SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Key Factors Supporting Small-Scale
Coastal Fisheries Management
September 2013
SYNTHESIS REVIEW
THE
RockefellerFoundation
EVALUATIONOFFICE
Financial support provided by
THE
RockefellerFoundation
EVALUATIONOFFICE
About IMM
IMM is a leading research, development and consultancy group providing innovative solutions
to global development problems, by promoting inclusive policy and planning; responsive and
effective institutions for service provision; empowered, capable and innovating communities;
sustainable and equitable use and governance of the environment and natural resources; and
expanded opportunities for disadvantaged, low income and vulnerable communities and groups.
IMM specializes in building partnerships between government, civil society and communities
to provide equitable and sustainable strategies for growth and development.
About the Foundation Center
Established in 1956 and supported by close to 550 foundations, the US-based Foundation Center
is the leading source of information about philanthropy worldwide. Through data, analysis
and training, it connects people who want to change the world to the resources they need
to succeed. The Center maintains the most comprehensive database on US and, increasingly,
global grantmakers and their grants. It also operates research, education and training programs
designed to advance knowledge of philanthropy at every level. Thousands of people visit the
Center’s website each day and are served in its five regional library/learning centers and its
network of 450 funding information centers located in public libraries, community foundations
and educational institutions nation-wide and beyond.
About the Rockefeller Foundation Evaluation Office
For more than 100 years, the Rockefeller Foundation’s mission has been to promote the well-be-
ing of humanity throughout the world. Today, the Rockefeller Foundation pursues this mission
through dual goals: advancing inclusive economies that expand opportunities for more broadly
shared prosperity, and building resilience by helping people, communities and institutions
prepare for, withstand and emerge stronger from acute shocks and chronic stresses. Committed
to supporting learning, accountability and performance improvements, the Evaluation Office
of the Rockefeller Foundation works with staff, grantees and partners to strengthen evaluation
practice and to support innovative approaches to monitoring, evaluation and learning.
For this synthesis review, the Rockefeller Foundation provided financial support, the Foundation
Center was involved in project and technology development and IMM authored the report. IMM
authors included Jock Campbell, Philip Townsley, Emma Whittingham and Jessica Marsh.
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 Unported License.
Cover photo © Cristina Rumbaitis Del Rio
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
i
Tableofcontents Acronyms	iii
Foreword	v
Acknowledgements	vi
Executive summary	vii
	
1. 	 Background to the synthesis	1
2. 	 Research process and methods	3
	 2.1	 Stage 1: Study design	 3
	 2.2	 Stage 2: Formal knowledge search and screening	 4
	 2.3	 Stage 3: Informal knowledge search	 5
	 2.4	 Stage 4: Analysis and report writing	 6
3. 	 Background to coastal fisheries	7
	 3.1	 The importance of coastal fisheries	 7
	 3.2	 The state of coastal fisheries	 11
	 3.3	 The potential of coastal fisheries	 12
4. 	 Fisheries management approaches and themes	13
	 4.1	 Customary marine tenure (CMT)	15
	 4.2	 Yield maximizing approaches	 16
	 4.3	 Conservation of resources	 16
	 4.4	 Economic maximization	 18
	 4.5	 Rights-based approaches	 19
	 4.6	 Ecosystem-based management	 20
	 4.7	Co-management	 22
5. 	 Impacts	25
6. 	 Critical factors that influence success	29
	 6.1	 Some frameworks of success factors	 30
	 6.2	 Factors affecting policy and planning	 32
	 6.3 	 Factors affecting technical implementation	 51
	 6.4 	 Factors affecting community engagement	 66
		
7. 	 Discussion, conclusions and ways forward	81
	 7.1	Discussion	 81
	 7.2	Conclusions	 83
	 7.3	 Ways forward	 84
References	86
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
ii
ANNEXES		
Annex 1:	 A: Electronic database search log	 99
		 B: Institutional grey literature search log	 101
Annex 2: 	 Informal knowledge search checklist	 104
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1: 	 Principal topics and keywords search strategy	 4
Table 2: 	 Summary of formal knowledge search results	 5
Table 3: 	 Summary of the informal knowledge search	 6
Table 4: 	 Global fish production by year and source in millon tonnes	 8
LIST OF BOXES
Box 1: 	 Overfishing in Asia	 11
Box 2: 	 Reef destruction	 12
Box 3: 	 Soufrière marine management area in St Lucia	 17
Box 4: 	 Impact of marine protected areas (MPAs) in Tanzania	 18
Box 5: 	 An economic approach in practice	 19
Box 6: 	 Ecosystem-based adaptation (EbA) in the Philippines	 21
Box 7: 	 Co-management in inland water bodies in Bangladesh	 22
Box 8: 	 Assessing community perceptions of impact in Cambodia	 25
Box 9: 	 Design principles for the Peruvian anchovy fishery	 30
Box 10: 	 Wicked problems of fisheries management	 33
Box 11: 	 Examples of variables in a framework for analysing
social-ecological systems 	 35
Box 12: 	 Linkages across scales of management	 41
Box 13: 	 The Conservation International (CI) seascape approach	 43
Box 14: 	 The drivers of fish abundance	 46
Box 15: 	 Community-based coastal resource management – success or failure?	 47
Box 16: 	 Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region	 49
Box 17: 	 Management approaches for different situations	 49
Box 18: 	 Local management of lobster stocks	 52
Box 19: 	 Rights in small-scale fisheries	 53
Box 20: 	 Lessons from ICM in the Philippines	54
Box 21: 	 A sector wide approach in Cambodia	58
Box 22: 	 Certification helps community fishery in Vietnam	65
Box 23: 	 Livelihood diversification 	 69
Box 24: 	 Post-cyclone cooperation	 71
Box 25: 	 Factors influencing fish processors in India	 77
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
iii
Acronyms ADB Asian Development Bank
ASFA Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts
ASSIA Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts
CAOPA African Confederation of Small-Scale Fisheries Professional Organisations
CBO Community-based organization
CBRM Community-based resource management
CBCRM Community-based coastal resource management
CBNRM Community-based natural resource management
CBFM Community-based fisheries management
CFDO Community Fisheries Development Office of the Fisheries Administration of
Cambodia
CI Conservation International
CMSP Coastal and Marine Spatial Planning
CMT Customary marine tenure
COBSEA Coordinating Body on the Seas of East Asia
COFI Committee on Fisheries (FAO)
CRM Coastal resource management
DFID Department for International Development (UK government)
DOAJ Directory of Open Access Journals
EAF Ecosystem approach to fisheries
EbA Ecosystem-based adaptation
EBM Ecosystem-based management
ECM Ecosystem-based community management
EEZ Exclusive economic zone
FAO Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations
FiA Fisheries Administration, Cambodia
FIRME Financial Institution for the Recovery of Marine Ecosystems
GDP Gross domestic product
GEF Global Environment Facility
GSSF Guidelines for Small-Scale Fisheries (FAO)
HDI Human Development Index
ICCAS Indigenous and community conserved areas
ICM Integrated coastal management
ICSF International Collective in Support of Fish Workers
ITQ Individual transferrable quota
IUCN International Union for the Conservation of Nature
IUU Illegal, unreported and unregulated fishing
LME Large marine ecosystem
MEY Maximum economic yield
MJY Maximum job yield
MMA Marine management area
MPA Marine protected area
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
iv
MRAG Marine Resources Assessment Group
MSC Marine Stewardship Council
MSW Minimum sustainable whinge
MSY Maximum sustainable yield
NGO Non-governmental organization
OECD Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development
PAF Partnership for African Fisheries
PPP Purchasing power parity
TAC Total allowable catch
TNC The Nature Conservancy
TURF Territorial use right in fisheries
UK United Kingdom
WBFM Wealth-based fisheries management
WCS World Conservation Society
WFFP World Forum of Fisher People
WWF World-Wide Fund for Nature
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
v
Foreword This synthesis review is part of a broader collaboration between the Rockefeller Foun-
dation and the Foundation Center aimed at helping the Foundation and our partners
build more effectively on what works and what does not in a given sector. As such,
this review aims to help identify the role that the Foundation could play in small-scale
coastal fisheries.
The Foundation Center engaged Integrated Marine Management (IMM), a leading
research and development group with expertise in fisheries, aquaculture and coastal
zone management, to undertake a rapid review of key sources of knowledge (evalu-
ations, literature reviews and key informant interviews) and to identify key factors
believed to influence success in small-scale coastal fisheries management.
While there are no simple universal solutions to the problems that small-scale coastal
fisheries face, IMM was able to identify 20 key and interconnected success factors.
Identifying these factors helped the Foundation in three specific ways. First, it helped
to improve the focus of its fisheries strategy and programmatic investments. The
review provided a broad overview of the different areas of knowledge in the fisheries
and marine conservation spaces, which allowed us to narrow the focus of our grant-
making into a subset of an extremely complex, globalized and interconnected system.
Second, recognizing the contribution of many different factors in successful outcomes
for fisheries pointed the Foundation and our partners towards interventions and ap-
proaches that seek to negotiate and resolve the various tradeoffs among success
factors. For example, determining whether or not fisheries should be managed for
wealth creation, sustainability or social benefit would suggest three very different
interventions. This review helped guide the Foundation to focus on processes that
bring in various diverse viewpoints – such as co-management or a fisheries improve-
ment partnership – and work to create governance mechanisms that can resolve the
differences in those viewpoints.
Third, the review serves as an entry point for our grantees and partners to examine
their own perspectives on what works and what doesn’t with evidence from other
sectors in marine conservation and fisheries. For example, one grantee that had pre-
viously focused its work more on grassroots capacity building came to see the value
(and risks) inherent in connecting those capacity-building efforts to the markets for
seafood, which can simultaneously create and inhibit opportunity for fishermen.
We are grateful to Gabi Fitz at the Foundation Center and to Jock Campbell and his
team at IMM for their diligent and creative efforts in undertaking this synthesis
review, and to John Thomas for his capable stewardship of the synthesis process
internally at the Foundation. We look forward to continuing to build on our collec-
tive knowledge in this and other fields. It should also be noted that the 20 success
factors can be explored in detail through an interactive data visualization tool online
at fisheries.issuelab.org.
Nancy MacPherson	 Fred Boltz
MANAGING DIRECTOR, EVALUATION	 MANAGING DIRECTOR, ECOSYSTEMS
THE ROCKEFELLER FOUNDATION	 THE ROCKEFELLER FOUNDATION
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
vi
The IMM team would like to thank the following key informants who so generously
shared their time and knowledge in the development of this report: Rolf Willmann,
Gabriella Bianchi, Daniela Kalikoski, Susana Siar, Nicole Franz and Carlos Fuente-
villa at the Fisheries Department of the FAO; Simon Funge-Smith at the Regional
Office for Asia and the Pacific of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations (FAO); Peter Degen at the Mekong River Commission; Marea Hatziolos
at the World Bank; Vidhisha Samarasekara at the Asian Development Bank Office
in India; Nigel Brett at IFAD; Hary Christijanto at the Directorate of Fisheries,
Indonesia; Jim Prestcott at the Australian Fisheries Management Authority; Terrence
Phillips at the Caribbean Regional Fisheries Mechanism; Steve Gaines at the Univer-
sity of California Santa Barbara; Ray Hilborn and Chris Anderson at the University of
Washington; Daniel Pauly at the University of British Columbia; Natasha Stacey and
Dirk Steenberg at Charles Darwin University; Tim McClanahan at World Conserva-
tion Society (WCS), Mombasa; Rosie Cooney at the Sustainable Use and Livelihoods
Specialist Group at the International Union for the Conservation of Nature (IUCN);
Tundi Agardy at Forest Trends; Nicola Frost and Helen Anthem at Fauna & Flora
International; Sebastien Troeung and Kathleen Flower at Conservation International;
Julie Robinson at The Nature Conservancy, Belize; Lena Westlund, Independent con-
sultant; Naseegh Jaffer at the World Forum of Fisher People (WFFP); Vivienne Solis
Rivera at CoopeSoliDar; Gaoussou Gueye at African Confederation of Small-Scale
Fisheries Professional Organisations (CAOPA); V. Vivekandan, independent fisheries
specialist and activist; and Brian O’Riordan at International Collective in Support of
Fish Workers (ICSF).
We would express appreciation for the support and encouragement of Cristina
Rumbaitis Del Rio, John Thomas and Nancy MacPherson from the Rockefeller Foun-
dation, Gabriela Fitz from the Foundation Center and Robbie Gregorowski from ITAD.
Acknowledgements
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
vii
This synthesis review of key factors supporting small-scale coastal fisheries man-
agement was undertaken by the Foundation Center with financial support from the
Rockefeller Foundation. The work was carried out by a team based at IMM Ltd, in
Exeter, UK, from July to September 2013.
It was designed to provide an evidence base on the success factors in small-scale
coastal fisheries management in developing countries and, in turn, to assist the Rock-
efeller Foundation in developing its strategy for its Oceans and Fisheries Initiative. In
doing so, it identifies and describes some 20 key factors believed to influence success
in small-scale coastal fisheries management.
The synthesis first presents an outline of the methods used in the study followed by
a background of coastal fisheries, an introduction to fisheries management themes,
and a review and discussion of some of the critical factors that influence success. It
then offers some conclusions and possible ways forward.
The review process
This report was completed via a rapid review of key sources of knowledge from formal
published literature, institutional literature, key informants and Internet searches.
The focus was on key success factors in achieving a balance of social, economic and
ecological benefits from the management of small-scale coastal fisheries.
Background to coastal fisheries
Small-scale coastal fisheries is an important sector. It contributes very significantly
to food and nutrition security, employment, income and providing livelihoods for
many very poor people. The diversity of coastal resources creates opportunities for
these people, and the ease of becoming a fisher means that many people depend on
fisheries for all or part of their household livelihood strategies.
However, as people are often able to enter the fishery with ease, many fisheries are
over-capitalized with too much investment in fishing capacity, some are over-exploited
and their contribution to wider economic development is being poorly used. Today,
87.3 percent of fisheries are either over-exploited or fully exploited (FAO, 2012a).
These issues are compounded by a number of other human activities that result in
coastal pollution and habitat destruction, further depleting resources. Subsidies to
the fisheries sector in the past have increased the excessive pressure on resources,
and destructive fishing methods are threatening wider ecosystem functions in many
coastal areas. Growing global demand for fish by a variety of users and the penetra-
tion of global marketing chains to almost all corners of the world are also creating
incentives to over-exploit fisheries.
Climate change is also beginning to affect coastal habitats, such as coral reefs which
are under severe threat. These are some of the richest habitats and provide a wide
diversity of opportunities for coastal people.
Executivesummary
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
viii
Climate change is likely to have other effects on both the ecology and the liveli-
hoods of people who live near the coast, including increasing their exposure to
natural hazards. The climate is only one of a number of factors that are changing.
Today’s fishers are faced with fuel and food price rises, changes in demand for fish
and changes in market structures which are forcing fisheries and fisheries manage-
ment to confront issues in the much broader contexts of the wider ecology and local
and national economies.
Fisheries management
Much of the current situation of poorly managed fisheries results from past policies
and practices. On the back of historic views that fisheries could not be depleted,
national governments and intergovernmental organizations promoted the expansion
of fisheries and subsidized expansion in capital, technology and skills. The momentum
of this growth meant that fishing capacity has now expanded beyond that required
for full and efficient utilization of the fisheries.
Many different forms of fisheries management have evolved, depending on the
perceived aims of the management process. Early forms of customary marine tenure
focused on the locally controlled management of resource access and benefits. As
fisheries developed, yield maximization approaches were adopted which, in turn,
gave rise to concerns for the environment and for maximizing sustainable economic
returns from fisheries management. Thus, approaches have been added that confer
rights – individual, community and human – on the people in the sector to achieve
both efficiency and equity gains. This recognition of the wider ecological and
economic implications of poor fisheries management also has stimulated an interest
in more holistic approaches that go beyond fisheries and include ecosystem-based
approaches and integrated coastal management. Such approaches are increasingly
looking closely again at community involvement in fisheries management through
co-management arrangements, under which the community and government share
roles and responsibilities.
Impacts
The social, economic and ecological impacts of fisheries management are hard to
measure. However, in the big picture, it can be said that a balance of sustainability,
efficiency and equity goals have not been achieved. In fact, with the current state
of the world’s fisheries, most people would conclude that, overall, the management
process has largely failed.
Key success factors
In spite of this rather negative picture of the management process, there are indica-
tions that some elements of fisheries management – in some locations and under
some circumstances – have contributed to success. While there is no single approach
or management system that addresses all the problems facing fisheries management
globally, there is a growing belief that if enough of the factors affecting success are
brought together, they have the potential to reverse fisheries’ downward spiral.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
ix
This report identifies 20 of these key success factors, grouping them under three
broad headings: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical
implementation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. This division is
more for ease of presentation, as there are considerable overlaps between levels.
In many cases, these overlaps are as important as the factors themselves. The key
factors are summarized below.
Factors affecting policy and planning
These factors tend to operate at the policy and planning levels, but also can influence
what happens at the policy implementation and community engagement levels.
1.	 Embracing complexity and integration.
	 Fisheries encompass interactions among people, the environment, political and
social institutions, and markets, making for a complex system. In the past, the
focus tended to be on simplifying fisheries in order to understand them, e.g. using
single species models of management from temperate fisheries on multi-species
small-scale fisheries. However, this did not fully address the complexity of these
fisheries and the biodiversity upon which they tend to depend. These small-scale
fisheries are also very closely linked to local economies, which greatly influences
the movement of people in and out of the fishery. At the same time, this com-
plexity is rapidly changing as climate change and other global pressures affect
the way fisheries operate – all of which indicates that engaging with complexity
is becoming more urgent. If the management of small-scale coastal fisheries is
to be successful, then a greater emphasis needs to be placed on understanding
and responding to this complexity rather than externalizing it. Fisheries man-
agement must embrace that complexity and integrate with the wider local and
national economies and development process.
2.	 Addressing conflicting aims.
	 The inherent complexity of fisheries has been compounded by confusion over
the aims of fisheries management. The aims of fisheries, and therefore fisheries
management, are often diverse and mixed. Different stakeholders have different
objectives, as is often reflected in contradictory policies and management plans.
Effective means of linking the aims of the sector to the wider development aims
of resolving conflicts between different objectives and prioritizing those objec-
tives are usually lacking. This leads to confusion as to what the management
process is trying to achieve, and contributes to the lack of success of fisheries
management approaches. It is important to recognize and address these con-
flicting and contradictory aims if fisheries management is to be successful and
contribute to national development aims.
3.	 Recognizing the importance of context.
	 Part of the complexity of fisheries is that each fishery has developed within,
and responds to, the local ecology, culture, economy, social patterns and political
forces that operate around it. Efforts to seek a common solution are bound to
be frustrated by this local diversity. This does not mean that solutions cannot
be found, but they must take the local context into account. A key part of this
x
process will be the full and meaningful engagement of local communities in the
management process.
4.	 Operating at multiple scales.
	 Although the local context is important, there is also a need to understand the in-
terconnectedness of different local situations. This interconnectedness operates
through ecological, economic, social, cultural and political structures and
processes at local, national, regional and global scales. Increasingly, it is recog-
nized that working at multiple scales is needed to understand the wider context
and to accommodate it in the fisheries management process. A variety of ap-
proaches to this are being piloted and used, including large marine ecosystems
(LMEs), Seascapes, Marine Ecoregions, Regional Seas and Integrated Coastal
Management (ICM). ICM has been used most extensively in the context of
linking coastal fisheries to wider development processes, but all these approach-
es have wider and more holistic elements that attempt to integrate fisheries more
realistically with other ecological and economic development areas.
5.	 Ensuring institutional coherence.
	 Recognizing the complexity of fisheries management and the need to link
fisheries much more closely to other economic, social, ecological and political
processes at different scales indicates the importance of ensuring institutional
coherence across these processes and at different levels. This is particularly so
in terms of policy coherence, legislative coherence and the incentives provided
by policy instruments. For example, where the establishment of well-defined
rights to access fisheries resources is seen as an important part of fisheries man-
agement, it also needs to be recognized in policy and legislation at all levels.
6.	 Ensuring the viability and sustainability of ecosystem function.
	 Fisheries cannot survive if there are no fish to catch. Ensuring the viability and
sustainability of ecosystem function underpins the long-term survival of fisheries
and the benefits that flow from them. Management measures such as marine
protected areas have an important role to play in this process. However, it is
important to understand this role in terms of the local ecological as well as socio-
economic context. In particular, environmental management measures will have
different effects on different groups of stakeholders in the fishery. In many situ-
ations, fishing opportunities will decline in the short to medium term for at least
some people, and the fishers’ abilities to react will also differ. Thus, management
interventions should pay particular attention to sequencing interventions and
measures to support fishers during transition to better management.
7.	 Adapting to external pressure and change.
	 Even under the best fisheries management system, change is inevitable. This is
becoming more pronounced as climate change takes effect and the forces that
drive markets for labor, capital and fish become more globalized. In addition,
in the face of outside opportunities, local economies are rapidly changing
and coastal populations are increasing. With global media reaching even the
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
xi
most remote parts of the world, people’s perceived needs and aspirations are
changing. Adapting to all of these external pressures and changes must become
an important part of the fisheries management process. Efforts to address
change by incorporating more adaptive planning and processes into fisheries
management are increasing. This can be facilitated through greater recognition
of the inherent adaptive capacities of fishing communities and using these ca-
pacities to support greater community resilience in the face of change.
Factors affecting technical implementation
These are factors that address more of the practical implementation aspects of
fisheries management.
