.) is a strictly concave satisfying all its properties and
its associated profit function, π(p, y), is at least twice continuously
differentiable. Then, for all p > 0 and w≫ 0, it is well defined:
1. Homogeneity of degree zero:
y(tp, tw) = y(p,w) for all t > 0,
xi(tp, tw) = xi(p,w) for all t > 0 and i = 1, . . . , n.
This means that if we multiply all of the prices by some t>0 , the
vector of factor inputs that maximizes profits will not change.
• It follows that firms supply of output will not change
2. Own-price effects:
Some commentaries
pD f (x*) = w.
Here
We will often assume that these functions are well-defined and nicely
behaved, but it is worthwhile considering problems that may arise
if they aren't.
Ex. If Leontief technology, no interior solutions, if there is no π max
plan (i.e. when p>w) and even when a profit-maximizing
production plan exists, it may not be unique.
The Envelope theorem (generalizes Hotelling’s
Lemma)
• The derivative property of the profit function is a special case of
a more general result known as the envelope theorem
• Consider an arbitrary maximization problem where the objective
function depends on some parameter a:
• The proof of the envelope theorem is given in Chapter 27, page 491
• Let's see how the envelope theorem works in the case of a simple
one-input, one-output profit maximization problem.
• The profit maximization problem is
This is simply the profit-maximizing supply of the firm at prices (p, w).
Similarly,
• We have just seen that the net supply functions (output supply function
and input demand functions) are the derivatives of the profit function.
• It is of interest to see what the properties of the profit function imply
about the properties of the net supply functions.
– First, the profit function is a monotonic function of the prices.
Hence, the partial derivative of (p) w.r.t price i will be negative if
good i is an input and positive if good i is an output.
– Second, the profit function is homo(1)in the prices. It follows that
the partial derivatives of the profit function ( supply & demand
functions) must be homogeneous of degree 0.
Scaling all prices by a positive factor t won't change the optimal
choice of the firm, and thus profits will scale by the same factor t.
– Third, the profit function is a convex function of p. Hence, the
Hessian matrix-must be a positive semi-definite.
But the matrix of second derivatives of the profit function is just
the matrix of first derivatives of the net supply functions.
• In the two-good case, for example, we have
This implies that in cost minimization MRTS b/n any two inputs is
equal to the ratio of their prices.
• The solution depends on the parameters w and y.
We can write x*≡ x(w, y) to denote the vector of inputs minimizing the cost of
producing y units of output at the input prices w.
The solution x(w, y) is referred to as the firm’s conditional input demand, b/c
it is conditional on the level of output y.
With two inputs, an interior solution corresponds to a point of tangency b/n the
y-level isoquant & an iso-cost line of the form
wx = α for some α > 0.
If x1(w, y) & x2(w, y) are solutions, then c(w, y) = w1x1(w, y) + w2x2(w, y).
Shephard’s lemma states that the change in cost induced by a change in the price
of an input equals the demand for that input, i.e., the direct effect of the price
change
Example: Consider a cost function in the form, c(w, y) =
From Shephard’s lemma, the conditional input demands are
obtained by differentiating w.r.t input prices:
The proportions in w/c a firm will use its inputs depend only on
relative input prices, and are independent of the level of output.
Input share: the proportion of total expenditure spent by the firm on
input i.
si≡ wixi(w, y)/c(w, y)
The input shares are always constant for the Cobb-Douglas cost
function: s1= α, and s2= β.
e.g: CRS & the cost function (how costs & inputs are related)
If the production function exhibits CRS, then the cost function should exhibit
costs that are linear in the level of output:
o if you want to produce twice as much output it will cost you twice as
much.
o If the technology exhibits CRS, then the average cost, the average
variable cost, and the marginal cost functions are all the same.
B/c CRS implies all factors are variable and AC =AVC and this
equals the constant MC
The geometry of costs
(How different costs change when output increases)
Since we have taken factor prices to be fued, costs depend only on the level
of output of a firm.
The TC curve is always assumed to be monotonic in output: the more you
produce, the more it costs.
It is often thought that, at least in the s/run, is the case where AC curve first
decreases and then increases b/c SAC = AVC+AFC, where AFC
continuously decreases with output while AVC initially decreases if there is
some initial region of economies of scale.
However, the variable factors required will increase more or less linearly
until we approach some capacity level of output determined by the amounts
of the fixed factors
The geometry of costs cont...
When we are near to capacity, we need to use more than a proportional
amount of the variable inputs to increase output.
Thus, the AVC function should eventually increase as output increases ,
The level of output at which the AC is minimized is sometimes known as the
minimal efficient scale.
If there are l/run fixed factors , the appropriate LAC curve should
presumably be U-shaped, for essentially the same reasons given in the short-
run case.
The geometry of costs cont....
The Marginal cost curve: What is its relationship to the average cost
curve?
Let y* denote the point of minimum average cost; then to the left of
y*average costs are declining so that for y y*
This inequality says that MC<AC to the left of the minimum AC point.
The geometry of costs cont...
that is, marginal costs equal average costs at the point of minimum
average costs.
Simply by changing the notation in the above argument, we can show that
1. average variable cost curve is decreasing: Marginal cost curve lies
below AVC curve
2. average variable cost curve is increasing: Marginal cost curve lies
above AVC curve
3. average variable cost curve is minimum: AVC = MC
It is also not hard to show that marginal cost must equal average variable cost
for the first unit of output.
Long-run and short-run cost curves (comparison of
costs in the two runs)
In the short run all factors cannot be adjusted in response to a change in
input prices.
Thus, short run total cost must exceed long run total cost for any output
level. Consequently, the same is also true for average costs.
Long-run and short-run cost curves…
The marginal cost curve intersects a U-shaped average cost curve at its
minimum point since,
Note that the long run average cost LAC is tangent to the short run average
cost SAC where SMC = LMC.
SAC LAC for all output levels and they coincide when the fixed factor is at
its optimal level (both on LAC and SAC curve).
At that point the curves must be tangent.
Moreover, at that point SMC = LMC since the value of adjusting the fixed
factor in response to a small change in output is zero (since it is already
optimal) by the envelope theorem.
If the technology exhibits constant returns to scale then AC=MC (in the long
run)
Long-run and short-run cost curves…
Elasticity of scale
Duality
Suppose the bundle x is choosen at prices w. Then the set of all input
bundles more expensive than this must include the true input requirement
set.
Let V*(y) be the set of input bundles that are at least as expensive as the
bundle choosen at w, for all prices w.
Duality (cont’d)