Chapter 1 Ma
Chapter 1 Ma
The consumer can divide up her life time resources among her
T remaining years of life. We assume that she wishes to
achieve the smoothest possible path of consumption over her
lifetime.
Therefore, she divides this total of W + RY equally
among the T years and each year consumes C=
(W + RY)/T.
We can write this person’s consumption
function as
C = (1/T)W + (R/T)Y.
For example, if the consumer expects to live for
50 more years and work for 30 of them, then T
= 50 and R = 30, so her consumption function is
C = 0.02W + 0.6Y
This equation says that consumption
depends on both income and wealth. An
extra $1 of income per year raises consumption
In particular, aggregate consumption depends
on both wealth and income. That is, the
economy’s consumption function is
C = aW + b Y, where the parameter a is the
marginal propensity to consume out of wealth,
and the parameter b is the marginal propensity to
consume out of income.
Implications
Implications Figure 17-10 graphs the relationship between
consumption and income predicted by the life-cycle
model. For any given level of wealth W, the model yields a
conventional consumption function similar to the one shown in
Figure 17-1.
Notice, however, that the intercept of the consumption
function, which shows what would happen to consumption if
income ever fell to zero, is not a fixed value, as it is in Figure
17-1. Instead, the intercept here is aW and, thus, depends on
the level of wealth.
This life-cycle model of consumer behavior can solve
the consumption puzzle. According to the life-cycle
consumption function, the average propensity to
consume is C/Y = a(W/Y) + b .
Because wealth does not vary
proportionately with income from person
to person or from year to year, we should
find that high income corresponds to a low
average propensity to consume when
looking at data across individuals or over
short periods of time.
But over long periods of time, wealth and
income grow together, resulting in a constant
ratio W/Y and thus a constant average
propensity to consume.
To make the same point somewhat
differently, consider how the consumption
function changes over time. As Figure 17-10
shows, for any given level of wealth, the life-
cycle consumption function looks like the one
Keynes suggested.
But this function holds only in the short run
when wealth is constant. In the long run, as
wealth increases, the consumption
function shifts upward, as in Figure 17-
11. This upward shift prevents the
Most important, it predicts that saving varies over
a person’s lifetime. If a person begins adulthood
with no wealth, she will accumulate wealth during
her working years and then run down her wealth
during her retirement years.
Figure 17-12 illustrates the consumer’s income,
consumption, and wealth over her adult life.
According to the life-cycle hypothesis,
because people want to smooth consumption
over their lives, the young who are working
save, while the old who are retired dissave.
Milton Friedman and the
Permanent-Income
Hypothesis
In a book published in 1957, Milton Friedman proposed
the permanent-income hypothesis to explain
consumer behavior.
Friedman’s permanent-income hypothesis complements
Modigliani’s life-cycle hypothesis: both use Irving
Fisher’s theory of the consumer to argue that
consumption should not depend on current
income alone. But unlike the life-cycle hypothesis,
which emphasizes that income follows a regular
pattern over a person’s lifetime, the permanent-
income hypothesis emphasizes that people
experience random and temporary changes in
their incomes from year to year.
The Hypothesis
Friedman suggested that we view current income Y
as the sum of two components, permanent income
YP and transitory income YT. That is,
Y = YP + Y T.