8.	 Establishing legal group rights and responsibilities.
	 There seems to be widespread agreement that the allocation of clearly defined
and limited rights in fisheries is essential if we are to stop further over-capitaliza-
tion of the fishery and provide a basis for rebuilding many fisheries into viable,
sustainable and equitable entities. Although there is less agreement about the
form of those rights, there is increasing recognition of the value of group-held
rights in developing countries where peer pressure can be a valuable force
for improved management. Establishing group rights and responsibilities in
fisheries can create clear incentives and a sense of commitment to making man-
agement work and stimulate a sense of responsibility for the sustainable use of
those resources. However, a group’s right to harvest can also become the group’s
right to over-exploit if adequate checks and balances are not in place. This would
suggest the importance of users and the state sharing roles and responsibilities
through some form of co-management structure. These rights should not just be
rights to harvest resources but should also include the right to a livelihood, good
health care and education, and other human rights so often unavailable to the
poor.
9.	 Incrementally changing to allow for capacity, reflection and negotiated
response.
	 Changes in both policy and policy implementation will require substantial
changes: in the way fisheries are managed; in the skills, attitudes and knowledge
for management; and in new institutional structures, processes and linkages that
can facilitate that change. This will require both the courage to make significant
changes in what is often a knowledge vacuum, and the humility to accept that
other groups of people may have something important to say about fisheries
management – including the young, the old, women, processors, traders and
shopkeepers. Such massive changes cannot occur quickly, they need time for
reflection, experimentation, negotiation and acceptance. It is important to adopt
change incrementally to assist this process and provide space for change.
10.	 Institutional fit and subsidiarity.
	 This change process also requires allocating institutional roles and responsibili-
ties at different levels, although decisions should ideally be made as close to the
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
xii
fishery as is possible while remaining effective. This will often link closely with
the administrative devolution processes increasingly being adopted in develop-
ing countries. Getting the right institutional fit and the right level of subsidiarity
for different roles and responsibilities is important, as is recognizing that it is an
iterative and adaptive process that evolves over time.
11.	 Incorporating politics and political choices.
	 In the past, many of the political influences on fisheries were externalized and
left unresolved. Even today, fisheries management remains a contested area,
with access and benefits often decided for political reasons, some for the public
good, others for the private benefit of politicians or other powerful elites. In-
corporating politics and political choices into the planning and implementation
of fisheries management is important for achieving a balance between social,
economic and environmental objectives. It is also important for gaining access
to government funding and support for implementing change, and for achieving
coherence between national development policies and sector policies.
12.	 Sustainably and equitably addressing costs and benefits.
	 Even when there is a budget and political commitment for reform, it is still
important to implement management efficiently and to share the costs and
benefits of fisheries management in ways that are fair – and seen to be fair. Ad-
dressing costs and benefits sustainably and equitably is vital if fisheries man-
agement is to gain support from the community and wider society. However, at
present, the understanding of costs and benefits is poorly documented. More
needs to be done to improve understanding in order to allow informed decisions
at all levels, such as by investigating the role of fishers in the funding of the
management process based on the improved gains and how that links into local
economic growth.
13.	 Getting market measures right.
	 There is potential for the markets to improve the livelihoods of fishers through
better returns for fish caught sustainably and equitably. With the public’s in-
creasing awareness of the damage poorly managed fisheries can inflict on coastal
ecosystems, their willingness to pay for such damage is being tested through
certification schemes and eco-labeling. However, changes in the way fish har-
vesting is carried out generally has costs, particularly for producers, making
it important to introduce these market-driven measures in support of better
fisheries management in the correct sequence and in ways that avoid having
adverse effects on poor and vulnerable producers. Given women’s important
role in fish processing and trade, it is important that they are fully engaged in all
decision-making around this and other fisheries management decisions.
Factors affecting community engagement
These factors are concerned with engagement at the community and household
levels. They will influence, and be influenced by, technical implementation factors
and those concerned with policy and planning.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
xiii
14.	 Understanding dependency.
	 A key factor that affects the way people behave in response to management
decisions is their level of dependency on the resource. Some people are full-time
fishers and have no other income source. Others are part-time or seasonal
fishers, or use the resource as a safety net. For many poor people, fisheries will
be part of a portfolio of household livelihood activities which may involve more
than one household member. Understanding how different stakeholder groups
depend on the fishery is essential to ensuring fair and sustainable management
decisions.
15.	 Balancing exclusion, livelihoods alternatives and the local economy.
	 Ultimately, fisheries management decisions will involve some people being
included in the right to fish and some being excluded. Those excluded may be
current fishers or future generations that may wish to join the fishery. There
need to be alternative livelihood options for those who are excluded because,
otherwise, they are likely to become impoverished or will try to circumvent entry
regulations. Fisheries are generally closely linked to the local economy in which
they operate, making it essential that they become a well-integrated part of the
local economic development process. Getting the right balance among exclusion,
alternative livelihoods and local economic growth is important to the sustainable
and equitable development of small-scale fisheries. It is also important to get the
sequencing of decisions around controls over entry requirements and livelihood
alternatives right.
16.	 Building capacity.
	 If fishing communities are to play a greater role in both decision-making and
management implementation, then many will also need support in building their
capacity to take on these new roles. Good leadership skills are essential, especial-
ly those which encourage inclusiveness and negotiation. Bringing communities
together to work in collaboration is important, as is clearly defining what their
roles and responsibilities are under the law and how far they extend geographi-
cally. Ensuring that the poor are fully included in this process is important.
17.	 Engaging with fishers’ motives and preferences.
	 While many assumptions have to be made about the social, economic and ecolog-
ical development factors surrounding fisheries management, perhaps one of the
most important areas of knowledge to get right is understanding and engaging
with fishers’ motives and preferences. Many fisheries management efforts have
gotten into trouble because managers have made assumptions about the way
fishers will behave that have proved to be wrong. For example, considerable
conflict arises over time preference – fishers, managers, politicians and funders
all have different time horizons and meshing them is particularly difficult.
18.	 Addressing commitment, compliance, conflict and enforcement.
	 Addressing many of the factors above will encourage a greater commitment
of fishers to the management process. However, there also will be a need to
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
xiv
address compliance, conflict and enforcement in order, for example, to enforce
regulations quickly and effectively, and to develop conflict resolution processes.
A greater emphasis on co-management of small-scale coastal fishers is likely to
increase group pressure to comply, but enforcement is likely to remain with gov-
ernment and must be recognized as effective.
19.	 Ensuring participation and inclusion.
	 Implicit in all of these factors is a greater level of participation and inclusion of
fishers and their wider communities in decision-making around fisheries man-
agement. This should include fish traders and processors, money lenders, gear
suppliers and those responsible for wider community and local economic devel-
opment. Men and women, the poor and the well-off, the old and the young, ethnic
and religious groups, all have different perspectives and need to be involved.
This will make for more representative decision-making while also supporting a
more empowering process.
20.	 Linking different knowledge management systems.
	 An important part of inclusion is recognizing the value of both traditional eco-
logical knowledge and experience-based knowledge in the management process.
A sharing of roles and responsibilities across formal and informal systems of
knowledge generation, sharing and use is likely to reduce costs and, at the same
time, increase the relevance of knowledge used. The linking of knowledge man-
agement systems will provide a very important reflection of mutual trust and
cooperation.
Discussion, conclusions and ways forward
As this research has shown, there is no simple universal cure for the problems that
small-scale coastal fisheries face in many developing countries. It is likely that this
is also true for fisheries more generally. However, this does not mean that fisheries
cannot achieve a much more balanced equitable and sustainable trajectory into the
future. The 20 factors identified in this report could help to achieve this, and there
are doubtless others that would emerge from a more comprehensive study. Already, a
number of these factors are starting to combine and to have a positive effect in some
fisheries. There is also increasing recognition that a greater emphasis on getting the
process right for specific contexts, rather than adopting a uniform approach for all
fisheries, is likely to lead to better outcomes.
Efforts to distill some of these factors into principles for management began with the
Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries. The specific needs of small-scale fisheries
that go beyond the Code have been progressively recognized and the United Nations
Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) is currently producing the International
Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-Scale Fisheries which address many of
the emerging issues associated with fisheries management. These Guidelines are
intended to enhance the contribution of small-scale fisheries to poverty alleviation,
food security and economic growth.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
xv
It is important to recognize that achieving success in fisheries management will take
a long time, a substantial financial commitment, enhanced sharing of knowledge and
experience, political support and a commitment to building capacity at all levels.
© Roberto Faidutti
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
1
1
1.	 Background to the synthesis
As part of its new model of operation, the Rockefeller Foundation is undertaking
synthesis reviews to strengthen its knowledge and evidence base of what works and
what does not work in its key areas of interest. The primary purpose of synthesis
reviews is to enable Foundation initiative teams and their grantees to build on what is
known, avoid the pitfalls of others and add value to the area of endeavor by not dupli-
cating efforts.
The Foundation’s Oceans and Fisheries Initiative aims to determine effective ways to
integrate natural ecosystems into their economic and social systems. Research under-
taken by the Foundation shows that oceans are in a state of crisis due, in large part,
to rampant overfishing that has occurred for several decades. Millions of people, par-
ticularly the poor and vulnerable who depend on the productivity of marine resources
for their food security and livelihoods, are seeing these eroded because of declining
ocean health. Efforts to emphasize resource conservation and sustainable manage-
ment while addressing the social and economic vulnerabilities of fishing communities
will have high potential to deliver joint benefits for ecosystems and for people. The
Foundation’s body of work aims to shift paradigms in the environmental community
in order to incorporate powerful new approaches including innovative financing, ap-
proaches and diffusion, and more purposeful planning for scale.
Oceans and Fisheries is a new Initiative in Development for the Rockefeller Founda-
tion. Consistent with the Foundation’s operating model, the dual objectives of Initia-
tives in Development are to quickly synthesize a wide variety of knowledge to inform
internal decision-making for larger-scale investment while contributing significant
public goods to the field, regardless of the Foundation’s potential future investment
in this space. In its Search process (the stage prior to Development), the Foundation
explored the potential for grant making in the areas of fisheries, aquaculture, poverty
and food security as a means of improving the lives of poor and vulnerable populations.
In addition to generating significant knowledge, the results of the Search concluded
that this area of work had significant potential. As a result, the Foundation approved a
15-month Initiative in Development spanning late March 2013 until April, 2014.
To learn quickly from existing knowledge in the field, the Initiative team wished to
learn from “a synthesis of knowledge and evidence of critical success factors for in-
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
2
terventions aimed at improving natural resource management and their potential scal-
ability, with a particular emphasis on the field of coastal/near shore fisheries manage-
ment and the links to poor, vulnerable, or marginalized populations” (the Rockefeller
Foundation, internal document). The objectives for this synthesis are built upon the
Foundation team’s latest understanding of the field and, to the extent of its knowledge,
reflect insufficiently studied areas of inquiry. Its focus is on integrating the socio-
ecological factors in the management of coastal small-scale fisheries in developing
countries and their effects and impacts.
Thus, in order to undertake a rapid review1
of key formal and informal knowledge
sources and identify factors influencing the success, failure and potential scalability
of fisheries management that combine ecological and socio-economic objectives, this
report:
•	 synthesizes key lessons from past and on-going ecosystem-based community
management efforts and programs, with a focus on fisheries and, where possible,
other sectors
•	 identifies key insights in terms of factors contributing to the success and failure of
ecosystem-based community management (ECM) and their implications for the
Foundation’s work
•	 provides a preliminary assessment of critical success factors for their potential to
be catalytic in achieving (or inhibiting) impact at scale
•	 identifies outliers of interest to the Foundation
•	 identifies key players and their areas of expertise in relation to key lessons.
It focuses on the lessons learned regarding key success factors from past and ongoing
work on managing small-scale fisheries in developing countries to achieve a balance
between social, economic and environmental benefits in sustainable and equitable
ways, and presents a synthesis of the lessons emerging from the key documents
reviewed and interviews held around this area of work.
The report starts with an outline of the methods used in the synthesis work. This
is followed by a background section on coastal fisheries, an outline of key fisheries
management approaches and the impacts that fisheries management has had. It then
identifies 20 critical factors that influence success in coastal small-scale fisheries
management. These factors are reviewed at three levels: i) factors affecting policy
and planning, ii) factors affecting technical implementation and iii) factors affecting
community engagement. These factors are then discussed, conclusions drawn and
ways forward briefly outlined.
1
	 The study took place over a 10-week period from July to September 2013.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
3
2
2.	Research process and methods
Theresearchprocesswasorganizedintofourstages:studydesign,
formal knowledge search and screening, informal knowledge
search, and analysis and report writing. The elements of each
stage are outlined in the sections below.
2.1	 Stage 1: Study design
The study design was developed from Terms of Reference (TORs) drafted by the
Rockefeller Foundation and based on an analysis of knowledge gaps around fisheries
management that needed to be addressed to inform its development strategy for en-
gagement with the sector. On the basis of the TORs, IMM’s research team prepared
a research protocol. The study design outlined in the research protocol proposed a
search strategy focusing on both formal and informal knowledge sources.
Formal knowledge search
This search focused on documented knowledge from two key areas: academic peer
review literature and institutional grey literature.
The academic literature search was based on five electronic reference databases:
•	 Web of Knowledge: Web of Science
•	 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts (ASFA)
•	 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts (ASSIA)
•	 Directory of Open Access Journals (DOAJ)
•	Scirus.
The institutional grey literature search was carried out using institutional website
search engines and online library databases. To guide the search, an institutional
map was developed of key institutions likely to be involved in the areas covered by
the synthesis. These included academic institutions, donors and funding agencies
(including foundations), intergovernmental agencies, regional fisheries management
organizations and NGOs.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
4
Informal knowledge search.
This search focused on the experiential knowledge of key informants working in the
field of fisheries management. Key informants were also asked to identify important
formal knowledge resources, which were obtained through online searches or sent
directly to us by the informant.
2.2	 Stage 2: Formal knowledge search and screening
Keyword search strategy
The search of formal knowledge sources applied a keyword search strategy based on
the principal topics of relevance to this synthesis (see Table 1).
TABLE 1: Principal topics and keywords search strategy
TOPIC 1
AND
TOPIC 2
AND
TOPIC 3
Fish*
Ecosystem
Natural Resource
*Manage*
Community-based
Adaptive NEAR *manage
Coast*
* / AND / NEAR represent Boolean search operators
Initially searches combined Topic 1 and 2 keywords and applied this strategy to the
whole document. To further narrow the search (for searches yielding over 6,000
results), Topic 3 was applied. Then if necessary, the search was applied to fewer
document fields (e.g. title or abstract). Once a search yielded less than 6,000 results,
it was exported to EndNote, a library software package.
The keyword search strategy was applied consistently to all five electronic reference
databases. Where possible this strategy was also adopted for the institutional grey
literature search. However, if a searchable library database was not available, a
manual search of publication lists for relevant topics (e.g. fishery management and
governance, co-management, ecosystem approach to fisheries) was undertaken. In
total, 26 institutional websites were searched. In addition, the IMM office library and
reference libraries of team members were searched to identify additional grey litera-
ture that, from experience, was considered useful.
All searches were recorded in a search log which indicated the number of results for
each search and which searches were downloaded into EndNote (see Annex 1).
Inclusion criteria
An initial set of inclusion criteria, developed to ensure the documents compiled for the
review were accessible and relevant, included:
•	 YEAR OF PUBLICATION: the study must be published in or after 1990
•	 LANGUAGE: the study must be published in English
•	 GEOGRAPHIC RELEVANCE: the study must be based on evidence from developed
countries
•	 TOPIC RELEVANCE: the study must pertain to management initiatives and factors of
their success/failure in relation to coastal marine fisheries, including articles that
examined relevant management concepts or theories.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
5
For the institutional grey literature searches, documents were screened for inclusion
criteria based on their title, and only those meeting the criteria were exported to
EndNote. In total, 141 accessible and relevant documents were identified from the
institutional grey literature search. Further grey literature documents were identified
from the IMM and team libraries.
For the academic literature searches, the year of publication criteria was combined
with the initial keyword search. In total, 16,923 academic references were compiled
from the five electronic databases. Of these, 7,304 were identified as duplicates and
removed, leaving a library of 9,619 documents to be screened for language and
relevance inclusion criteria.2
Inclusion screening was applied to the title and abstract of each document. A coding
system was used during screening to identify the reason for exclusion. This provided
an outlier library resource, containing documents which may have potential insights
for the synthesis but may be outside the geographical relevance (e.g. developed
country) or topic relevance (e.g. inland fishery or forestry management). Following
inclusion screening, a total of 1,166 documents were identified as accessible and
relevant for the synthesis.
Included academic literature documents were further screened to identify documents
of particular relevance to the synthesis. These included overviews or reviews of
fisheries management initiatives at multiple sites. In total, 195 documents were identi-
fied as key documents, with snowball sampling from citation lists of key documents
also yielding further documents.
The overall formal knowledge search and screening yielded 1,379 relevant documents
for review, as summarized in Table 2.
TABLE 2: Summary of formal knowledge search results
ACADEMIC LITERATURE SEARCH RESULTS
Keyword search
results
Included
documents
Key documents Excluded:
Developed country
Excluded:
Relevant off topic
9,613 1,166 195 2,940 1,045
GREY LITERATURE SEARCH RESULTS
Website search results IMM library search & snowball sampling
150 63
2.3	 Stage 3: Informal knowledge search
From the institutional grey literature search and from the research team’s experience
of the sector, a number of key informants were contacted to take part in semi-struc-
2
	 Due to the export functionality of the Directory of Open Access Journals (DOAJ) and Applied Social Sciences
Index and Abstracts (ASSIA) databases, inclusion screening for language and relevance criteria was carried
out as documents were exported to EndNote. This yielded 45 documents.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
6
tured interviews. Interviews were conducted in person, by telephone or email, and
were guided by a checklist of topics and questions (see Annex 2).
In total, the team contacted 55 individuals, of whom 20 were interviewed and 4 replied
to an email checklist, as summarized in Table 3 below. Approximately half of those
contacted were unavailable, or failed to respond, which may be explained by the fact
that the synthesis was conducted during a holiday season.
TABLE 3: Summary of the informal knowledge search
INSTITUTIONS CONTACTS
MADE
INTERVIEWS CONDUCTED
In person Telephone Email
Intergovernmental/multi-lateral organizations 7 2 - 1
International development banks 3 - 3 -
Government organizations 2 - 1 1
Regional fisheries management organizations 3 - - 1
Research institutions 18 - 5 -
Non-governmental organizations 15 - 6
Fisher organizations 7 - 3 1
2.4	 Stage 4: Analysis and report writing
Analysis of documents initially focused on the full text of key documents identified
from the academic literature search. As the review progressed, documents identi-
fied through snowball sampling of citation lists and from the institutional grey litera-
ture search were also analyzed. This analysis revealed a number of preliminary key
success factors, which were reviewed and revised to fit more closely to the available
evidence as the analysis developed. These factors were finally grouped into three
areas: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical implemen-
tation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. This analysis was cross refer-
enced against the results of the informal knowledge search in order to triangulate the
results. This provided the basis for the report’s results and discussion.
Given that the study had only two months to complete the search and analysis, only
a limited number of documents could be reviewed in the time available. Ultimately,
the scope of knowledge included in the report reflects the limitations imposed by
this time schedule. In total, approximately 170 documents were reviewed. As such, it
is recognized that a continued review of the formal knowledge search results would
reveal additional information that may be of benefit. However, the level of repetition in
the results suggests that the synthesis represents an acceptable level of convergence
of thought.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
7
3
3.	 Background to coastal fisheries
This section provides a brief summary of the global fisheries
sector: its importance, its current state, the effectiveness of
fisheries management measures and the potential of the sector.
The coastal environment is one of the most diverse parts of the planet with many
ecosystems and species. This diversity, combined with the dynamic and changing
nature of coasts, creates conditions for the provision of a wide range of ecosystem
services which benefit humans as individuals and societies including: food from fish,
building materials from reefs and mangroves, storm protection for coastal communi-
ties, medicines and cultural traditions, as well as wider regulatory support services.
Fish are harvested from all coastal countries throughout the world. In developing
countries, fisheries are particularly important for providing food and nutrition security,
income and employment. The diversity of species and habitats in coastal areas provides
a range of opportunities for the livelihoods of men, women and children, and the open
access nature of many resources provides opportunities for the poor.
However, the vital role of coastal ecosystem services is being undermined by over-fish-
ing, habitat destruction and pollution. As a consequence, many of the world’s fisheries
are at, or beyond, their sustainable limits of harvesting. Fisheries management has been
used to try to halt or reverse this adverse situation, but overall it has failed to improve
matters significantly. If fisheries can be successfully managed, then their potential con-
tribution to food, employment, foreign exchange generation and poverty reduction can
be both large and sustainable. This is discussed in more detail below.
3.1	 The importance of coastal fisheries
The coast is one of the most ecologically diverse ecosystems – a diversity that creates
many livelihood opportunities for different groups of people. Because of the relatively
open access nature of coastal fisheries and the low cost of entering, these opportuni-
ties attract many poor people into the fishery and, in turn, the fishing supports many
different forms of livelihoods for different groups of people. The main attraction of the
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
8
coastal waters is the ability to harvest fish for food and to sell, but this is only part of
the engagement of the community with the coastal system.
Fisheries ecology
The sea covers 71 percent of the surface of the earth and constitutes 96.5 percent
of all water by volume. It is one of the most biologically diverse parts of the planet
in terms of both ecosystem diversity and species diversity. Much of that diversity is
concentrated in coast fringes where small-scale fisheries often operate (Campbell and
Beardmore, 2001). Key habitats include:
•	 open sea	
•	 deep ocean floor
•	 continental slopes
•	 sea mounts
•	 mud/sand banks
•	 inshore coastal areas
•	 coral reefs
•	mudflats
•	 sandy beaches
•	 kelp forests
•	estuaries
•	mangroves
•	deltas
•	lagoons
These different habitats are often mutually supporting with, for example, reefs
providing shelter for sea grass areas and sand for beaches. The habitats also link
the different lifecycles of fish, some as nursery areas and others as adult feeding
and breeding areas. Connectivity between these is important in the wider ecological
balance.
Although coral reefs cover less than 0.1 percent of the ocean (250,000 km2
), they are
the most productive and biologically rich ecosystems on earth with around 25 percent
of all known marine species (Burke et al., 2011). They occur mainly in coastal areas
where fisheries are particularly important.
Fish production
The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) monitors the
world’s fisheries on a regular basis. Capture fisheries and aquaculture supplied
the world with an estimated 154 million tonnes of fish in 2011 (with a total value of
$217.5 billion), of which about 131 million tonnes was utilized as food for people
(FAO, 2012a) (See Table 4). Fish production maintained a growth rate of 3.2 percent
per year in the period 1961–2009, outstripping population growth.
TABLE 4: Global fish production by year and source in millon tonnes
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
CAPTURE
Inland 9.8 10 10.2 10.4 11.2 11.5
Marine 80.2 80.4 79.5 79.2 77.4 78.9
Total 90.0 90.3 89.7 89.6 88.6 90.4
CULTURE
Inland 31.2 33.4 36 38.1 41.7 44.3
Marine 16.0 16.6 16.9 17.6 18.1 19.3
Total 46.3 49.9 52.9 55.7 59.9 63.6
TOTAL WORLD PRODUCTION 137.3 140.2 142.6 145.3 148.5 154.0
Source: FAO, 2012a
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
9
Table 1 shows that while wild capture fisheries have remained relatively static in recent
years, aquaculture has grown considerably. Aquaculture now makes up 41 percent of
total fish availability compared with 51 percent from marine capture fisheries (FAO,
2012a).
The global fishing fleet is comprised of 4.36 million vessels, of which 74 percent work
in marine fisheries. Asia has the largest fleet with 73 percent, Africa has 11 percent
and Latin America and the Caribbean has 8 percent (FAO, 2012a).
Food and nutrition security
World per capita food fish supply increased from an average of 9.9 kg (live weight
equivalent) in the 1960s to 18.4 kg in 2009 and is set to increase further (FAO, 2012a).
In 2010, fish production provided a global fish consumption rate of 18.7 kg/person/
year with consumption rates varying across the globe from 9.1 kg/person/year in
Africa to 24.6 kg/person/year in Oceania. Fish makes up 16.6 percent of all animal
protein consumed and 6.5 percent of all protein consumed by people. Globally, fish
provides about 3.0 billion people with almost 20  percent of their intake of animal
protein, and 4.3 billion people with about 15 percent (FAO, 2012a). Fish also provide
other benefits such as micro-nutrients (MRAG et al., 2013) that are particularly
important in the diets of the poor.
In most developing countries, fish is sold mainly in live or fresh form (representing
56  percent of fish destined for human consumption in 2010). Cured forms of fish
(dried, salted, smoked or fermented) still remain important in developing country
markets, although the share of fish that is processed is declining (FAO, 2012a).
Fish and fishery products are among the world’s most traded food commodities.
In 2010, fishery trade represented about 10  percent of total agricultural exports
(excluding forest products) and 1 percent of world merchandise trade in value terms
(FAO, 2012a).
Fisheries livelihoods and poverty reduction
There are some 54.8 million people involved in the production of fish. An estimated
660–820 million people, or 10–12  percent of the global population, depend upon
fisheries and aquaculture for their livelihoods: 87 percent of them in Asia, 7 percent in
Africa and 3.6 percent in Latin America and the Caribbean (FAO, 2012a). Of the people
directly employed in capture fisheries (production and processing), 97 percent live in
developing countries and 90 percent work in small-scale fisheries (Hall and Andrew,
2011). It is thought that, on average, 30 percent of people employed in fisheries overall
are women mainly in fish processing and trade (FAO, 2012a).
Many of the people involved in small-scale fisheries in developing countries are poor,
marginalized or vulnerable to adverse change. According to Pomeroy (1994, 3),
“[i]n many parts of the world, rights to common property are all that separate the
poor from destitution.” While many of these people are poor, vulnerable and margin-
alized, an important question is “are they poor because they are fishers, or are they
fishers because they are poor?” (Béné, 2003). The answer is complex and is probably
a mixture of both.
10
Coastal fishers live in one of the most dynamic and contested parts of the world where
risk is a part of their livelihood strategies (Campbell et al., 2006). This creates oppor-
tunities for poor people that others may consider too costly or unpredictable, but it
also creates threats to life, assets, income and savings, which means there is consider-
able movement into and out of poverty in fishing communities.
Fishers often live adjacent to areas of high biological diversity which creates a
diversity of opportunities to employ different combinations of labor, skill, experience-
based knowledge, capital, technical knowledge, risk-avoidance strategies, market
knowledge and access, and seasonal time allocation (Campbell and Townsley, 2013).
This diversity often, at least initially, reduces competition from other fishers that
require the economies of scale afforded by less ecologically diverse environments.
Increasingly, however, such biological diversity is attracting tourism which offers both
threats (land acquisition, pollution, habitat destruction) and opportunities (markets
for seafood, alternative employment opportunities). Where barriers to entry are low,
such as open access fisheries, where there is low competition or where entry requires
little investment in, e.g. skills or equipment, poor people can often find niches as in-
dividual fishers or as hired crew. While there is high gender differentiation in most
fisheries (generally with men catching fish and women processing and trading),
some habitats, such as coral reefs, provide opportunities for women to glean food for
domestic consumption or trade, an activity which often provides an important social
and cultural function (Whittingham et al., 2003). In addition, women in many parts of
the world play an important role in owning and financing fishing operations.
However, while open access coastal fisheries attract poor people, they often remain
poor, because:
•	 they have inherent risks working in such difficult environments, where catch pre-
dictability is low
•	 they have few enforceable rights over land and fish resources
•	 they have competition in harvesting combined with pollution, habitat destruction,
increasing climate change and decreasing catches
•	 they may be marginalized to poorer parts of the fishery or excluded at certain
times
•	 they are dealing with highly perishable products, where market access is difficult
and market knowledge poor
•	 their investment in boats, gear, fuel and labor is often dependent on loans from
middle men and women who are able to charge high costs for their services
•	 their lack of rights over land and access to fisheries resources (especially for the
very poor, migrant workers, certain classes and castes of people, and ethnic mi-
norities) often means that their activities fall outside of the law and the decision-
making processes (Béné, 2003; Campbell et al., 2006).
For small-scale processors and traders, increasing competition for supply, changing
market and quality-control demands, concentration of landings in fewer landing sites,
and changes in investment levels in processing and trade are often leading to signifi-
cant shifts in the structure of the post-harvest fisheries sector – changes that often
marginalize small-scale operators. In some areas where women previously played key
roles in post-harvest fisheries, more men may be found entering processing and trade,
which is leading to reduced opportunities and increased competition for small-scale
female traders and processors (IMM and ICM, 2003).
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
11
3.2	 The state of coastal fisheries
There can be little doubt that the world’s fisheries are in suboptimal condition (see
Box 1). In 2009, 29.9 percent of global fish stocks were overexploited, 57.4 percent
were fully exploited and 12.7 percent were not-fully exploited (FAO, 2012a). Most of
the fully exploited stocks are at their maximum sustainable yield (MSY) and therefore
not achieving their full economic potential. FAO (2012a, 200), in its analysis of global
fisheries in 2012, stated that the results “are troubling from a resource exploitation
perspective and suggest a global system that is overstressed, reducing in biodiversity
and in imminent danger of collapse.”
In addition, many key ecosystems on which the health of marine fisheries depend are
being degraded. Mangrove forests have been widely depleted and, over the past 50
years, approximately one-third of the world’s
mangrove forests have been lost (Alonghi,
2002), 29  percent of sea grasses have been
lost (Waycott et al., 2008) and more than
75 percent of coral reefs are under immediate
threat from local and global forces (Burke
et al., 2011). In addition, 60 percent of coral
reefs are threatened by local pressures such
as over-fishing, destructive fishing, coastal
development, watershed-based pollution, or
marine-based pollution and damage (Burke
et al., 2011).
In addition to pressures on species and eco-
systems, there are also significant economic
losses from the sector. World Bank-FAO
(2009) estimated global losses of net economic
benefit at some US$50 billion, due to excess
harvesting capacity and effort, linked with
capital and operating-cost subsidies. In 2003,
subsidies primarily to support overfishing
were estimated at $16.2 billion out of a total of
$27 billion globally (Sumaila et al., 2010). In
addition, illegal, unreported and unregulated
(IUU) fishing is now a major concern for
many fisheries, with global losses estimated at
between $9 billion and $24 billion annually, representing between 11 and 26 million tons
of fish or between 10 percent and 22 percent of total fisheries production (MRAG, 2009).
These losses impact directly on the availability of fish for small-scale fishers.
Marine and, in particular, coastal habitats and resources are under increasing threat
from a variety of sources (Campbell, 1996; Bryant et al., 1998; Whittingham et al.,
2003) (see Box 2) including:
•	 habitat loss, destruction and fragmentation as a result of agriculture, aquaculture,
fishing, urban growth, port developments and tourism
•	 pollution from industry, mining, farming, aquaculture and urban development
•	 changes in water sediment loads from agriculture, forestry and mining
BOX 1:
Overfishing in Asia
An Asian Development Bank (ADB)-funded,
WorldFish-implemented regional fisheries project
in Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, the
Philippines and Sri Lanka identified the central
issue of fisheries as drastically depleted resources
– resulting from overfishing and compounded
by environmental degradation. All fisheries had
harvesting rates that were greater than those
required to achieve maximum sustainable yields or
maximum economic yields.
Overfishing was found to be intimately linked to
poverty among fishing communities, where fishing
was seen to be the income of last resort. The de
facto open access regime of the fishery allowed
more and more people to join the fishery.
Source: Stobutzki et al., 2006
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
12
•	 changes in water flows as a result of deforestation, abstraction for irrigation and
human consumption, and hydroelectric dams
•	 excessive or inappropriate exploitation of resources
•	 inappropriate genetic manipulation and selection in aquaculture
•	 introduction of exotic species from aquaculture, the aquarium trade, ships ballast
tanks
•	 climate variability resulting in periodic coastal shocks
•	 climate-related changes such as changes in sea level, sea temperatures and pred-
ator-prey relations.
The reasons for the poor state of global fisheries are complicated (Rudd et al., 2003).
They are complex systems that combine social, economic, ecological and political forces
which are difficult to reconcile. Fisheries management has been a major component
of the wider sector development process that has been used to address some of these
issues. However, fisheries management has not been very successful across global
fisheries. According to Bromley (2009), “the
imperiled status of global fish stocks offers
clear evidence of the comprehensive failure of
nationalgovernmentstoprovidecoherentman-
agement to protect those stocks.” This reflects
the complex nature of fisheries management
as will be discussed later. As Hilborn noted,
“fisheries management isn’t rocket science, it
is actually quite a bit harder” (Western Star,
2009).
3.3	 The potential of
coastal fisheries
In spite of these management issues, the
potential of fisheries, if managed well, is con-
siderable. What form that potential will take
will depend on how and why fisheries are
managed.
The ability of depleted fisheries to recover and achieve their maximum potential will
depend, to an extent, on how that potential is measured, i.e. in terms of production max-
imization, economic return maximization, environmental protection or employment
maximization. The length of time required to return fisheries to their desired state
will also vary, depending on the current state of the stocks and the species concerned.
Even with management, multiple-species stocks are likely to evolve gradually towards
an equilibrium which may or may not be the same as before exploitation.
There is, however, broad recognition of the potential of fisheries to bounce back
from the current state of mismanagement and to continue to provide benefits into
the future. What those benefits are and who benefits from them are largely political
decisions that countries will have to decide. The following section reviews a variety of
management themes that have been used in the quest to achieve that potential.
BOX 2:
Reef destruction
Coral reefs are seen as an important source of food
and income through the sale of fish in many coastal
communities. However, there are also examples
where the sustainability of this ecosystem service is
being threatened by coral mining.
In Tanzania, live and dead coral was extracted for
lime production in the 1990s. On Mafia Island,
coral mining was ranked third among income-
earning activities, in terms of the number of people
involved. After commercial lime production was
made illegal this fell rapidly.
Source: Tobey and Torell, 2006
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
13
4
4.	Fisheries management
	 approaches and themes
This section discusses the concept of fisheries management, its
evolution and how it manifests itself in modern fisheries. It looks
at the broad management themes that have been adopted and
briefly discusses each of these.
Fisheries management has been defined as: “The integrated process of information
gathering, analysis, planning, consultation, decision-making, allocation of resources
and formulation and implementation, with enforcement as necessary, of regulations
or rules which govern fisheries activities in order to ensure the continued productiv-
ity of the resources and the accomplishment of other fisheries objectives”(Cochrane,
2002, 3).
In the past, there was widespread discussion of the different merits of economic, social
and biological objectives and management strategies for fisheries. Much of the focus
was on the maximization of productivity and production targets, which remains the
key indicator of success used by many governments around the world. However, as
the realization has grown that fish stock harvesting cannot be continuously increased,
the focus has increasingly shifted towards environmental management. The social
aspects also have taken a more prominent role in strategies, due to a greater focus on
reduction of global poverty and recognition that fish and fisheries play an important
role in the livelihoods of many poor people.
The conflicts among the different management schools of thought continue. However,
efforts are being made to bring these disparate threads together into a management
process that harmonizes different aims and strategies to achieve a balance across
social, economic and environmental sector objectives.
In reality, a fishery is a complex system which links individual human endeavor, en-
terprise, risk, culture, the physical world, technology, the natural world, the political
economy and wider society’s beliefs, aspirations and values (Campbell and Catter-
moul, 2009). According to Ostrom (2009a), all human-used resources are embedded
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
14
in complex, social-ecological systems composed of multiple subsystems and the
internal variables within these subsystems at multiple levels.
Scientists have often responded by developing simple theoretical models to analyze
aspects of the resource problems and to prescribe universal solutions (Ostrom,
2009a). In their attempts to understand and interact with fisheries, scientists have
often tried to simplify or break down the complexity. Thus they can work with its
separate parts by, for example, focusing on specific components of fisheries, such
as gear/vessel classification, or over-simplifying relationships implicit in bio-econom-
ic models. As the crisis in world fisheries deepens, the pressure to find workable
solutions increases. The combination of complexity and urgency has created a market
for quick and technical solutions to management problems (Degnbol et al., 2006). But
these rarely do more than explain a part of what is happening in localized situations
at a given time. As Dengbol et al. explained, these “fixes” often lead to tunnel vision.
The responsibility for the management of fisheries has been disputed for many years.
In many traditional communities, management has been a function of the community
itself. In the Pacific, for instance, the rights to resources are often part of a complex
web of social and cultural relations between and within communities and kinship
groups. More recently, and particularly as fisheries have come under increasing
pressure, the state has taken on a greater role in their management.
However, governments are no longer the only source of decision-making in fisheries
or other environmental fields (Armitage et al., 2012) where collaborative approaches
involving a number of stakeholders are becoming accepted. This is important because
different groups of people want different things from the resource, at different times
and collected in different ways. Armitage et al. (2012) argued that while “command
and control” management systems have yielded success in terms of flows of ecosystem
services, they have done so at social and environmental cost – social cost related
to compliance, enforcement and conflict, and environmental cost due to declines in
regulating and providing ecosystem services. They noted that management and gov-
ernance systems are not mutually exclusive and suggested that cooperative models of
governance are more likely to work effectively within an enabling system of govern-
ment regulation.
However, the very concept of management is sometimes questioned and the broader
approach of governance, which considers the wider processes and institutions through
which society makes decisions, is often seen as more appropriate (Armitage et al.,
2012). Governance of resources raises questions that go far beyond narrow manage-
ment concerns and start to address more philosophical issues about wider benefit
flows to society and to future generations. The form and function of governance often
reflect the wider changes in society’s approaches, concerns and priorities, the market
realities, and the cost-cutting motives of government to hand over responsibility for
that management.
Whiletherearenoclear-cutorseparatemodelsoffisheriesmanagement,therearebroad
approaches or themes that reflect the emphasis of a particular management process
in a particular situation. Some are suited to some circumstances, others to other cir-
cumstances. Management methods developed for single species fisheries in temperate
waters, for example, may be unsuited to tropical multi-species inshore fisheries (Rudd
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
15
et al., 2003) where ecological and fish landing data are poor, where there are few formal
property rights, where many operators compete for resources with different gear from
many sites, and where people regularly move in and out of the fishery. Often these
approaches or themes are combined, as in the use of marine protected areas with co-
management, to address different aspects of the management process.
These management themes can be grouped in numerous ways. We have identified
seven broad themes reflecting different aims: i) customary marine tenure, ii) yield
maximization, iii) conservation of resources, iv) economic maximization, v) rights-
based approaches, vi) ecosystem-based management and vii) co-management. There
is much overlap between them, and which ones are used depends very much on the
local context. These are reviewed in the following sections.
4.1	 Customary marine tenure (CMT)
Traditional community-based resources management systems have been document-
ed across the world by, e.g. Ruddle et al. (1992) and Kuemlangan (2004). Berkes et
al. (2000) noted that resource monitoring has been a regular feature of traditional
systems that note and act upon the abundance of different species. Sacred sites may
have provided some protection to species much as a marine protected area does. For
example, Berkes et al. (2000) recalled how some indigenous people “rested” their
fisheries on a periodic basis, and that traditional fisheries sometimes used methods
that are only beginning to be adopted by more formal systems. Some traditional com-
munities have tended to conceptualize their fisheries as multi-species, rather than
single species, and also to view the interconnectedness of land and water systems. In
their review of the similarities among some 30 traditional fishing societies throughout
the world, Acheson et al. (1998 cited in Berkes et al., 2000) suggested that the similari-
ties indicate some geographic transfer of knowledge.
Many customary marine tenure (CMT) arrangements may have resulted in the sus-
tainable and equitable use of fisheries resources, in part because there was limited
fishing pressure. Many continued to operate when resources declined and effort sub-
stantially increased, but with varying degrees of success. However, it needs to be
remembered that these CMT systems are often primarily mechanisms that govern
exchange and social relations within and between traditional communities and groups,
rather than explicitly protecting resources.
While customary marine tenure may have been associated largely with traditional
systems, there is increasing recognition that it also has a role to play, albeit in modified
form, in modern management systems. For example, Kuemlangan (2004) noted that
a “[a] cursory examination of PIC (Pacific Island Countries) Constitutions, fisheries
legislation and general natural resource management practice indicate that the PICs
have the necessary minimum legal basis for application of CMT, and are receptive to
or already practise participatory approaches to fisheries management including those
based on CMT.”
Today, there is renewed interest in learning from these approaches and applying them
to rights-based approaches at the community level. But, it is also recognized that com-
munity-based approaches more generally are not a panacea for resource management
(Pomeroy, 1994).
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
16
4.2	 Yield maximizing approaches
As mentioned above, in the past, the focus of fisheries management and development
tended to focus on ways of maximizing production. Speaking at the opening of the 1883
International Fisheries Exhibition in London, the biologist Thomas Huxley famously
stated that “The world’s fish and fisheries are inexhaustible” (Link, 2010). It was only
in the 1900s that people began to fully realize that the world’s fish were exhaustible.
More recently, there have been concerns about maintaining stock size, retaining bio-
diversity and ensuring ecosystem function – with significant tension between those
approaches adopted to maximize productivity and those for achieving biological con-
servation. For example, the Plan of Implementation of the 2002 World Summit on Sus-
tainable Development targeted the restoration of fish stocks to maximum sustainable
yield (MSY) levels by 2015. While MSY is a useful concept in a single species stock, it
becomes less useful in a multi-species stock with inter-species interaction (Leal, 2010).
In addition, limited governmental capacity may limit the ability to assess what MSY
actually is. The World Bank-FAO report, The Sunken Billions: The Economic Justifica-
tion for Fisheries Reform, suggested that MSY should be considered a minimum target
(World Bank-FAO, 2009).
The drive to maximize production from fisheries has been, in large part, behind the
massive over-capitalization of fisheries and the perverse incentives that now are the
norm. As a result, there have been many attempts to control fishing efforts at MSY.
These have often involved a series of technical measures including direct gear and
fishing effort restrictions, including limits on vessel numbers (e.g. by license), vessel
types, engine power, vessel length and gear used. Gear restriction may include mesh
size restrictions, hook size, net length and the use of excluder devices. Restrictions
may also be on species, fish length or age, total weight taken, weights landed (and
thus discards) and breeding state. Fishing activities may be limited by physical areas
which may range from zones where no fishing occurs at any time of the year to lesser
restrictions that allow certain gears by certain people at certain times. These might
include inshore fishing areas for small-scale fishers. Such spatial restrictions, often
called marine management areas (MMAs), are discussed in more detail below. In
some fisheries, total allowable catches (TACs) of different species are designated and,
in some cases, quotas are allocated within that. They may be allocated directly (free of
cost or for a fee) or through an auction system.
These different measures have come into favor and gone out of favor in different
fisheries at different times. In Scott’s (2010) useful chronology of such changes, he
identified a general movement from gear restrictions, through licenses, to quotas
and to property rights with a move towards stronger qualities of rights including:
greater exclusivity, greater permanence, greater transferability, greater divisibility
and greater security.
4.3	 Conservation of resources
Approaches to conserve resources have adopted a number of measures to limit the
ability of fishers to harvest resources. While technical measures (as outlined above)
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
17
have been adopted, marine conservation areas, habitat and stock restoration, and pre-
cautionary principles have been a key part of this approach (Hilborn, 2007).
The precautionary approach uses foresight to avoid unacceptable or undesirable situ-
ations, taking into account that changes in fisheries systems are only slowly revers-
ible, difficult to control, not well understood, and subject to change in the environment
and human values (FAO, 1996). As Hilborn (2003, 387) noted “[t]he precautionary
approach is built around the concept that managers should not wait until they have
unequivocal evidence that fishing effort needs to be reduced before acting, and it is
intended to protect fisheries from overexploitation in the face of uncertainty.”
Even where fisheries are being managed effectively, there is likely to be a need to
ensure that forces from outside of the sector do not degrade habitats and stocks.
These include land-based pollution, marine pollution, coastal development and climate
change. Restoring habitats and stocks to
their original condition and limiting external
pressure are important components.
Marine conservation areas are often referred
to as Marine Protected Area (MPAs),
including those which are no-take zones
and thus have the benefit of protecting the
species and individual fish that remain inside
the protected area (see Box 3).
FAO (2007) listed eight common reasons for
establishing MPAs:  i) to protect a specific
life history stage, ii) to control fishing
mortality, iii) to handle the spillover effect
of fish migrating across the boundaries of an
MPA so they can be fished, iv) to serve as a
source and/or sink for fish eggs and larvae to
improve recruitment, v) to protect habitat, food web integrity and biodiversity, vi) to
reduce by-catch, discarding and other negative impacts on harvested species, other
species, endangered species and other species society wants to protect, vii) to reduce
competition between user groups or to enhance opportunities for certain groups of
users (by establishing rights), and viii) to serve as a potential hedge against uncer-
tainty. However, MPAs take many forms around the world and the language used to
describe them differs from place to place, which can lead to considerable confusion
(Christie and White, 2006).
The effectiveness of MPAs depends in part upon the size and ecological sufficiency
of the enclosed area, its level of exclusion and its connectivity to other MPAs. While
very large MPAs which are enforced no-take zones effectively eliminate fishing
pressure, there still may be other pressures from climatic conditions, non-fisheries
pollution or habitat destruction. A review of the experience of inter-coastal manage-
ment (ICM) in the Philippines by White et al. (2006) determined that MPAs, as part
of wider ICM processes, protect and enhance near-shore habitats and fisheries for
BOX 3:
Soufrière marine management
area in St Lucia
The Soufrière Marine Management Area in St
Lucia, created in 1995, had a rapid impact on the
combined biomass of five commercially important
fish families in the adjacent fishing area. Mean total
catch per trip per fisher increased by between 46%
and 90% over a five-year period with stable fishing
effort.
Source: Roberts et al., 2001
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
18
the benefit of coastal communities, and they
attract marine tourism which contributes to
the local economy. Key benefits include i)
enhanced local biophysical quality of coastal
habitats and improved fish catches inside and
outside of MPAs, ii) enhanced revenues to
communities and local governments derived
from tourism within and outside of MPAs, iii)
revenues from marine-based or eco-tourism
enterprises to local communities, and iv)
improved planning and implementation of
ICM through 100 municipal and city govern-
ments. However, benefits can be mixed, as
shown in Box 4.
In addition to conserving existing resources,
there has been considerable interest in
enhancing fish stocks. Bell et al. (2006) stated
that the key challenges for capture fisheries
are i) reducing fishing effort, ii) removing
excess fishing capacity, and iii) building
the institutional arrangements needed to
restore spawning biomass to more produc-
tive levels and reverse degradation of sup-
porting habitats. They suggested two options
from the cultured production of juveniles to
enhance this process – restocking and stock enhancement – although they also recog-
nized the difficulties of doing so. Examples of success include scallop stock enhance-
ment in Hokkaido, Japan, and giant clam restocking in the Philippines.
4.4	 Economic maximization
The over-exploitation of fisheries resources is often associated with significant
economic losses. When the World Bank and FAO (2009) calculated the current state
of fisheries from an economic perspective, FAO reported that “economic losses in
marine fisheries resulting from poor management, inefficiencies, and overfishing add
up to a staggering US$50 billion per year ... Taken over the last three decades, these
losses total over $US2 trillion, a figure roughly equivalent to the GDP of Italy.”
The focus of economic approaches calls for the maximization of economic yield (MEY)
and the reduction of these losses. MEY – the value of the largest positive difference
between total revenues and total costs of fishing – generally requires less fishing
effort than what is required to achieve maximum sustainable yield (MSY). Many
fisheries managers hope that some of this economic return may be captured by wider
society as a resource rent that will provide a return from giving fishers the opportu-
nity to profit from the nation’s fishery. Economic approaches often include some of the
technical measures discussed above and the use of rights which are outlined below.
BOX 4:
Impact of marine protected areas
(MPAs) in Tanzania
The impact on abundance of harvested fish around
MPAs in Tanga and Mafia, Tanzania, was perceived
to be positive, but impacts were perceived as
negligible or negative in other MPA sites. Fishers’
focus group meetings in Tanga and Mafia sites
corroborated that MPA efforts have improved the
fisheries. The changes in Mafia were further verified
by key informant marine experts who knew the
condition of the fisheries in the early 1990s and at
the time of the study. Finfish, octopus, endangered
species such as marine turtles, and even whales and
dolphins were returning.
However, social and economic changes were less
obvious, with only a small impact on household
involvement in decision-making, negligible or
negative effects on employment, and negligible
impact on incomes.
Source: Tobey and Torell, 2006
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
19
Resource rents can be captured, for example,
through charging for the right to fish, either
directly on landed catch or by selling licenses
for access or selling quota access.
One approach to fisheries management which
emphasizes the potential economic returns is
referred to as wealth-based fisheries manage-
ment (WBFM). WBFM calls for using the al-
location of fishing rights to capture the wealth
that is currently being dissipated through
poor management practices (Cunningham
et al., 2009). While this has occurred in, for
example, Norway, Iceland and New Zealand, there are few examples in developing
countries where small-scale, labor-intensive fisheries operate (see Box 5). A key
problem is that this approach depends on the capacity of resource managers to assess
how much fish catch is sustainable in a particular fishery and establish quotas based
on that amount, which can be challenging in developing country fisheries that may
lack such information and the capacity to collect it.
4.5	 Rights-based approaches
In recognition of the adverse effects of the often open-access nature of fisheries,
fisheries authorities have been developing a series of approaches to fisheries manage-
ment that confer specific rights to some groups of fishers but exclude others. This is
an increasing trend in fisheries and other natural resources (Pearse, 1992).
Rights-based management of fisheries, in its most basic form, refers to bundles of
entitlements that confer both privileges and responsibilities. For example, since the
1980s, countries have established Exclusive Economic Zones (EEZs) through which
they claim exclusive rights up to 200 nautical miles from baselines. Such rights-based
approaches are evolving to address more complex issues, and discussions referring
to “rights-based management” or “rights-based approaches” are now expanded to
include human rights (Charles, 2008; FAO, 2010; Charles, 2011) to reach, for example,
adequate livelihood and poverty-reduction criteria (Willmann, 2010).
Rights are an emotive issue that is much misunderstood. A “right” can be thought of
as an entitlement assured by custom, law or property, and defined by legal, social or
ethical principles. Some rights have been described as universal, natural, permanent
and inalienable while others are thought to be more culturally specific or limited to
specific groups. Rights may be defined by international or national law or custom, and
may be changed or removed by society. Rights generally involve two parties: those
that hold the right and those that have responsibility to uphold the right. The effective-
ness of the right is in large part dependent on each party fulfilling its role (Donnelly,
2003). Rights in fisheries have tended to refer to a legally defined ability to do or to
own something, e.g. to catch a quota of fish, to access an area of water or to harvest
a certain species.
BOX 5:
An economic approach in practice
The Partnership for African Fisheries (PAF),
operated under the auspices of the African Union,
is currently piloting an approach to the economic
rationalization of the fisheries of Africa through
wealth-based fisheries management (WBFM). This
will inform fisheries policy across the continent.
Source: DFID, 2012
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
20
Pomeroy (1994) noted that rights and rules, or incentives and sanctions are essential for
the effective operation of any fisheries management system. Rights to harvest resources
have taken a number of forms that include licenses, individual transferrable quotas
(ITQs), and territorial use rights in fisheries (TURFs). In most cases, fisheries rights
also have associated responsibilities that need to be adhered to, as reflected in the Code
of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries (Charles, 2011). Informal rights are being recognized
more and more, and are being converted into formal rights in developing fisheries es-
pecially in co-management systems. These informal property or use rights, which have
tended to be based around community ownership of resources, are becoming more
formally recognized. The draft International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-
Scale Fisheries (GSSF) currently being prepared by FAO (FAO, 2012b, 7) recognizes
that “[r]ights and responsibilities should be bestowed on small-scale fishing communi-
ties to restore, protect and manage local aquatic and coastal ecosystems on which they
depend for their wellbeing and that they have used traditionally for their livelihoods.”
For example, individual transferrable quotas (ITQs), used in a number of developed
fisheries across the globe, receive much attention in the literature. They can be seen
as part of a rights-based approach where the right to a certain part of a total allowable
catch (TAC) is transferrable and tradable. They are based on a TAC being established
for a fishery and the quotas within the TAC limits being allocated to individuals,
vessels or groups. Key questions around the specific design of ITQs include i) method
of allocation and charges for a accessing a quota, ii) length of time of ownership of the
quota, iii) its transferability between users, iv) divisibility of quotas, v) the ability to
assess the TAC and vi) enforcement.
4.6	 Ecosystem-based management
Ecosystem approaches to fisheries (EAFs) represent a move away from management
systems that focus only on the sustainable harvest of target species or the manage-
ment of fishers’ behaviors, to a system that also considers the major components of
the ecosystem and the social and economic benefits that can be derived from them
(FAO, 2012a). EAFs also follow the direction established by the 1993 Convention on
Biological Diversity and can be seen as an attempt to reverse the divergence of two
management goals that call for i) conserving the structure, diversity and function
of ecosystems and ii) satisfying societal and human needs for food and economic
benefits (Zhou et al., 2010). But it also recognizes the wider importance of ecosystems
services and the long-term benefits of their continuation.
FAO’s EAF, adopted by FAO’s Committee on Fisheries (COFI) in 2003 as the most ap-
propriate management framework, was explicitly indicated as the target framework by
the World Summit of Sustainable Development (WSSD, 2002). FAO (2008) suggested
that ecosystem approaches to fisheries management should be implemented with the
following features:
•	 adopting participatory approaches at all levels of the planning and implementation
steps
•	 ensuring that all key components of the fishery system are considered (including
those related to the ecological, social, economic and governance dimensions) and
also take account of external drivers such as climate change
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
21
•	 encouraging the use of the best available knowledge – both scientific and tradi-
tional – in decision-making
•	 promoting the adoption of adaptive management systems
•	 building on existing institutions and practices.
FAO promotes EAF as the most recent stage in a process of fisheries management
which includes the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries and guidelines for EAF’s
implementation developed in 2003. EAF is recognized as an important guiding
principle in FAO’s Guidelines for Small-Scale Fisheries (FAO, 2012b). To date, the most
extensive applications of the EAF have been in developed countries such as Norway,
Australia and the EU.
Although the concept of the EAF may seem relatively straightforward, its implementation
may require the involvement of a large number of stakeholder groups, particularly if the
implementation is across sectors. This implies a need to find improved ways of defining
and sharing responsibilities. The importance of stakeholder participation in EAF has im-
plications for the type of governance arrangements required to implement that approach
(FAO, 2008). As regards existing fisheries management procedures, FAO recommends
supporting current management systems, enabling them to evolve and adapt in order to
become EAF compliant. In many ways, the ecosystem approach is designed to address
the complexity of fisheries management, es-
pecially with respect to small-scale fisheries
(Mahon et al., 2008). In order to understand
this complexity, Hall and Mainprize (2004)
suggest the need for ecosystem performance
measures and reference points for a diversity
of metrics to provide an overall picture of the
ecosystem.
Integrated coastal management (ICM), which
aims to bring together a wide diversity of
sectors, interests and groups in a large area,
is one management approach that comple-
ments the wider approach of EAF. Likewise,
marine protected areas (MPAs) can play an
important role in EAF.
The concept of ecosystem-based approaches
is now being extended to address a much
wider set of issues where fisheries man-
agement concerns are embedded in the
local economic, social and environmental
situations and designed not only to improve
existing resource use but to address future
issues such as climate change. Conservation
International (2011) describes its approach
as ecosystem-based adaptation (EbA), “which
capitalizes on the ability of natural systems to
BOX 6:
Ecosystem-based adaptation
(EbA) in the Philippines
In the Philippines, Conservation International (CI) is
targeting the Verde Island Passage marine corridor,
specifically its coastal ecosystem where 830,000
people live and depend on its marine resources
for livelihoods including fishing, aquaculture and
tourism.
With increasing population, pressures such as
overfishing, clearing of mangroves for aquaculture,
development and logging will result in erosion and
degradation of the natural coast. The vulnerability
assessment for this region, completed in 2009,
resulted in a series of recommendations. Based
on this, CI is working with partners to implement
two initiatives: to enhance coastal protection and
strengthen fisheries resilience. Key actions include
mangrove reforestation, training local communities
and government in EbA coastal management
techniques, application of best fishing practices and
technologies, and income diversification strategies.
Source: Conservation International, 2011
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
22
assist in human adaptation to climate change.” CI defines EbA as “the use of biodiver-
sity and ecosystem services as part of an overall adaptation strategy to help people to
adapt to the adverse effects of climate change” (see Box 6).
The interpretation of ecosystem approaches is also becoming increasingly sophisticat-
ed – with more attention given to the interlinkages among different ecosystems, with
more recognition of marine and coastal management in terms of “from the deep-sea to
the ridgeline”, and with more recognition of the ways ecosystems interact with each
other (Silvestri and Kershaw, eds., 2010). The added complexities of these “expanded”
ecosystem approaches clearly has important implications for the decision-making
processes, policies and institutional structures required to support them.
4.7	 Co-management
Co-management systems are becoming popular in many parts of the world and are
demonstrating considerable levels of success (see Box 7).
The greater involvement of fishers in the management decisions of fisheries not only
builds on traditional systems of resource management in many parts of the world, it
reflects both an increased awareness of the need to empower and engage fishers in
the management process, and a recognition that it is potentially less expensive than
trying to manage from the center (Alpízar, 2006). Berkes (2008) discussed the oppor-
tunities and challenges of using indigenous and community conserved areas (ICCAs)
for conservation practice, noting that they have a role to play in ensuring that conven-
tional conservation approaches become more inclusive and pluralistic.
In its simplest form, co-management can be described as fisheries management
where roles and responsibilities are shared between the government and the users
(Pomeroy, 1994; Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen,
1996). Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen (1996) dif-
ferentiated this from community-based
resource management (CBRM) because with
co-management, government is also involved
in the decision-making process concerning
the management of the fishery. Abdullah et
al. (1998, 106) found that “co-management is
a middle course between pure state property
and pure communal property regimes,”
while Guttiérrez et al. (2011) referred to co-
management as community-based co-man-
agement where fishers and managers work
together to improve the regulatory process.
In many respects, co-management and com-
munity-based management are separated
by the degree of government involvement
and community centricity (Alpízar, 2006).
However, in the wider context of Exclusive
Economic Zones (EEZ), markets, infrastruc-
BOX 7:
Co-management in inland water
bodies in Bangladesh
During a ten-year period, the Bangladesh
Department of Fisheries, in partnership with
the WorldFish Center and 11 NGOs, established
community control over 116 water bodies. Over 130
poverty-based community-based organizations
(CBOs) were involved in the management of these
water bodies.
In return for the right to operate these fisheries, the
CBOs had to embrace the principles of sustainable
fisheries management.
Source: Dickson,
www.worldfishcenter.org
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
23
ture, safety and rescue, and the associated policy and legislative environment in which
fisheries exists, it is difficult to conceive of any fishery which is not co-managed.
Abdullah et al (1998, 106) noted that “[s]trictly speaking, pure communal property
systems and community-based coastal resource management (CBCRM) are always
embedded in state property systems and derive their strength from them.”
Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen (1996) provide a useful classification within the broader
scope of co-management as follows:3
•	 INSTRUCTIVE: where there is only minimal exchange of information between gov-
ernment and users (e.g. co-management arrangements in inland fisheries in Ban-
gladesh)
•	 CONSULTATIVE: where mechanisms exist for government to consult with users
but all decisions are made by the government (e.g. the fisheries committees es-
tablished on Lake Malombe in Malawi and the bay management council in San
Miguel Bay in the Philippines)
•	 COOPERATIVE: where government and users cooperate as equal partners in deci-
sion-making (e.g. customary rights areas in Fiji)
•	 ADVISORY: where users advise government of decisions to be taken and govern-
ment endorses these decisions
•	 INFORMATIVE: where government has delegated authority to make decisions to
user groups who are responsible for informing government of these decisions
(e.g. the mechanized seine fishery in Inhassoro, Mozambique).
While co-management covers a broad spectrum of relationships between government
and users, others such as environmental advocacy groups and scientists may also feel
they have a role to play in the process. The level of participation by non-state actors
can often reflect the cultural or political preferences of the country concerned (Sen
and Raakjaer Nielsen, 1996).
Co-management, in addition to being regarded as a management approach on its own,
is also key to other approaches, such as integrated area management, ecosystem-
based management, protected area management and adaptive management (Evans
et al., 2011a).
The developing focus on co-management in fisheries is, in part, a response to the
failure of other, more top-down forms of management. But, as Wamukota et al. (2012)
noted, there has also been considerable debate about whether co-management has
provided the expected benefits. There seems to be widespread agreement that co-
management has a growing role to play in fisheries management globally, especially
in small-scale tropical coastal fisheries. However, the evidence to support this still
remains elusive, largely because of the complexity of the processes involved and the
long-time frames often required to see clearly distinguishable impacts. Evans et al.
(2011a, 1938), carried out a meta-analysis of 29 case studies in 90 sites, noting that
“overall fisheries co-management delivers benefits to end-users through improve-
ments in key process and outcome indicators. However, the dataset as a whole is con-
stituted primarily of data from the Philippines. When we exclude this body of work,
few generalizations can be made about the impact of fisheries co-management.”
3
	 The examples given were from a sample of 22 case studies on fisheries co-management.
24
© Roberto Faidutti
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
25
5
5.	 Impacts
The success of different fisheries management systems can be
measured in terms of their impact. This section discusses impacts,
howtheymightbemeasuredandwhathasbeenachievedthrough
fisheries management.
Impact has two sides. One concerns the achievement of the objectives established
in the management regime, the second defines the actual, objectively measurable
impacts of the management regime on the resource, environment and people’s lives,
i.e. the intended versus the actual. The impacts identified in the literature are often
selective and may be biased towards social, ecological or economic perspectives
(Bennett, 2005b) or even biased to demonstrate effectiveness selectively (Wamukota
et al., 2012). Even when one of these biases is adopted, it may have bias within it, e.g.
the type of sociological indicators selected may be those of the researcher rather than
those of the people who are impacted. This needs to be kept in mind when assessing
impact. In the Philippines, for instance, CBCRM programs are effective in engaging
BOX 8:
Assessing community perceptions of impact in Cambodia
In Cambodia, the decision to introduce
community-based fisheries management was a
political one. The government had its perceptions
of what it wanted to achieve in terms of improving
people’s livelihoods but it also wanted to see what
perceptions the communities had.
It adopted a process of participatory impact
assessment to evaluate policy effectiveness.
Different stakeholders were asked to identify
the impact on their livelihoods and to score
them. Initially, the policy reforms generated
improvements in poverty reduction, reduced
fishing costs, improved income and improved food
security, but these started to decline over time as
they encouraged more people to join the fishery.
They also created opportunities for small-scale
processors and for small-scale farmers who were
better able to access flooded land.
Source: CFDO and IMM, 2004
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
26
local communities but resource users are skeptical about the impact on their liveli-
hoods (Maliao et al., 2009). Evans et al. (2011a) also noted that different studies tend
to measure different indicators and include biases towards favorable places, or they
focus on successful projects or projects that are currently being supported, which is
likely to produce more favorable results.
There can often be confusion around impact because of who decides the criteria used
to assess it. Researchers or managers views of what should, could or has occurred
may be very different from those of the community, and different stakeholder groups
in the community may also have quite different perceptions from each other. Par-
ticipatory approaches to policy reform impact assessment can often reveal interesting
aspects of impact (see Box 8).
According to Hanna (1996), there are three main means of assessing the effectiveness
of co-management:
•	 SUSTAINABILITY: in the form of stewardship (the maintenance of productivity and
ecological characteristics) and resilience (the ability to withstand changes and
shocks)
•	 EFFICIENCY: the cost effectiveness of the arrangement (transaction costs or net
returns)
•	 EQUITY: this is divided into representation (of users), process clarity (transpar-
ency and accountability), homogenous expectations (similarity of user expecta-
tions) and distributive effects (equitable distribution of benefit flows).
Wamukota et al. (2012) complemented this by indicating that co-management
success can be measured through social dimensions, the condition of the resources
and aspects of wider ecology. In regard to community-based fisheries management
(CBFM), Kuemlangan (2004) noted the importance of balancing the livelihoods of
fisheries with improving fish resource conservation or management. Weeratunge et
al. (2013) pointed out that human wellbeing can be measured in a number of different
ways but, in relation to fisheries, this is not a well-developed area of research. They
also noted that fishers’ perceptions of wellbeing changes over time, which needs to be
accommodated in any wellbeing analysis.
Assessing the delivery of impact is often confused by a lack of clarity around the aims
of the intervention. Many programs have confused policy objectives that interact,
are internally inconsistent (Bellamy et al., 2001), are unrealistic or are incapable of
objective measurement. Few seem to recognize trade-offs or a need to prioritize. In
part, the ability to measure impact is time dependent, with some impacts taking many
years to become apparent. In other situations, the theory of change itself may be
changed over time to reflect changing political aims, and the focus of implementation
may shift while the impacts being evaluated may remain unchanged (Bellamy et al.,
2001).
Co-management impacts seem to have been studied more than most. Sen and Nielsen
(1996) noted that in most of the co-management cases they studied, the rationale
for introducing co-management was that the fishery was reaching a point of over-
exploitation or was already over-exploited, making it a form of crisis management.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
27
Although it was mostly not possible to assess the outcomes in terms of sustainability,
equity and efficiency, in most cases representation was increased and process clarity
was improved. Guttiérrez et al. (2011) noted that the advantages of co-management
include an enhanced sense of ownership which encourages responsible fishing,
greater sensitivity to local socio-economic and ecological restraints, improved man-
agement through use of local knowledge, collective ownership by users in decision-
making, increased compliance with regulations through peer pressure, and better
monitoring, control and surveillance by fishers.
However, what is rather disappointing is the general lack of strong evidence about
the impact of fisheries on people’s livelihoods and sense of inclusion. Evans et al.
(2011a) noted the scarcity of impact assessment data on fisheries co-management
in developing countries. Hilborn (2007a, 272) also found that there has been “very
little systematic attempt to evaluate the success and failures of individual fisheries.”
Roe et al (2009, x) found that a “major deficiency of formal CBNRM projects is the
absence or paucity of quantitative and/or qualitative data on the social, economic and
environmental impacts,” and Hilborn (2007) also noted that there are no systematic
evaluations of the ecological impact of fisheries.
In reviewing the evidence for the success of fisheries management, Sutinen (2010,
97) concluded that: “Although there are several bright spots for some marine fishery
resources (marginal improvements in stock status, growing use of rights-based man-
agement, capacity reduction programs, to name a few), the evidence overall leads me
to conclude that our marine resource management institutions have failed to conserve
resources and improve the economic health of coastal communities.”
Although there are few examples of really successful management in developing
country coastal fisheries, much still can be learned from the existing operations of
fisheries management that may inform a better way of doing things. These critical
success factors are outlined in the next section.
28
© Roberto Faidutti
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
29
6
6.	Critical factors that influence 		
	success
This section of the report presents evidence from the literature,
cross-referenced with key informants, as to factors that have
been key in making fisheries management work.
In spite of the paucity of evidence on the impact of fisheries management systems and
approaches, there is some evidence about which factors influence success in particu-
lar fisheries in particular locations at a particular time.
This section starts with a brief introduction of some of the efforts undertaken by
specialists in the fields of fisheries and natural resources management to encapsulate
frameworks of success factors. It then looks at these factors in more detail under three
headings: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical imple-
mentation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. The critical factors are
those which fisheries experts and practitioners perceive to have influenced the extent
to which a fisheries management approach has had direct influence over planned or
perceived impact. As our concern here is to achieve an understanding of the balance
between social and ecological impacts, the critical success factors are reviewed in
terms of both social and ecological impacts.
This analysis does not give a concrete solution to management problems but indicates
the trends in thinking and practice towards more successful ways of implement-
ing management. As Hilborn (2007, 300) noted, “there is no single prescription for
moving currently unsustainable fisheries towards sustainability. The appropriate
method will depend greatly on local circumstances.” Arthur (2005, 4) concluded in
an 11-year study of fisheries management, funded by the UK government’s Depart-
ment for International Development (DFID), “[w]hile a diversity of circumstances and
needs suggests there is no single or ‘optimum’ co-management arrangement for any
region, nation or local situation there are some features common to all and common
lessons that can be drawn from the study of different arrangements.”
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
30
In spite of these concerns for the specificity of success, some researchers have
developed design principles or generalized criteria. Some are outlined below with the
components discussed in more detail in later sections.
6.1	 Some frameworks of success factors
Ostrom (2009b) identified the following design principles for the management of com-
mon-pool resources management that were sustained over a long period of time and
absent from fsystems:
•	 USER BOUNDARIES: clear and locally understood boundaries between legitimate
users and nonusers are present
•	 RESOURCE BOUNDARIES: clear boundaries that separate a specific common-pool
resource from a larger socio-ecological system are present
•	 CONGRUENCE WITH LOCAL CONDITIONS: appropriation and provision rules are
congruent with local social and environmental conditions
•	 APPROPRIATION AND PROVISION: appropriation rules are congruent with provision
rules: the distribution of costs is proportional to the distribution of benefits
•	 COLLECTIVE-CHOICE ARRANGEMENTS: most individuals affected by a resource
regime are authorized to participate in making and modifying its rules
•	 MONITORING USERS: individuals who are accountable to or are the users monitor
the appropriation and provision levels of the users
•	 MONITORING THE RESOURCE: individuals who are accountable to or are the users
monitor the condition of the resource
•	 GRADUATED SANCTIONS: sanctions for rule violations start very low but become
stronger if a user repeatedly violates a rule
•	 CONFLICT-RESOLUTION MECHANISMS: rapid, low-cost, local arenas exist for
resolving conflicts among users or with officials
•	 MINIMAL RECOGNITION OF RIGHTS: the rights of local users to make their own rules
are recognized by the government
•	 NESTED ENTERPRISES: when a common-pool resource is closely connected to a
larger social-ecological system, governance activities are organized in multiple
nested layers.
BOX 9:
Design principes for the Peruvian anchovy fishery
A study of the Peruvian anchovy fisheries assessed
the applicability of Ostrom’s eight “design principles”
of long-lasting common pool resources management
regimes. Ostrom (1990) confirmed these could serve as
a valuable tool for analysis and understanding of large-
scale common pool resource systems:
1. 	early defined boundaries defining who has rights
to withdraw resources and the boundaries of the
common resource
2.	congruence between appropriation (restricting time,
place, technology, etc.) and provision rules (requiring
labor, material, and money) and local conditions
3.	collective-choice arrangements
4.	monitoring of conditions and behavior
5.	graduated sanctions depending on the seriousness of
an offense
6.	conflict-resolution mechanisms
7.	minimal recognition by government authorities of
rights of appropriators to organize
8.	nested enterprises with monitoring, enforcement
and governance activities organized in multiple levels
for CPRs that are part of larger systems.
Source: Arias Schreiber and Halliday, 2013
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
31
Refined versions of these have been tested in the field and demonstrated their value,
as shown in Box 9.
Similar sorts of criteria that support positive management experiences have been
identified by other researchers. The following highlights the findings of Leal (2010),
Berkes et al. (2001), Francis and Bryceson (2001) and Bennett (2005b).
Community management of quotas
Leal (2010) suggested that, to be effective, the communities require:
•	 legally backed quota rights
•	 sufficient common interest to make negotiations feasible
•	 clear awareness among fishers that collective management will generate benefits
for both fishers and non-fishers
•	 an acceptable system for disposal of rights should the collective arrangement
close
•	 an effective system for deterring violations with sanctions
•	 clear signals that such arrangements will not be overturned by higher levels of
government.
Fisheries management in San Salvador
Berkes et al. (2001) determined that success was due to a number of factors including:
•	 the resource stakeholders’ participation and sense of ownership in project
planning and implementation
•	 clarity of objectives
•	 supportive leadership
•	 the partnership between fishers and government
•	 specification and legitimacy of user rights enforcement
•	 capability building
•	 tangible benefits such as redefined resource access, a shift to non-destructive
fishing methods, improved enforcement, and observable biological, economic
and social changes.
Sustainable use of coastal and marine resources in Tanzania
Francis and Bryceson (2001, 76) identified general lessons learned and key factors,
including:
•	 dialogue and linkage between traditional and scientific knowledge systems
•	 mechanisms for interaction between scientists, managers and decision-makers
•	 continued human and technical capacity building of research institutions
•	 essentiality of addressing land and sea tenure and common property rights
•	 genuine involvement and empowerment of local communities and civil society
including community-based organizations (CBOs), and local non-governmental
organizations (NGOs)
•	 credible and equitable arrangements for benefit-sharing with communities
•	 open availability of information for overall transparency and accountability
•	 integration of socio-economic opportunities into conservation programs
•	 recognition of and respect for local and traditional institutions
•	 openness in collaboration between traditional and government institutions
•	 strengthening of relevant institutions providing entry to decision-making
•	 management agreements between institutions for cross-sectoral coordination
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
32
•	 long-term and broad-based visions in policy thinking
•	 democratic process of public involvement in policy-making and implementation.
Measures which achieved their objectives
Bennett (2005b) collated a number of drivers from a 1997 Organisation of Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) study on measures which achieved their
fisheries objectives. These were found to be:
•	 use rights
•	co-management
•	 compliance and enforcement
•	 biology and luck
•	 policy frameworks
•	 pro-active industry
•	 stakeholder participation
•	 multi-sectoral approaches.
Bennett noted that few if any of these factors are able to contribute to success on their
own but need to be applied in association with others.
As can be seen from these examples, the factors which support positive manage-
ment experiences are likely to be numerous, and operating over several scales. For
example, Wamukota et al. (2012) found that “[t]he full list of contextual conditions
thought to influence the success of common-pool resource management is large
(>30).” But having systematically reviewed 38 papers of 49 co-management projects
related to reefs, they concluded that few studies presented results that covered the
full range of social-ecological success criteria and that reporting selectivity was likely
to have been high.
Success factors appear to operate at different levels and here we have reviewed them
at three levels:
•	 factors affecting policy and planning
•	 factors affecting technical implementation
•	 factors affecting community engagement.
However, we have noted that while this helps split the number of factors into opera-
tional levels, some operate at multiple levels – and the linkages between these levels
are as important as the levels themselves.
6.2	 Factors affecting policy and planning
Factors affecting policy and planning are broadly those that act globally, regionally
and nationally. This includes relating fisheries management to the complexity of the
management situation and conflicting aims, recognizing the importance of context,
operating at different scales and levels, ensuring institutional coherence, ensuring
ecosystem viability and adapting to external change.
Embracing complexity and integration
Fisheries management is, as mentioned above, a complex process. Efforts to simplify
that process tend to result in simplistic solutions. Increasingly, there is a focus on
embracing complexity and integrating management across sectors.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
33
Coastal areas are, by their nature, complex. They support a diversity of species, eco-
systems and stakeholders in a dynamic environment where the land-water interface
generates constant change. The very nature of social and ecological approaches to
natural resources management means dealing with the complexity of bringing together
factors that relate to the environment, society, the economy, politics and culture. This
complexity can often mean that problems have
no right or wrong answer (see Box 10). But as
Link (2010) noted, the potential for fisheries
management to become so complex that it
becomes unmanageable should be avoided by
getting the balance right.
In the past, fisheries management tended
to represent the issues involved in coastal
fisheries management in a simplified form.
The use of single species models from
temperate waters, for example, has been trans-
ferred to multi-species fisheries operating in
ecologically diverse ecosystems. While this
has generated much knowledge of the stocks,
it also has many limitations (Link, 2010).
Models based on fisheries with fewer larger
vessels landing into fewer ports with good
infrastructure and monitoring facilities do not always transfer well to fisheries with
many small craft landing into dispersed sites with limited monitoring.
A key factor of success is bringing these different elements together in ways that
integrate them as a working whole. Acknowledging and dealing with the holistic
nature of the coast is an important starting point for understanding how to bring other
factors into a management approach. As Link (2010, 3335 of Kindle edition) noted,
“without a place, process, or some such mechanism to sort out the social, economic,
biological, ecological, and cultural tradeoffs, we will remain mired in the same difficul-
ties we have faced for centuries.”
Pomeroy (1994) noted that the delay in developing community-based management in
fisheries, compared with other natural resource systems is due, in part, to the com-
plexity of coastal and marine resource systems, the social and cultural structure of
fishing communities, and the independent nature of fishers.
Addressing the issue of scale in commons management, Berkes (2006) noted that it
may be more useful to think in terms of managing complexity rather than simply trying
to “scale up”. This involves thinking of management of the commons as the manage-
ment of complex systems, and recognizing that communities are themselves complex
systems embedded within a larger complex system of politics and economics. Ostrom
(2009a, 421) identified a number of variables that need to be considered in analyzing
socio-ecological systems. Shown in Box 11, these demonstrate how complex it can be
to understand and to monitor such systems.
Understanding the processes that lead to improvements in, or deterioration of,
natural resources is limited because scientific disciplines use different concepts
BOX 10:
Wicked problems of fisheries
management
There is increasing study of the “wicked” nature
of some of the problems that face fisheries and
coastal governance. “Wicked” problems are those
that are difficult to define and delineate from
bigger problems and tend not to be resolved easily.
Essentially they have no right or wrong answer that
can be scientifically determined. This can place
limits to how rational and effective fisheries and
coastal governance can possibly be.
Source: Jentoft and Chuenpagdee, 2009
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
34
and languages to describe and explain complex social-ecological systems (Ostrom,
2009a). The current debate on fisheries and marine biodiversity has polarized to an
extent around three key areas: i) economic rationalization, ii) marine conservation
and iii) distributional/equity issues. Each of these areas has emerged from specific
disciplines, each of which operates within a specific discourse, i.e. a shared way of ap-
prehending the world which constructs meaning and relationships, creates and uses
its own language, validates knowledge in its own way, helps to define common sense
and legitimate knowledge, and builds assumptions, judgments and contentions that
provide the basis for analysis and debate (Dryzek, 2005).
Such discourses tend to separate, confuse and isolate parts of the debate from other
parts, which then tend towards reductionism in the solutions they provide and to
heightened disagreement between different discourses. Bromley (2009) noted that
even within fisheries economics, confused concepts result in incoherent models of
fisheries management.
Compartmentalization of the fisheries/biodiversity debate around the three key areas
mentioned above has often been characterized by oversimplified solutions to fisheries
problems such as the use of individual transferrable quotas, marine protected areas
and community-based management (Degnbol et al., 2006). This has been compound-
ed by the evolution of these discourses away from each other (Belsky, 2000). Ostrom
(2009a) noted that, without a common framework to organize findings, isolated
knowledge does not cumulate.
Armitage et al. (2012) found that there are thresholds where existing systems are
no longer valid, e.g. where coastal fisheries have reached a level of resource decline
that produces profound effects on the system as a whole. This suggests that systems,
whatever form they take, should be sufficiently flexible and adaptable to embrace
change and respond to it. One approach to this calls for utilizing multi-level arrange-
ments where different levels of management or governance have different roles and
responsibilities, and are linked through coordinating institutions (Ostrom, 2009b).
The devolution of roles and responsibilities may be the necessary course of action,
in part to address capacity issues within government, but such transfers also have
the effect of redistributing power, which may be difficult for government to deal with
(Mahon et al., 2008).
The multi-species nature of fisheries, especially in high biodiversity areas such as
coral reefs, can make management particularly difficult. The potential number of in-
teractions of different species and ecosystems in any given fishery can be extremely
high, which manifests itself in many different fisheries (Link, 2010). For instance, the
multispecies nature of the fishery along India’s Andhra Pradesh coast constrains man-
agement measures (Salagrama, 2005). Studies of coastal fisheries and other natural
resource systems suggest that success depends upon matching rules to the local
resource context and attributes (Ostrom, 2009a).
In research on coastal resource management (CRM) in the Philippines, Fabinyi et al.
(2010) demonstrated that various aspects of social complexity also have significant
implications for the outcomes. By highlighting social complexity, they demonstrat-
ed how the planning, implementation and impacts of CRM have different effects for
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
35
BOX 11:
Examples of variables in a framework for analysing social-ecological systems
Social, economic and political settingss (S)
S1 Economic development,. S2 Demogaphic trends. S3 Political stability.
S4 Government resource polices. S5 Market incentives. S6 Media organization.
Resource systems (RS)
RS1 Sector (e.g., water, forests, pasture, fish)
RS2 Clarity of system boundaries
RS3 Size of resource system*
RS4 Human-constructed facilities
RS5 Productivity of system*
RS6 Equilibrium properties
RS7 Predictabaility of system dynamics*
RS8 Storage characteristics
RS9 Location
Resource units (RU)
RU1 Resource unit mobility*
RU2 Growth or replacement rate
RU3 Interaction among resource units
RU4 Economic value
RU5 Number of units
RU6 Distincitve markings
RU7 Spatial and temporal distribution
I1 Harvesting levels of diverse users
I2 Information sharing among users
I3 Deliberation processes
I4 Conflicts among users
I5 Investment activites
I6 Lobbying activites
I7 Self-organizing activities
I8 Netowrking activities
Governance systems
G51 Government organizations
GS2 Nongovernment organizations
GS3 Network structure
GS4 Property-rights systmes
GS5 Operational rules*
GS6 Collective-choice rules*
GS7 Constitutional rules
GS8 Monitoring and sanctioning processes
Users (U)
U1 Number of users*
U2 Socioeconomic attributes of users
U3 History of use
U4 Location
U5 Leadership/entrepreneurship*
U6 Norms/social capital*
U7 Knowledge of SES/mental models*
U8 Importance of resource *
U9 Technology uses
01 Social performance measures (e.g., efficiency, equity,
accountability, sustainability)
02 Ecological performance measures
(e.g., overharvested, resilience, bio-diversity,
sustainability)
03 Externalities to other SES
Source: Ostrom, 2009a
Interactions (1) outcomes (O)
*Subset of variables found to be associated with self-organization.
Related ecosystems (ECO)
ECO1 Climate patterms. ECO2 Pollution patterns. ECO3 Flows into and out of focal SES.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
36
different groups of people. The complexity of the socio-cultural systems that make
up the way people and ecosystems interact means moving away from simplistic gen-
eralizations about the coast and embracing complexity (Mahon et al, 2008; Ostrom,
2009a; Campbell and Townsley, 2013). Understanding and using behavior patterns
that emerge from complexity might suggest that management measures focus more
on developing participation, building trust, gaining commitment to change, internaliz-
ing the political economy, enhancing communication and fostering common interdis-
ciplinary discourses rather than focusing on specific technical measures (Campbell
and Townsley, 2013).
There is also a growing realization that complex situations, such as those that charac-
terize coastal fisheries, will often generate forms of feedback, learning processes and
non-linear relationships that are not always predictable. These are becoming more
difficult to predict due to external factors that affect the fishery – such as climate
change, natural hazards, global fuel and food prices – becoming more common and in-
fluencing fisheries and coastal livelihoods (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). However,
attempts to break down these complex relationships at sectoral and sub-sectoral
levels fail to recognize the interconnectedness of the social, economic and ecological
systems in which fisheries operate (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). Ferrol-Schulte et
al. (2013) called for a more holistic approach to understanding coastal livelihoods in
order to manage coastal and marine social-ecological systems more effectively.
There is increasing realization that fisheries are, in fact, complex social-ecological
systems that are capable of adaptation as management systems alter conditions
(McConney and Charles, 2008). Mahon et al. (2008, 110) proposed “an approach
that emphasizes enabling self organization and adaptive capacity through empower-
ment, learning, and response systems and promoting positive, equitable, transparent
interaction among stakeholders” as a foundation for governing fishery systems. In
reviewing a number of papers concerned with this complexity, Armitage et al. (2009,
95) determined that “[e]fforts to resolve multi-scale environment-society dilemmas
require innovative governance approaches.”
Some of these innovative approaches are starting to emerge, but there is still much
to be done in this area. In the main, there has been a tendency to implement fisheries
management processes in isolation from wider coastal activities and from the planning
and management actions in other sectors (Copes and Charles, 2004). In the future,
fisheries management will have to take into account a much wider set of social and
economic variables and address inter-generational issues (Copes and Charles, 2004).
This has started to emerge as a way forward in some areas. In the Philippines, there
has been some success in integrating fisheries into a wider process of integrated
coastal management. In fact, integrated coastal management (ICM) is now replacing
the narrow focus of fisheries management and narrowly based habitat management
and moving more towards ecosystem-based management which emphasizes the need
for integration and collaboration (White et al., 2006). The potential of ICM to address
coastal complexity through breaking down institutional barriers is gaining support
and is starting to show positive effects (Christie and White, 2006). But the complexity
of such approaches requires that they be developed over time through correspond-
ingly complex systems of consultation and institution building.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
37
Addressing conflicting aims
Fisheries management tries to address social, economic, environmental and political
aims, but these often conflict with each other (Cochrane, 2002). Deciding how to
trade-off between different aims is not an objective process but is ultimately a political
one of negotiation. This section looks at these conflicting aims and discusses the im-
portance of responding to them.
A fishery is a complex system that links individual human endeavor, enterprise, risk,
culture, the physical world, technology, the natural world, the political economy, and
wider society’s beliefs, aspirations and values. Different people’s perceptions of reality
and their ideals can influence the aims that are chosen for different interventions. For
example, wilderness science uses two points on a spectrum when approaching man-
agement: i) the pristine wilderness devoid of humans, and ii) humanized landscapes
and manipulated ecosystems (Belsky, 2000). Different fisheries ecosystems lie within
this spectrum but different aims place different fisheries at different points along it.
Even within a given fishery, the aims of different people engaged in the sector are
often confusing. These aims may be numerous, often conflicting or requiring trade-
offs, and quite often are being under-achieved. In some situations, the conflicts are
clearly defined as noted by Salagama (2005), who identified the need to balance man-
agement efforts with providing livelihoods and foreign exchange earnings as one of
the constraints to effective management in Andhra Pradesh, India. In other cases, the
conflicts are more complex, as noted by Sugiyama et al. (2004, 49) who determined
“[a] key factor to turn around the current trends (in fisheries in Asia and the Pacific)
would be for States to resolve the competing policy imperatives of:
•	 optimal and sustainable use of fish resources and their supporting ecosystems;
•	 economic objectives, especially in relation to either small- or large-scale fisheries;
•	 social objectives, including maximizing employment and improving livelihoods;
•	 objectives related to equity, including access for only small-scale fisheries; and
•	 any other objectives (for example trade liberalization, market access etc.) which
may have impacts on this sub-sector.”
At any one time, the stated aims of fisheries management may be maximization of
production, conservation of resources and ecosystems, maximization of economic
benefits to the nation, food and nutrition security, foreign exchange generation, em-
ployment, poverty reduction, sustainable resource use or maximization of ecosystem
service provision. There may also be many unstated aims, such as rent seeking by
politicians or for powerful groups that might otherwise threaten political stability, or
appeasement of some parts of the electorate, or trade-offs with other non-fisheries
aims in other sectors.
Historically the main aim of fisheries was to increase production to satisfy growing
demand from an expanding population. Many saw the sea as full of fish, a resource
that could never be depleted (Roberts, 2007; Link, 2010). But technology and fishing
effort have proved that to be incorrect, and many fisheries are now over-exploited,
biodiversity has changed and ecosystems are damaged. The desire to harvest fish
must now be balanced by a need to do so sustainably. There is also recognition that
fisheries can play a significant role in the livelihoods of people, especially the poor, by
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
38
providing food, nutrition, employment and income. As such, the issue of equity in the
benefits that flow from fisheries is also important.
In addition to fisheries management having conflicting aims, there also seems to be a
significant divide around how those aims might be achieved. Hilborn (2007b) noted
that ecologists strongly support marine protected areas (MPAs) as a central part of
the solution whereas fisheries specialists support stopping the “race to fish” through
a change of incentives to encourage sustainability and stock building. These two ap-
proaches need not be seen as two distinct ways of looking at the world. Claudet (2011)
noted, for instance, that MPAs can have multiple objectives ranging from sustainable
use and management of marine resources to socio-economic development. Likewise,
Pomeroy (2003) recognized how co-management approaches can work well with
MPAs.
In trying to make sense of the complexities of fisheries management and to break
them down into their component parts, Hilborn (2007c) cast light on the motives and
intended outcomes of different groups of stakeholders involved in the management
process. He concluded that there are broadly four categories of fisheries objectives:
biological, economic, social and political, each with specific concerns:
•	 BIOLOGICAL OBJECTIVES: concerned with maximizing production which translates
in the traditional maximum sustainable yield (MSY)
•	 ECONOMIC OBJECTIVES: concerned with resource rent maximization through ef-
ficiency i.e. maximum economic yield (MEY)
•	 SOCIAL OBJECTIVES: concerned with distributional issues of employment, income,
maintenance of communities and food security – or maximum job yield (MJY)
•	 POLITICAL OBJECTIVES: concerned primarily with the avoidance of conflict among
the electorate and opposition from resource-users regarding management
measures – or what he refers to as “minimum sustainable whinge” (MSW).4
This gives some idea of the complexity of objectives and even of the different ways
that different groups have of looking at the fishery. It also gives some indication as to
why there is so little agreement on targets for the achievement of management objec-
tives – if the different groups are talking at cross-purposes about radically different
priorities, they are unlikely to ever achieve a consensus on what is needed. Hilborn
(2007c) suggested that the current fisheries crisis can be thought of largely as a
conflict between these different objectives, and linked these possible policy objectives
to different stakeholder groups in a way that clearly differentiates the groups from
each other:
•	 large-scale fishers may want a greater focus on economic optimization or
maximum production (depending on the management regime in place)
•	 small-scale fishers may prioritize stable, reliable yields
•	 fisheries managers operate within a highly politicized context
•	 politicians often react to policy by providing appeasement measures, such as
subsidies, to reduce conflict
•	 government scientists tend to err on the side of caution and avoid deciding where
they stand in favor of collecting more data
•	 environmental NGOs tend to focus on ecosystem and species health and the
negative impacts of fishing, concerns which tend to conflict directly with those of
production maximization and social inclusiveness.
4
	 MSW is a term first used by Pope, J.G. in 1983.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
39
In spite of the diversity of possible aims for fisheries management, Hilborn (2007b)
found a seemingly broad agreement among the fisheries management community, the
conservation world and even the resource users themselves that the future of fisheries
lies with much less fishing, lower exploitation rates, larger fish stocks, reduced
by-catch, increased concerns for ecosystems, less destructive fishing methods, more
spatial management of fisheries and more areas protected from fishing. In reviews
of schools of thought around fisheries management, he identified some areas of
agreement, pointing out a broad consensus of the need to move towards lower ex-
ploitation rates and to remove subsidies that increase fishing effort. Key elements of
the consensus included dedicated access, as well as: “quotas and allocation, fishing
cooperatives that internally allocate, territorial fishing rights for communities, groups
or individuals, and individual allocation of catch quotas” (Hilborn 2007b, 297).
The debate around the implementation of MPAs, as one form of fisheries manage-
ment measure, illustrates the increasing recognition of the importance of negotia-
tion in setting management objectives. Christie and White (2007, 1053) noted that
“[u]nclear goals and inattention to social dynamics are almost certain to result in
conflict that derails MPA implementation.” Gaining the support of communities in the
use of MPAs and other management measures is vital if fisheries and conservation
aims are to be achieved. Integrated coastal management, if planned properly and with
a sufficiently holistic perspective can provide a useful framework for bringing aims
together. As Christie and White (2006, 191) noted, the ICM process “tries to break
down the barriers erected by traditional sectoral management of natural resources as
well as the divide that exists among local government, national agencies, community
groups, and NGOs.”
Diversity in the aims for fisheries management is a fact and needs to be acknowledged
and reconciled if we are to move forwards successfully. Berkes et al. (2001) discussed
in some detail how conflicts between objectives can be resolved but ultimately this
requires agreement on a prioritization process.
Recognizing the importance of context
The level and form of complexity of fisheries and their management is not constant
but varies between places. The importance of local context and how it affects fisheries
management comes out clearly from many references. Recognizing the importance
of the local context in fisheries management and adjusting management measures to
accommodate that is very important.
The specific context in which fisheries management operates will have considerable
influence on what works and what does not. In the wider context of wilderness manage-
ment, it has been argued that there are no “right solutions” to management problems
and that these should be examined in the context of particular places, peoples, issues
and ecosystems (Belsky, 2000). Hilborn (2007b) acknowledged that different situations
call for different solutions. The local biological, ecological, political economy and socio-
economic aspects of a fishery often determine the success of management initiatives.
What works in developed countries will not necessarily work in developing countries.
Guttiérrez et al. (2011) noted that countries with high and very high human devel-
opment indices (HDIs) were more successful at fisheries management than those
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
40
with low to medium HDIs. Andrade and Rhodes (2012) found that although there is
a positive correlation between gross domestic product (GDP) at purchasing power
parity (PPP) per capita and compliance with regulations, this may well be due to other
factors such as political will, corruption and social inequality. However they also found
that population density was negatively correlated with compliance.
Hilborn (2007b, 301) noted that “[i]n countries without strong central management
structures, decentralization and locally controlled dedicated access appears to be
the best way to make the transition to biological and economic sustainability.” In
relation to community-based fisheries management (CBFM), Kuemlangan (2004)
noted that above all, “the CBFM initiative or programme should be tailored in design
and delivery to the individual country circumstances.” Bell et al. (2006) determined
that the success of stock enhancement of scallops in Japan could not be replicated in
New Zealand, which may have been due to the existence or not of the other factors
mentioned here.
While in many parts of the world there is a move towards greater engagement of com-
munities in resource management, this is not always the case. In Costa Rica, when
Alpízar (2006) compared the current level of government involvement in marine pro-
tection and fisheries management with that of the community, he concluded that, at
that stage of development, the greater role should remain with government. Francis
and Bryceson (2001) noted weaknesses in both government and traditional institu-
tions in coastal management in Tanzania that needed support, while Baticados et al.
(1998) found that even within the Philippines, fisheries cooperatives on the mainland
had significant differences in their capacities compared with those on the islands.
This pattern of dependence on specific circumstances also seems to affect specific
management measures. On the subject of individual transferrable quotas (ITQs),
Robinson (2010, 53) noted “the first best, ITQs, is barely politically feasible anywhere.
Even in the best possible circumstances, in rich, well-functioning democracies where
the stakes are high, ITQs are highly controversial … If ITQs are not politically feasible
in Norway, what chance have they of being adopted in Ghana or Sierra Leone? Very
little would be my guess.”
Rudd et al. (2003, 66) reported that complexity of tropical coastal fisheries “makes
economically efficient policy tools such as individual transferable quotas impossible
to implement …” This is likely due to a number of factors, such as the quality of
the institutions in place in terms of their governance arrangements and management
capacity, the adherence to the rule of law, the political economy, the financial and staff
resources available, the number of vessels and the number of operating sites.
Operating at multiple scales
Fisheries management cannot be addressed in isolation from other factors that affect
the fishery. Fisheries are, by the fluid and interconnected nature of the sea, part of
a bigger whole which creates the social and ecological context in which fisheries
management must operate. Attempts to externalize these wider influences from the
fisheries management equation have tended to lead to rather simplistic and often
failed management approaches.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
41
These factors that influence fisheries also operate at multiple levels. In particular,
fisheries fit inside a wider set of ecological processes that influence, and are influ-
enced by, the fisheries. There are different scales and levels at which fisheries need
to be considered (Jentoft and McCay, 1995; Raakjaer Nielsen and Vedsmand, 1995).
In this case, “levels” refers to where decisions should be made and “scale” refers to
the fisheries resource system and the management tasks to be undertaken (Sen and
Raakjaer Nielsen, 1996). It is clear that when the ecological system is large, some
decisions have to be made at the national or international levels, such as those that
deal with transboundary issues or are designed to reflect wider national development
policies. Likewise, the economic conditions that allow fisheries to function at the local
level are also influenced by the wider national
and regional economy (see Box 12). Under-
standing the need to work at these different
scales and to identify the appropriate level for
particular roles is important to understand-
ing what works in fisheries and how it works.
Legislation is generally a national role, trade
may be controlled by an international body
and the development of specific site regula-
tions may be much more local. In some cases,
roles are shared – policy and planning may be
jointly developed, and monitoring and evalua-
tion may be participatory.
The movements of water, pollution, fish
and predators across large areas, between
locations and across adjacent or connected
ecosystems can affect ecosystem function.
Likewise, water circulation patterns, climate
change effects and industrial fisheries can all affect small-scale fisheries over large
areas and time frames. Where fisheries cover large geographical areas and different
fish stocks, there may be need for higher level management functions than in the
case of the management of a small area of reef. Arthur (2005) noted the importance of
getting management of fisheries at the right scale for the size of the fishery concerned.
At the larger scales, there would appear to be greater room for generalizing the factors
that create positive social, ecological and economic benefits. Berkes et al. (2000) start
to address the generalizability issues in co-management at higher scales. However,
the most appropriate scale to manage from an ecological perspective does not neces-
sarily correspond to the most appropriate scale from social or economic perspectives
(Roe et al., 2009). This is likely to be particularly true in coastal fisheries where the
fluid and interconnected nature of the sea invites a much wider perspective, such
as a large marine ecosystem, whereas communities of resource users may be more
isolated and different from each other.
The value of managing at multiple levels has become increasingly apparent. Armitage
et al. (2012) noted that devolution of power to lower levels – closer to the level of
resource users – works best when formal policy and regulatory support from the
BOX 12:
Linkages across scales of
management
In Cambodia, the community management of
fisheries is embedded in a wider process that
links fisheries, through the provincial levels,
into national development objectives through a
Strategic Planning Framework for Fisheries 2010-
2019. This Framework allows for decision-making
to be devolved to different levels to incorporate
local needs and aspirations while also ensuring
coherence of objectives at national levels.
Source: Fisheries Administration, 2010
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
42
state are provided. However, such devolution can generate the risk of elite capture of
decision-making processes.
Wilson et al. (2006) also noted that complex scale issues are now resulting in combina-
tions of institutions working at different scales to form cross-scale networks that can
address greater complexity. While the more traditional view of fisheries management
has been a more “command and control” approach, these have not tended to create
the conservation outcomes that are desired because of the complexity and multi-scale
reality of the management issues (Armitage et al., 2012). In response, multi-level gov-
ernance arrangements involving state and non-state actors are emerging. Multi-levels
approaches are often needed to confer economies of scale on knowledge generation,
ensure coherence across policy areas, allocate rights fairly, and link national and local
priorities. This is particularly so where the effects of management in a fishery will
affect adjacent fisheries – either along the coast or further out to sea.
Even in fisheries research, the value of shared functions is being recognized across the
research cycle (Campbell and Salagrama, 2001), which has shown traditional ecological
knowledge to be very useful, especially when combined with more formal knowledge.
The interconnectedness of the marine environment suggests the need for taking a
broader perspective that links fisheries to the wider ecology and human world. This
reflects a similar change which is developing in terrestrial systems (Berkström et al.,
2012), such as the “tropical seascape” approach in the marine sphere. This approach
works with a mosaic of interlinked patches that provides a multitude of ecosystem
services and represents a level of management intervention which is receiving
increased interest. However, the knowledge of the inter-linkages and connectivity
within such systems is limited (Berkström et al., 2012).
In comparing a number of approaches to large areas for marine management (LAMM),
Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010) addressed marine management at multiple scales
from the larger scale of multiple nations down, in some cases, to the local scale with
stated aims that covered both marine conservation and sustainable development.
These approaches included Large Marine Ecosystems (LMEs), Seascapes, Marine
Ecoregions, Regional Seas and Integrated Coastal Zone Management (ICM). Large
Marine Ecosystems that cross national boundaries address marine ecosystems at this
larger scale – especially in relation to fisheries. The term (LME) is now used to define
marine management areas by agencies such as the Global Environment Facility
(GEF), the International Union for the Conservation of Nature (IUCN) and the World
Bank. The World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF) and The Nature Conservancy (TNC)
use the term “Marine Ecoregions” and Conservation International (CI) is working
with “Seascapes” (see Box 13) in the Coral Triangle Initiative (Indonesia, Malaysia,
Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Solomon Islands, Timor-Leste). The United Nations
Environment Programme (UNEP) has developed a “Regional Seas Approach” which
includes action plans for protecting the environment and delivering sustainable de-
velopment. Some form of wider ecosystem approach is an important component of
many fisheries management programs, and integrated coastal management is used in
a number of countries but particularly widely in the Philippines.
Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, (2010, iv) determined that “Large Marine Ecosystems,
Marine Ecoregions and to some extent Seascapes are all ecosystem-based in their
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
43
geography and are reasonable starting units, around which to build a programme of
marine conservation or restoration and sustainable use.” In addition, they suggested
that for all of these approaches, context is very important. They (2010, iv) noted that
all three approaches “have attained important results, yet we are concerned that the
aim of effective governance across sectors and at all levels, from local to regional, is
poorly articulated and inadequately addressed, especially in the case of the Large
Marine Ecosystems.” They also noted that “most Regional Seas Programmes are well
established and have an increasingly significant role in coastal and marine resource
management and conservation in their respective regions.” In relation to ICM they
wrote (2010, iv) that “we consider that the other approaches studied here have much
to learn from the ICM process, as they strive to overcome some of the barriers to
EBM in developing countries, such as: ineffective governance, sometimes under-
mined by corruption; local stakeholders lacking rights over resources, power in
decision-making and the means to develop alternative livelihoods; rapid social and
BOX 13:
The Conservation International (CI) seascape approach
Seascapes are large, multiple-use marine areas,
defined scientifically and strategically, in which
government authorities, private organizations and
other stakeholders cooperate to conserve the diversity
and abundance of marine life, with the ultimate goal
of promoting human well-being. In each seascape, CI
is building coalitions with governments, corporations
and civil society organizations to attain nine essential
elements.
1.	 Enabling legal framework. Seascapes generate an
enabling framework of laws, conventions, regulations
and policies that facilitate marine conservation at
local, national and regional scales.
2.	Ecosystem-based management including MPAs.
Seascapes advance large-scale management of
marine ecosystems and species through the use of
multidisciplinary scientific information to inform
effective planning, implementation, monitoring and
evaluation.
3.	Adequate institution and capacity. Seascapes
build adequate institutional frameworks and
capacity, including personnel, infrastructure, and
equipment, to make marine governance structures
(governmental, commercial and civil) work effectively
and efficiently.
4.	Private sector engagement. Seascapes promote
convergence between conservation and development
by linking the viability and profitability of major
economic activities with sustainable management of
the ecosystem.
5.	Social and political support. Seascapes increase the
social and political viability of marine conservation as
an integral part of sustainable development, and they
build broad support at all scales, from stakeholders in
local marine managed areas to national leaders.
6.	Maintenance and restoration of critical habitats and
ecosystems. Seascapes maintain or restore critical
habitats and ecosystems so that ecological processes
and ecosystem services are sustained.
7.	Threatened species recovery. Seascapes reverse
declining population trends for threatened marine
species.
8.	Human well-being benefits. Seascapes improve the
social, economic, and cultural well-being of human
communities dependent on marine and coastal
resources and ecosystems.
9.	Sustainable financing and market mechanisms.
Seascapes strive to be financially sustainable with
funding portfolios that are stable, diverse, and large
enough to implement all priority marine conservation
activities.
Source: Conservation International http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/initiatives/seascapes/pages/seascapes.aspx
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
44
political change preventing sustained commitment to EBM; scarcity of strong civil
society organisations to champion and support EBM.” Since that review, some of the
other approaches, such has the Conservation International Seascape (see Box 13)
and The Nature Conservancy approaches have reportedly placed greater emphasis
on governance issues and context-specific approaches.
Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010, 22) also noted that given the different nature –
and, in some aspects, complementary roles – of the five LAMM approaches, “it is
not surprising that their application has in many cases overlapped. In some places
the outcomes, funding and sustainability achieved may be fruits not of individual
programs but of two or more complementary, interacting approaches. An additional
question to ask, then, is whether the application of multiple approaches in the same
area, or overlapping areas, is synergistic or merely inefficiency caused by institutions
adhering to their own methodologies instead of building on what is already in place.”
Integrated coastal management is seen by many as an effective, comprehensive and
holistic way of bringing different sectors and levels together. The Philippines has
probably had the most extensive ICM experience (White et al., 2006). ICM’s effective-
ness is likely to be, in part, a result of its ability to incorporate other tools at the local
level, e.g. MPAs. Christie and White (2006, 184) noted that “[t]o be effective on a wide
scale MPAs should be embedded within larger planning frameworks such as inte-
grated coastal management (ICM) or ecosystem-based management (EBM).” These
wider frameworks are designed to balance economic development with resource man-
agement processes in cross-sectoral ways.
Ecosystem approaches to fisheries also place an emphasis on operating at different
scales. Charles and Saunders (2006) noted that from the perspective of EAF, “it is
important for fisheries management to take into account the impacts of fishing on the
ecosystem, and conversely, the impacts of the ecosystem and of other human uses of
that ecosystem, on fisheries.” The ecological aspects of fisheries need also be consid-
ered in wider development approaches where multiple use economic development is
occurring. It is important to understand that context and to adjust fisheries manage-
ment accordingly.
Clearly, there is a need for fisheries managers to look outside of their normal environ-
ment and seek solutions and linkages with other sectors (Mahon et al., 2008). This
need for integration of social, economic, environmental and political concerns and
issues is starting to take on a new form as integrated ecosystem-based approaches,
which have considerable potential to integrate sustainable resource-use management,
conservation and development into a single paradigm. The value of addressing this at
higher levels of spatial planning is becoming more generally recognized. The Coordi-
nating Body on the Seas of East Asia (COBSEA) (2011) noted that coastal and marine
spatial planning (CMSP) “is emerging as a tool of choice around the world, particu-
larly in heavily used marine areas. CMSP offers countries an operational framework
to maintain the value of their marine biodiversity while at the same time allowing
sustainable use of the economic potential of their oceans. CMSP is an approach that
can make key components of ecosystem-based management of coastal and marine
areas a reality.”
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
45
Ensuring institutional coherence
As discussed above, many fisheries are faced with multiple aims that are often conflict-
ing, and few mechanisms exist to facilitate trade-offs and choices. This can potentially
lead to a lack of policy coherence which confuses what fisheries management is trying
to achieve. Even when there is some clarity of aim, it may not be possible to predict
how implementation of policies will pan out. Overfishing can be seen as a rational
response to irrational policies (Dengbol, 2009).
Policy processes, legislative frameworks and governance structures often reflect
situations that no longer exist. As noted by Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, (2010, 4)
“[a]ccess rights, laws and institutional structures in some countries are outdated
and do not reflect social and political realities, so that governance structures have
inherent conflicts.” The historic evolution of the fishery and the forces at play within
the political economy influence the way political decisions are made and the way
fisheries managers at the national level have interpreted national policy. Much of the
past emphasis of fisheries has been on productivity increases and many government
departments are still staffed by people with skills that reflect this focus, in agencies
structured around productivity using top-down approaches. Salas and Gaertner (2004,
154) recognized this, noting: “… fishers develop and implement strategies and tactics
in response to the constraints they encounter and their intended objectives given
their particular human, social, cultural and economic contexts. Managers in contrast,
have generally made simplistic assumptions about fishers’ nature and attitudes when
defining management policies.”
There is also a need to ensure that institutional structures and processes are
enshrined in law to avoid failure in political coherence when political parties or indi-
viduals change. Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010, 4) noted that frequent changes in
political leadership can “make it difficult to secure the sustained policy commitment
over decades that EBM requires; individual and institutional champions of EBM can
counterbalance this problem but they are few and civil society organisations in many
countries are weak.” Informal discussions with key informants during the course of
the current review also emphasized the importance of this aspect in terms of ensuring
coherence between management efforts at the local level and the prevailing policy
and legislative framework within which they are nested, and in terms of the need to
evolve approaches that take account of changing political priorities over the course of
long-term management initiatives.
Ensuring the viability and sustainability of ecosystem function
Marine ecosystems are important not just for the food and income that they generate
but also for the many other ecosystem services they provide. These ecosystem
services generate benefits for local communities and wider society. A key part of
any fisheries management program must be to ensure the healthy condition of the
resources and ecosystems being fished. Without this, the harvests are likely to be
reduced and/or unsustainable.
As discussed above, greater emphasis is being placed on the larger scales involved
in fisheries management and beginning to address some of these larger ecological
issues through approaches such as LMEs, Seascapes, Marine Ecoregions, Regional
Seas and ICM.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
46
Even with smaller areas of sea, there are wider ecological considerations that need to be
included in fisheries management. According to Bennett (2005b), several studies have
found that much of the success of the management system put in place is due to the
biology of the underlying resource species being managed. Some species and ecosys-
tems respond to fishing pressure better than others. Sharks, for instance, often have to
reach a greater age to breed than many small pelagics (e.g. Peruvian anchovy) and are
thus more easily affected by overfishing. Coral reefs seem to be very susceptible to sea
water temperature increases and, where local fisheries are under pressure from over-
exploitation, a decline in habitat can enhance the negative effects of fishing pressure.
A University of Washington study of some 230 fish stocks emphasized the impact of
environmental conditions on potential fish harvest (see Box 14).
Addressing the wider ecosystem needs will often require combining several ap-
proaches to management. The concept of marine protected areas (MPAs), one of
the main measures discussed in the literature to ensure the viability and sustainabil-
ity of ecosystem function, is used widely across fisheries with mixed results. Many
consider MPAs a central tool in marine ecosystem-based management of tropical
inshore fisheries (Rudd et al., 2003) and there is now substantial evidence to indicate
that, within MPAs, species tend to live longer and grow bigger, and that biomass
increases, especially among sedentary and benthic species (Roberts et al., 2001; Gell
and Roberts, 2002; Rudd et al., 2003). These larger, more abundant fish may be benefi-
cial for tourism. Protected areas can also play an important role in stock enhancement
and restocking programs to allow adequate growth and spawning (Bell et al., 2006).
Roberts et al. (2005) argue that no-take MPAs can also protect against over-generous
fishing quotas, which are often set based on poor information about the fisheries
stocks available or on a political reluctance to upset fishers. MPAs are part of a larger
group of marine management areas which might include no-take zones, buffer zones
or limited access zones – all of which have a role to play in fisheries management
depending on the local context.
Some spill-over effects from MPAs – where
protected species migrate into the unprotect-
ed area – are also reported. The effect of this
will depend on a number of factors such as
the time taken to reach a point where density-
dependent movement is achieved (Rudd et
al., 2003) – which will vary among species,
depending upon their behavior and natural
ranges (Tupper and Rudd, 2003). This time
needs to be taken into account in order to
consider the extent to which excluded fishers
will be affected by lost fishing opportunities
before beneficial spill-over effects are seen.
At the time of their study, Rudd et al. (2003)
recognized that it was generally unknown if
the benefits of greater catches from spillover
were sufficient to offset lost catches from
the MPA. Pitcher et al. (2000) showed that
boundary porosity had a strong influence
BOX 14:
The drivers of fish abundance
It is often assumed that the potential harvest of fish
is dependent upon their abundance, but a recent
study suggests that we may have to rethink some
assumptions. The University of Washington-led
study suggested that harvestable amount was
only closely linked to abundance in 18% of 230
fish stocks assessed. For the other 82% of stocks,
potential harvest was primarily controlled by
irregular shifts in environmental conditions or was
random and not controlled by either abundance or
shifts in environmental regimes.
Source: University of Washington http://www.washington.
edu/news/2013/01/14/potential-harvest-of-most-fish-
stocks-largely-unrelated-to-abundance/
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
47
on the success of marine reserves. One obstacle to MPAs as an effective fisheries
management tool is that, while the fish that stay within the MPA are afforded pro-
tection, those outside are subjected to greater harvesting pressure unless effort is
reduced. While the exploitation of resources inside protected areas on a sustainable
basis is reported to improve the living conditions of people who depend upon the
protected resources (Andrade and Rhodes, 2012), there can also be negative effects.
McConney and Charles (2008) noted that MPAs can lead to conflicts over resources,
but the extent to which such issues arise tends to be influenced by design and gov-
ernance arrangements.
MPAs have a role to play in fisheries management systems, particularly when com-
munities are directly involved in their design and management. Community-based
MPAs are designed to meet both small-scale fisheries management and conservation
needs. In addition, when run by interested and informed people through collective
action, they have proved an effective approach (Christie and White, 2006). In recogni-
tion of the role of communities in environmental protection, in 2003, the African Heads
of State amended the African Convention on Conservation of Nature and Natural
Resources to promote the establishment of community-based protected areas (Tobey
and Torell, 2006). MPAs, as part of a wider ICM approach, are having some success in
some parts of the world (White et al., 2006). For example, the Philippines has estab-
lished more than 1,100 MPAs, of which at least 20 percent are reportedly achieving
their management targets (Lowry et al., 2009) (See Box 15).
Adaptating to external pressure and changes
Fisheries are always changing and often in ways that cannot be predicted (see Box
14). Climate change is having considerable effects on fisheries, and fuel and food
prices are changing rapidly. Even with the best will in the world, plans will need to be
adjusted and changed over time. Being able
to adapt to these external pressures will be
an important function of future fisheries
management.
The coast is in a constant state of flux and
is subject to major upheavals from time to
time. Coastal and marine social-ecological
systems are characterized by their high
degree of risk and uncertainty (Ferrol-
Schulte et al., 2013). Fishers, fish farmers
and their communities around the world
tend to be vulnerable to natural disasters
because of their locations, the characteris-
tics of their livelihood activities, and their
overall high levels of exposure to natural
hazards, livelihood shocks and climate
change impacts. As exposure and vulner-
ability to these hazards is increasing (FAO,
2012a), the ability to predict, prepare for,
cope with and adapt to change will be critical
to any fisheries management situation.
BOX 15:
Community-based coastal resource
management – success or failure?
There have been a number of assessments of the
effectiveness of community-based coastal resource
management (CBCRM) programs in the Philippines
where MPAs play a major role. Approximately
91% of the over 600 MPAs in the Philippines are
managed under the CBCRM framework. In 1997,
19% of the 47 completed CBCRM programs survived
after external funding was withdrawn.
In 1999, 10% of the 439 MPAs in existence were well
enforced. In 2004, 156 MPAs were evaluated and
44.2% were found to be successful. This suggests
that success increases over time.
Worldwide the estimates of successful MPAs vary
from 10–30%.
Source: Maliao et al., 2009
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
48
Climate change
Climate change is now well recognized as having potential effects on fisheries that are
widespread and significant (Cochrane et al., 2009). Climate change is already affecting
the distribution and movement of fish stocks. It is also affecting coral reefs through sea
temperature rise, and increasing coastal inundation. Extreme weather events, such as
tidal surges and storms, are also on the increase. These not only affect the social,
economic and cultural aspects of fishers’ lives directly, they also affect fishing com-
munities located on coastal margins. Loss of life from such events is more common in
developing countries. From 1970 to 2008, more than 95 percent of deaths from natural
disasters were in developing countries (IPCC, 2011). The poor are often affected most
in these situations, as they inhabit the higher risk environments (Blaikie et al., 1994).
Food and fuel prices
Global food and fuel prices change the costs and benefits of fisheries, as well as the
tourism trade, which can be a significant market for many small-scale fishers, such
as those in the Caribbean. In addition, global terrorism and economic decline affect
markets and especially tourism which, in turn, directly affect fish sales and alternative
employment opportunities.
Population and development
Increasing coastal populations and coastal development have a significant effect on
coastal habitats and pollution. While coastal tourism brings opportunities to coastal
communities, it also increases stress on water and land use. Inland infrastructure,
such as dams and factories, is also beginning to affect water quality and flows into
coastal areas.
While it is unlikely that all forecasts will be consistently accurate in the fisheries
management process, McConney and Charles (2008) noted the importance of
learning to live with uncertainty, rather than seeking more sophisticated fisheries
models. Box 16 provides an example of how coastal management is evolving to
address uncertainty.
Allen and Gunderson (2011) suggested that there are specific circumstances where
adaptive management can be effective – especially when the situation is controllable
but uncertain (see Box 17). Adaptive co-management can be defined as an approach
based on collaboration among agencies, researchers and local stewards where natural
resource management is seen as a process of controlled experiments that need to be
monitored and improved upon (Moberg and Galaz, 2005).
There is growing support for adaptive management processes that foster resilience
and flexibility (Mahon et al., 2008; Allen and Gunderson, 2011; Evans et al., 2011b).
Alpízar (2006) noted that co-management and community-based management ap-
proaches have the potential to respond to change and dynamic conditions more quickly
than central programs because they are closer to where these changes are being ex-
perienced. Berkes et al. (2000) pointed out that traditional management systems have
certain elements in common with adaptive management strategies, such as: i) man-
agement rules are locally crafted and socially enforced by users, ii) resource use tends
to be flexible and change with circumstances, iii) accumulated knowledge allows ap-
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
49
propriate responses from ecological feedback, iv) a diversity of resources is used for
livelihoods thus keeping options open, and v) qualitative approaches are used, rather
than working towards quantitative yield targets. They also discussed how traditional
ecological knowledge “can be viewed as a ‘library of information’ on how to cope with
dynamic change in complex systems” (Berkes et al., 2000, 1259). They also pointed out
that adaptive management and traditional practices emphasize process and accommo-
date change as part of that process, and that
by “responding to and managing feedbacks
from ecosystems, instead of blocking them
out, adaptive management seeks to avoid eco-
logical thresholds at scales that threaten the
existence of social and economic activities, as
do some traditional management systems”
(Berkes et al., 2000, 1260). In relation specifi-
cally to MPAs, Christie and White (2006, 211)
said that “[i]t is apparent that a well-managed
MPA requires an adaptive management
approach.”
The external changes not only affect people,
they also affect the environment. Increas-
ingly climate change is seen to be affecting
abundance and distribution of coastal species.
One argument for MPAs in fisheries is that
the levels of uncertainty associated with
change require a risk buffer that MPAs can
provide for the wider marine ecosystem. The
BOX 16:
Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region
INTEGRATING EMERGING ISSUES AND MODERN MANAGEMENT APPROACHES
The  Spatial  Planning  in  the  Coastal Zone  Disaster 
Prevention  and  Sustainable Development  Project
was developed by the Coordinating Body on the
Seas of East Asia (COBSEA) Secretariat as a post-
tsunami project during 2006. Its overall goals are to
reduce and prevent the impacts of natural disasters,
climate change and sea level rise, and to promote
sustainable development of the coastal areas in COBSEA
member countries through the application of spatial
planning for integrated coastal zone management
(ICZM) and ecosystem-based management (EBM). In
achieving the overall goal, the specific objectives are to:
•	 develop the regional policy, resource and guidance
document, Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the
East Asian Seas Region: Integrating Emerging Issues
and Modern Management Approaches
•	 strengthen national capacities in sustainable coastal
spatial planning through the application of the
adaptation of the document into national needs
and capacities for the COBSEA countries for spatial
planning and disaster risk reduction
•	 enhance the capacity of countries to integrate the
consideration of new concepts such as climate change,
ecosystem based management, disaster risk reduction
and integrated land-sea planning into their existing
national spatial planning procedures and systems.
Source: COBSEA, 2011
BOX 17:
Management approaches for
different situations
Source: Allen and Gunderson 2011, adapted from Peterson
et al., 2003
Controllable
LowHigh
Uncertainty
Uncontrollable
Controllability
Adaptive
managment
Maximum
sustainable yield
Scenario
planning
Build
Resilience
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
50
fact that MPAs may have a role to play in building ecological resilience (Rudd et al.,
2003) has never been as important as now when, in many parts of the world, climate
change is an uncertain process.
When looking at how community-based systems for commons management can be
used to scale-up approaches, Berke (2006) noted that “it may be more illuminating to
approach the debate by suggesting that commons management in many cases should
be understood as the management of complex adaptive systems …”, and that such
systems are affected by a multitude of outside forces which affect them.
However, adaptive management approaches are not without problems. Allen and
Gunderson (2011) identified a number of conditions that can negatively affect the
success of adaptive management when:
•	 stakeholders are not fully engaged in the process
•	 ecosystems are very complex
•	 unforeseen events occur – such as natural disasters which are on the increase in
many areas where climate change is expected to be significant
•	 managers are too prescriptive about how they respond to change
•	 the desire to learn overtakes the desire to act
•	 learning does not feed back to policy
•	 hard decisions are avoided
•	 leadership is absent, dogmatic, non-inclusive or biased in a particular direction
•	 planning takes the place of action.
There will always be uncertainty in the management of fisheries which are complex
social-ecological systems, and this will lead to unpredictability. In addition Ferrol-
Schulte et al. (2013) noted that, in poverty stricken areas, the necessary funds and
know-how to manage resources adaptively is often lacking. A sustainable livelihoods
approach can be a useful tool to address the complexities of social-ecological systems
in coastal areas and assist adaptive planning.
Adaptive management takes learning as a necessary starting point in the struggle to
confront and respond to this uncertainty, according to Armitage et al. (2009). They
noted that adaptive management is not a governance panacea and will not be suitable
in all cases, and that tools are still being developed. They also identified ten key condi-
tions for successful adaptive co-management:
•	 a well-defined resource system
•	 small-scale resource-use contexts
•	 clear and identifiable set of social entities with shared interests
•	 reasonably clear property rights to resources of concern
•	 access to an adaptable portfolio of management measures
•	 commitment to support a long-term institution-building process
•	 provision training, capacity building and resources for local-, regional- and nation-
al-level stakeholders
•	 key leaders or individuals prepared to champion the process
•	 openness of participants to share and draw upon a plurality of knowledge systems
and sources
•	 national and regional policy environment explicitly supportive of collaborative
management efforts.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
51
However, as Gondo (2008) noted, adaptive co-management systems and tools are still at
an early stage of development and should be treated with caution. Gondo also pointed
out that a key part of adaptive co-management is the need for continuous experimenta-
tion and experience in dealing with the associated problems. This is not new for fisheries
managers, who have experimented with management measures over decades.
6.3	 Factors affecting technical implementation
While the above factors tend to apply to a larger design scale, there are others that are
more concerned with technical issues. Although these classifications are not set in
stone, these technical issues can include the allocations of rights, the need to change
structures and processes incrementally in order to accommodate the local pace of
change, ensuring that the right things are done with the right institution and that
decisions occur at the right level, acknowledging the importance of the local political
situation and factoring it into management decisions, recognizing the importance of
balancing costs and benefits of management, and addressing the importance of local
and global markets.
Establishing legal group rights and responsibilities
Across the range of fisheries management approaches and themes discussed above,
rights are playing a more and more central role in what is done. There is a growing
move towards greater and more sophisticated approaches to rights that combine
fisheries and human rights. This is a first step towards connecting fisheries to the
wider well-being of coastal communities (Charles, 2011). While fisheries rights can
take many forms, there seems to be growing support for community-based rights in
small-scale fisheries. Recognition of this linkage between community-based systems
and welfare of communities is gaining momentum (e.g. Copes and Charles, 2004) but
lacks supporting data, particularly on the multiplier effects across communities.
The need for controls in fisheries and the recognition of the finite and exhaustible
nature of fish has encouraged a stronger focus on rights around fishing. This has
been closely linked to two key problems associated with common property resources,
namely that: i) exclusion or control of access is difficult and ii) each fisher’s activity
subtracts from the potential gains of other users (Berke, 2006). There is now wide-
spread acceptance among fisheries academics and managers that some form of rights
in fisheries is essential to the success of fisheries management.
According to FAO (2012a), such approaches do have potential to rationalize and
improve returns in small-scale fisheries and increase resources rents at the national
level. However, they need to be implemented in ways that provide for rent distribution
methods that include the poor and vulnerable.
Huppert (2005, 201) noted that “(t)he controversies over fishing rights take three
forms: disagreements over the meaning and intent of fishing rights, disputes over
the distribution of rights and associated economic gain, and concern for disruptions
imposed on people who are dependent on the ‘old order’.” The initial allocation of
rights can be particularly difficult and controversial (Pearse, 1992). Anderson and
Libecap (2010) suggested that, in the allocation of rights, the allocation along the lines
52
of first-possession, or “grandfathering” can make both economic sense (they are more
knowledgeable about the resource and thus often lower cost) and institutional sense
(by suggesting that historic engagement is likely to ensure rights of access). They
said that in community-based fisheries where the participants are often poor but well
informed about the resources, “grandfathering” is likely to generate local support for
management measures.
Overall, the practical experience of using individual transferrable quotas (ITQs), one
of the most commonly promoted forms of individual fishing right, is seen as encourag-
ing as a rights-based approach. Yet, in 2008, ITQs were found in less than 2 percent
of the world’s fisheries (Costello et al., 2008). According to Leal (2010), they had
generated considerable benefits in the form of higher income for fishers, improved
product quality for consumers, reduced fleet excesses, and largely maintained harvest
with TACs. But these benefits have largely been associated with developed countries.
ITQs are also beginning to be used in those developing countries where there is a
transition to more reliable legal institutions with stronger governance, e.g. in the
anchovy fishery of Peru and Chile (Leal, 2010).
While transferable quotas in developed countries have focused mainly on giving
quotas to vessels or owners, in developing countries there is increasing interest in
rights to quotas being provided to communities or specific community groups or as-
sociations For example, in the Philippines, collective action and participation would
be increased if fishers cooperatives were given exclusive rights which restrict access
and, in turn, provide greater incentives for improved resource management in the
long-term (Baticados, 2004). The balance between small-scale and industrial fisheries
needs to be examined with a view to the appropriate allocation of property rights
(Stobutzki et al., 2006).
In many developing fisheries, legally-backed exclusive fishing rights granted to
nearby communities or fishing cooperatives are likely to be a more practical form of
rights (Leal, 2010) (see Box 18). Associations
of fishers are more and more taking on the
role of government in fisheries management,
which according to Scott (2010) heralds a
new fishers’ culture. This is supported to an
extent by the fact that studies over the last 30
years have documented the capability of com-
munities to self-organize and self-regulate to
resolve problems of the commons (Berke,
2006).
Territorial use rights in fisheries (TURFs),
in practice in many parts of the world, have
been a means of traditional fisheries access
rights and, according to Hilborn (2007a): “the
most direct incentive to facilitate compliance
is the granting of territorial fishing rights to
individuals or communities. This provides a
BOX 18:
Local management of lobster
stocks
The red lobster (Panuliris interuptus) found on the
west coast of Baja California, Mexico, is harvested
by fishers’ cooperatives under concessions
established in the 1930s. Nine cooperatives work
together in a federation to manage the stock. As
an indication of success, in 2004, after extensive
scientific review, the Marine Stewardship Council
(MSC) certified that the fishery satisfied the MSC’s
criteria for sustainable fishing.
Source: Leal, 2010
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
53
strong incentive to exclude non-members … .” In much of the Pacific, small-scale
fisheries have been based on TURFs from which neighboring communities have been
largely excluded.
During expert consultations as part of this review, several respondents referred to the
success of introducing TURFS in the Chilean loco (abalone) fishery, through which
rights to fisheries in different areas are allocated to local cooperatives.
Increasingly fishing rights are being placed in the wider framework of human rights
(FAO, 2010) (See Box 19).
Incrementally changing to allow for capacity, reflection and negotiated
response
Adopting new approaches and tools for fisheries management – including those
that address wider social, economic, ecological and political concerns and are inte-
grated vertically across scale and horizontally across sectors – requires new skills
and knowledge, and also new attitudes from those involved, such as managers and
community members. In addition, getting the speed of change right is very important
to the successful management of change. In many situations, change has been intro-
duced at a pace that managers and community members find difficult to understand
and respond to.
The increased focus on the need to integrate fisheries management into wider
economic systems is reflected in a move towards more integrated, multi-sector and
BOX 19:
Rights in small-scale fisheries
At its 26th session in March 2009, the FAO Committee
on Fisheries (COFI) reviewed the outcome of the
Global Conference on Small-Scale Fisheries – Securing
sustainable small-scale fisheries: Bringing together
responsible fisheries and social development. Held in
Bangkok, Thailand, 13-17 October 2008, the Conference
was attended by more than 280 participants from 65
countries. It was preceded by a preparatory workshop
with more than 100 participants from fishworkers’
organizations and CSOs. The Conference re-enforced
the claim that small-scale fisheries have yet to fully
realize their potential to significantly contribute to
sustainable development and the attaining of the UN
millennium development goals (MDGs).
In spite of their economic, social and nutritional benefits
and societal and cultural values, small-scale fishing
communities often face precarious and vulnerable living
and working conditions. Various factors contribute to
these conditions, including insecure rights to land and
fishery resources, inadequate or absent health and
educational services and social safety nets, vulnerability
to natural disasters and climate change, and exclusion
from wider development processes due to weak
organizational structures and representation and
participation in decision-making.
The 2008 Conference identified several critical
ways forward in securing sustainable small-scale
fisheries that integrate social, cultural and economic
development, address resource access and use-rights
issues guided by human rights principles, and recognize
the rights of indigenous peoples. The Conference also
reaffirmed that human rights are critical to achieving
sustainable development.
Source: Willmann, 2010
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
54
ecosystem-based management (White et al., 2006). The increased use of integrated
coastal management (ICM) as an approach to wider ecological management systems
in coastal areas has necessitated adapting institutional and organizational structure to
accommodate the different roles and responsibilities. This has meant building skills
and qualifications across different ministries and departments to ensure a commonal-
ity of purpose, methods and language, a difficult process that should not be underesti-
mated, as shown by ICM experience in the Philippines (see Box 20).
During discussions for this review, experts highlighted the challenge of finding
the means of communicating ideas about complex management issues that are ac-
cessible to those who are unfamiliar with the terminology and concepts. Several re-
spondents referred to experiences with foreign experts in ecosystem-based manage-
ment approaches who had attempted to explain extremely complex ideas to local or
national counterparts using language that was largely inaccessible to them, rather
than breaking the concepts down into more “digestible” elements and building under-
standing incrementally.
Christie and White (2006) recommended the incremental development and the
adoption of ICM and other comprehensive frameworks such as EBM, building on past
practice to match human and fiscal capacities. Although calls have been made for larger
scale interventions to maximize ecological
function, they were sometimes done without
sufficiently careful analysis. For example, the
Large Marine Ecosystem (LME) approach
moved ahead with little empirically grounded
understanding of what it entailed (Christie and
White, 2006).
Incentives are often needed for local gov-
ernment to move in the direction of change
in support of ICM. For example, when the
Philippines adopted a coastal resources man-
agement (CRM) certification process which
was often provided with external financial
support, it encouraged national-level agencies
to start redefining their roles as providing
technical assistance to local government
rather than taking the lead on such initiatives
(White et al., 2006). There is also recognition
in the Philippines that networks of MPAs in
a wider ICM process require development of
network governance (Lowry et al., 2009). In
some areas of the world, MPA and other man-
agement networks have been established to
support joint learning and lesson sharing.
The Philippines has social and information
networks that assist in improved manage-
ment of MPAs. Christie and White (2006)
BOX 20:
Lessons from ICM in the Philippines
A review of experiences in coastal management in
the Philippines provided the following lessons.
•	 ICM provides the framework for local
government to implement sustainable coastal
development.
•	 Participation at all levels and allowing
interagency cooperation and cross-sectoral
integration is a prerequisite for ICM.
•	 An integrated planning process is essential.
•	 Comprehensive information systems that evolve
with planning processes are needed.
•	 Institutionalizing ICM into local government
is important for integrating into regular
development plans.
•	 Baseline information is necessary for ICM
planning.
•	 Community-based management requires
on-going support and mentoring from
government, civil society and the private sector.
•	 Sustainability of ICM cannot be determined
without time and field testing.
Source: modified from White et al., 2006
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
55
identified five effective processes derived from networking efforts that led to good
practice and scaling-up of governance: i) consensus building on common issues, ii)
information sharing and identification of core groups, iii) institutionalizing mecha-
nisms for administration, iv) sustainable financing and v) adaptive management. For
instance, at the international level, the Local Marine Management Area Network
(LMMA) is an example of a learning network, in place across Southeast Asia and the
Pacific where members exchange information and experiences.
Institutional fit and subsidiarity
Ensuring the institutional “fit” of a set of management/governance issues is increas-
ingly recognized as important (Armitage et al., 2012). This might include the suit-
ability of different institutional arrangements to address specific problems. Some
researchers, such as Folke et al. (1998) have determined that resource boundaries
rarely fit institutional boundaries. Similarly, Berkes (2006) noted “integrated systems
of human-in-nature are more likely to work if there is a fit between the level and
boundary of the ecosystem and the institution designed to manage it.” For example,
tuna in the Pacific migrate between nations, in and out of EEZs and through inshore
fishing areas. Even though many communities have successfully addressed many of
the issues associated with common property fisheries, they are still subject to many
external pressures that require solutions that respond to scale (Berkes, 2006).
In many parts of the world, traditional customary marine tenure (CMT) was the
norm and, in some places, particularly in the Pacific, CMT still plays an important
role. However, as fisheries capacity has developed and concerns over the resource
have increased, the management process in many places has become more central-
ized and developed. Some see this move from community-based fisheries manage-
ment systems to centrally controlled government systems as leading to replacement
of common-property regimes with open-access (Pomeroy, 1994). However, in many
cases, traditional community-based institutions, in their original form, are no longer
appropriate for the management of more mechanized fisheries which extend beyond
traditional grounds, involve many more people and feed into more easily accessible
and larger markets.
Kuemlangan (2004), who looked at the institutional fit between community-based
fisheries management and the legal systems in a number of countries in the Pacific,
found that recognition of customary marine tenure may provide an opportunity for
adopting more community-based systems. This raised the important question of the
legal requirements needed to establish co-management in countries with less history
of such approaches. In Cambodia, a process of consultation around the by-law on
fisheries co-management took four years. Although customary marine tenure has
worked in the past, Kuemlangan (2004) also noted that those past structures and
processes are not necessarily ideal for the future. Rather, it is better to see customary
marine tenure as a dynamic process that can inform and influence future processes.
In noting the importance of the legal and jurisdictional context in which MPAs operate
to long-term management, Christie and White (2006) also identified the following
principles for effective legal and jurisdictional norms related to MPA experience.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
56
Nested institutional and legal (national to local) systems, if balanced and supportive
of local initiatives, support MPA implementation. MPA management requires both
upward (from local to national agency) and downward (from national to local agency)
coordination and accountability.
•	 Embedding MPA management within larger management systems designed to
address larger sectoral and development processes will help address external
impacts on MPAs.
•	 Transparency, fairness and broad understanding of the law and enforcement
support compliance and reduce conflict.
•	 Clear identification of the role and responsibilities for formal and informal MPA
management bodies is necessary.
•	 The jurisdictional mandate should fit the institutional capacity of a management
body. If necessary, there should be ongoing attention to the development of insti-
tutional capacity.
A consistent national mandate for MPA implementation with adequate resources for
implementation can provide a supportive environment (Christie and White, 2006, 197).
This theme, regarding the way in which the legal and institutional context meshes
with management efforts on the ground, emerged repeatedly during expert inter-
views. It often took the form of constraints encountered by local-level fisheries man-
agement initiatives in situations where existing legislation on fisheries and manage-
ment contradicted rules and regulations being evolved at the local level. Often, the
fact that legislative functions are entirely held at the national level meant that local
administrations could not be as responsive as they wished in approving and sanc-
tioning new forms of management being generated at the ground level. The issue of
subsidiarity and the devolution of decision-making responsibility to the lowest appro-
priate level in order to support adaptive management in the field therefore seemed to
be particularly important.
Institutional fit also has cost implications (Abdullah et al., 1998). Christie and White
(2006) noted that MPA planning and monitoring can be expensive, and centralized
government MPA agencies must compete with other more pressing budget needs
such as health, economic development and education. But they also pointed out that
centralized control of management is necessary and effective in some situations, as in
the case of MPAs in Brunei.
In some cases, it may be appropriate to consider the private sector as the agency for
engaging in management as, for example, was shown in Chumbe Island, Tanzania
(Cristie and White, 2006). In such situations, it is important to balance the incentives
of society’s goals with those of the private sector. Across a number of environmental
concerns, there is a growing emergence of hybrid forms of governance that combine
state, markets and civil society (Armitage et al., 2012).
Costa Rica has split its resource management function between two government or-
ganizations, one concerned with conservation and the other with resource use. This
agency interaction is not uncommon, as fisheries departments do not always agree
with the policies of environment agencies (Alpízar, 2006).
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
57
Also, in dealing with the effect of climate change on fisheries, the more traditional insti-
tutional arrangements within government no longer fit the problems to be addressed.
Instead, this calls for incentives to be in place that will encourage different agencies and
ministries to collaborate and share information and experience, e.g. in cross-sectoral
functions such as climate change response, disaster risk reduction and ICM.
Other external considerations, such as fuel and food prices, fisheries-tourism interac-
tions, coastal development and livelihood diversification might require changes in the
types of institutional arrangements needed to implement change. Likewise, the move
from a production focus in many fisheries to a poverty reduction or food security focus
may require skills and experience that fisheries departments do not have and may
necessitate evolving new partnerships with other agencies such as NGOs. Having the
right institutional arrangements at the community level and within government is also
crucial. In some situations, localization of governance might be seen as decentraliza-
tion of function to district-level fisheries offices rather than to community organiza-
tions (Rudd et al., 2003).
Less traditional forms of rights, such as ITQs, faced implementation issues in develop-
ing countries, in part because of the lack of appropriate legal, institutional and gov-
ernance arrangements required to achieve an appropriate institutional fit. Bennett
(2005b) noted that property rights have to be equitable in their allocation but also, the
wider stakeholder group, i.e. society, must see them as fair.
Another often overlooked aspect of institutional fit is the way that external funding
can distort fisheries management processes. Project support can provide a hothouse
effect which ensures a greater chance of a fisheries management initiative succeed-
ing. However, reporting on the success of such projects during implementation may
generate a more favorable assessment than would be the case several years after
the project has finished. Likewise, donor willingness to compartmentalize the policy
process and fund some aspects of fisheries management but not others can distort
those policies, resulting in long-term adverse effects. Aid effectiveness processes have
been established to address some of these distortions.5
The situation has shown con-
siderable progress in the fisheries sector in Cambodia, which now has much greater
policy coherence and has reduced the transaction costs of policy, planning and policy
implementation (see Box 21).
The engagement of any external implementer or funder, e.g. NGO, consultancy or
intergovernmental agency, in the process of fisheries management can distort the
factors that support sustainability of positive change. The ecoregional approach
adopted by The Nature Conservancy and World-Wide Forum for Nature, works with
national and local partners and with NGOs that are committed to the kind of long-term
(15–20 year) intervention needed. However, the long-term engagement of an external
NGO can impede the emergence of sustainable governance (Bensted-Smith and
Kirkman, 2010). Such powerful organizations can influence policy implementation in
much the same way as that described for donors above, and aid effectiveness proce-
dures need apply equally to them.
5
	 For example see OECD: www.oecd.org/dac/effectiveness
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
58
Incorporating politics and political choices
Fisheries management is, in part at least, about the distribution of rights to access
resources and the distribution of the benefits from those rights. These are largely
political decisions and can be subject to both the choices of political parties and the
personal choices of politicians. These two choices manifest themselves either as overt
policies or covert forces behind the scenes. Political decisions can be some of the most
important influences on fisheries, and the political economy needs to be included fully
in the management process for it to stand a chance of being successful.
The political forces that influence fisheries management effectiveness have been
touched on a number of times in this synthesis. In management more generally, the
political aspect of environmental protection has been downplayed (Belsky, 2000) or
even externalized in the resource management equation. Economic rationalization
approaches to fisheries management tend to focus on the state capture of resource
rents for the wider application to national economic development – a political decision
which prioritizes economic impacts over other impacts. Welfare approaches tend to
focus more on the distributive aspects of resource rents to fuel local development and
secure livelihoods. Politics, power and corruption often influence how wealth is redis-
tributed in both cases, e.g. through the political economy of national governments and
through patronage at a local level.
A renewed focus on rent capture by the state is sometimes seen as a means of “introduc-
ing some logic into the policy process” (Cunningham et al., 2009). This might suggest
a level of rational thinking in economics that does not exist in politics. However, policy
is driven by politics, and political processes may have their own logic which may not
prioritize purely economic incentives. Wider political issues may concern re-election,
feeding the population now, short-term foreign exchange generation, trading fisheries
sustainability for politically more important gains, or enhancing personal wealth and/
or patronage through non-transparent means. These may well represent logical uses
BOX 21:
A sector wide approach in Cambodia
The fisheries sector in Cambodia is planned around
a 10-year Strategic Planning Framework (SPF) that
links to national development policy. The SPF was
developed through a participatory planning process
that links all subsectors together and links those to
provincial plans.
A “basket funding” mechanism is in place, which
allows donors to fund the sector according to the SPF,
rather than their own donor-generated projects. It
also has a common monitoring and evaluation system,
which uses participatory approaches to gain fishers’
perspectives on policy implementation and feeds
these back into policy.
Cross-sectoral and donor harmonization issues are
addressed through a technical working group process
and a strategy for harmonization and alignment
encourages donor procedures to harmonize with each
other and then align to those of government. There
also has been a progressive process of decentralization
of function and resources on the basis of subsidiarity.
The government-developed Cambodian Code of
Conduct for Responsible Fisheries (CamCode) provides
a framework for government, development partners,
civil society and private sector to work to a common
set of principles and guidance.
Source: FiA, internal documents
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
59
of fisheries resources if they achieve wider development aims. Externalizing the
political economy in discussions of policy is likely to lead to unforeseen outcomes.
Robinson (2010) found that most fisheries reform has occurred in well-functioning
democracies where competition is for public goods rather than private goods, e.g.
to achieve larger departmental budgets rather than personal financial gains. The
extent to which the rule of law and other legal and governance institutions function
effectively will play a major role in the form of fisheries management and who will
benefit from it. If, for instance, government officials allow foreign fishing vessels
or unlicensed domestic fishers to operate, then sustainability can be easily under-
mined (Hilborn, 2007b). There are many documented cases in the Philippines where
CBCRM initiatives have collapsed because of local politics (Maliao et al., 2009). Roe
et al. (2009), after reviewing a number of community-based natural resource manage-
ment initiatives across Africa, noted that conflicts between local groups and powerful
elites remain widespread and are often intensifying. According to Rudd et al. (2003), a
breakdown in MPA management on Sumilon Island in the Philippines was caused in
part by local politicians engaging in opportunism.
Vested interests can also be an incentive for greater or lesser involvement of the state
– if conflict over resources plays out beyond local levels, then greater involvement by
government may be needed (Wilson et al., 2006). In some situations, the government
may be provided with inadequate resources to implement management of fisheries on
their own, and it may need the involvement of the community to assist (Wilson et al.,
2006). In fisheries management, the generation of knowledge itself is not an apolitical
process. By its very nature, what scientists say has a political element because some
of the evidence goes on to inform policy and some does not (Belsky, 2000).
In discussing the political economy approach to fisheries, Robinson (2010, 54) noted
that the political economy approach “leads to a very different way of thinking about
policy than the one current in international institutions. It suggests that too much
attention is being paid to the first-best solution to this problem and not enough to
finding politically feasible ways of mitigating the tragedy of the commons.”
The key challenge here, and one widely recognized by respondents during the expert
interviews, is that these issues relating to politics and power relations in society are
too often regarded as “externalities” which cannot be influenced or addressed by in-
terventions focused on fisheries management. However, the critical role that these
factors play in influencing fisheries management outcomes is equally recognized.
This is in part attributable to the nature of projects working on fisheries manage-
ment, which do not necessarily have the skills, mandate, resources or time required
to engage at the political level. However, it is also due to a general paucity of appropri-
ate tools for analyzing and addressing the political economy surrounding fisheries
management and understanding how it can be influenced, or adapted to, during the
course of interventions.
Sustainably and equitably addressing costs and benefits
According to recent analyses of fisheries management, fisheries in some parts of the
world cost more than they generate. To generate benefits for society or for fishers, the
fisheries management and development process needs to generate surpluses. This, in
turn, means understanding the costs and benefits of the management process.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
60
At present, most of the world’s fisheries are heavily subsidized (World Bank-FAO,
2009). In 1992, FAO estimated the global fiscal deficit of fisheries at US$50 billion
[FAO, 1993]. Thus, the reference to wealth capture involved in some fisheries man-
agement approaches must seem very attractive to politicians who are faced with
small budgets, low returns from the sector and ever increasing demands on financial
resources. According to Cunningham et al. (2009), under free- and open-access condi-
tions, fisheries exploitation levels will reach equilibrium only when all resource rent
has been dissipated. While the removal of the free and open access could be seen as
the solution to this problem, such arrangements also incur costs.
For tropical inshore fisheries, transaction costs may make up a large proportion of
the total fisheries management cost, but there are limited data to assess this (Rudd
et al., 2003). Abdullah et al. (1998, 108) separate transaction costs into: 1) informa-
tion costs, 2) collective decision-making costs, 3) collective operational coast, 4) dis-
tributional costs, 5) resource maintenance costs and 6) monitoring, enforcement and
compliance costs. They suggest that the cost difference between centrally run man-
agement and co-management systems is that cost 1 and 2 are low under a centralized
systems whereas 3, 4, 5 and 6 are high, while in a co-management system the cost
structure is reversed. Copes and Charles (2004) recognized that socio-economic data
are limited for different management systems, but also noted that community-based
systems can be less expensive to manage than more individually focused approaches
such as ITQs, because of the self-regulation aspects of community based systems.
Co-management represents a shift in the financial burden from the central govern-
ment to the community, which the community may not be able or willing to support,
especially where the benefits of better management may not arrive for many years.
MPAs, as part of a program of fisheries management, do appear to have some cost ad-
vantages. Cullis-Suzuki and Pauly (2010) roughly estimated the global costs of MPAs
to be only 3 percent of fishing subsidies. But this needs to be balanced by considering
the number of MPAs that are actually operating effectively.
The work done under the DFID-funded Fisheries Management Science Programme
(FMSP) showed that, while participation in fisheries management by fishers is ben-
eficial, it also comes at a cost. Arthur (2005, 13) noted that, in order for the benefits
of co-management to outweigh these costs, “it is vital from the outset that efforts are
to develop trust and mutual respect, including respect for different knowledge types.
This requires a commitment, throughout the management process, to transparency,
accountability and empowerment as well as to explanation, developing skills, and
increasing organisational flexibility.” Analyses of marine management areas across
Belize, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Panama, Colombia and Brazil found considerable variabil-
ity in costs among locations but all sites had significant expenditure on enforcement
(Samonte et al., 2010).
If fishers are not committed to the rules, there is a particular danger that enforce-
ment costs can exceed the benefits to society that the fishery is capable of generat-
ing. There may be strong arguments for increased economic rent capture to cover at
least some of the costs to society of fisheries management, but given the institutional
weaknesses in many developing countries, this seems unlikely to be very effective
(Robinson, 2010). Many see co-management as the implementation of the principle of
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
61
subsidiarity, and that management is better done, at least in part, at lower levels. This
perhaps suggests that there is a case for greater resource rent going to local authori-
ties to assist with that management process and to facilitate the wider development
role of fisheries locally.
Taxation of fisheries might be one way to do this but, in reality, these taxes are rarely
applied in developing countries. In part, this is because governments do not have
the information to set such taxes at appropriate levels, or do not have the political
power to do so, or both (Anderson and Libecap, 2010). This is not to say that more
rational economic measures in fisheries would not be beneficial. For instance, fishers
generally do not pay for the right to fish or for the ecological costs of stock depletion
(Sutinen, 2010) and, in some situations, revenue generation from the fishery, espe-
cially if locally collected, might be beneficial for wider development.
In most developed country fisheries, a trend towards the concentration of investment
and fishing effort into fewer, larger vessels has helped the management process.
However, a side effect has been the decline of employment opportunities. In the UK
between 1938 and 2008, employment in capture fisheries fell from 48,000 people to
12,761, a loss of 73 percent of the workforce (Campbell and Cattermoul, 2009), a trend
also seen in Norway, which lost 90 percent of its capture fisheries employment in a
similar period (Béné et al., 2010). While this may be acceptable in developed countries,
where greater employment opportunities exist, it is less so in developing countries. Fur-
thermore, the transaction costs of governments collecting this rent, enforcing property
rights and delivering replacement development services to rural communities while
avoiding political interference are likely to be high, especially where the rule of law is
poorly adhered to. Legal rules, organizations and processes are central to the success
of any effort to reform fisheries management (Thompson, 2010) and their existence
and rigorous application in many developing countries is limited. Anderson and Libecap
(2010) also noted that rents created by rights-based approaches and transferred to gov-
ernment will be competed for in a potentially rent-dissipating political process.
The extent to which fisheries are seen to generate economic benefits is in part
dependent on how costs and benefits are measured. As Béné (2011) noted, “reducing
the value of fisheries to their rent … misrepresents the real contribution that these
small-scale fisheries play for the livelihoods and food security of millions of people in
Africa.” In the case of small-scale fisheries in developing countries, what is perceived
as the dissipation of rents through a failure to accurately capture and measure them
can actually represent, at least in part, the distribution of benefits from small-scale
fisheries within local communities through employment and trade. This contribution
is often not recorded in GDP figures, and so the economic role of small-scale fisheries
is often ignored (Hall and Andrew, 2011). In this sense, community-based fisheries
can play a significant role as a social policy instrument (Campbell et al., 2006). In
many countries, coastal fishing communities represent growth hubs where income
from fisheries fuels a large local economy, but these multiplier effects are often
poorly understood (Allison, 2011) and are all too often externalized from fisheries
economic calculations. Small-scale coastal fisheries have generated, and continue to
generate, employment for large numbers of people (Béné, 2011) on a full-time, part-
time, seasonal and safety net basis which often forms a very significant part of their
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
62
livelihood strategies linked into other sectors (Whittingham et al., 2003, Béné, 2011).
For many people, having a particular sectoral focus for food, income and employment
puts too much risk in one area, while a diversified portfolio of livelihood activities is
safer and may keep them out of poverty (Allison and Ellis, 2001).
However attractive the capture of resource rent by the state may seem, it is difficult
to find many examples where fisheries resource rent from small-scale fisheries in
developing counties has been captured by the government and subsequently applied
to local community development with the same multiplier effect as the fishery itself.
This role of generating rural employment and providing a safety net, which fisheries
often play in developing countries, is very important politically, especially when the
government does not have the funds to fill the gap that other approaches to fisheries
management might create.
Alban et al. (2011) provided some useful insights into addressing cost benefit analysis
of MPAs but recognized the problems involved in doing so effectively, for example the
difficulty of measuring non-market values such as marine biodiversity and the lack of
data on the effects of MPAs on wider fisheries. In addition, transaction costs are likely
to be high when using MPAs for tropical inshore fisheries (Rudd et al., 2003). After
reviewing a number of protected areas and associated approaches to management,
DeFries et al. (2007) determined that identifying “small loss-big gain” opportunities –
where big gains for management are achieved at low cost to human use – presents a
key management challenge.
While the costs and benefits of different management systems will vary greatly, there
are doubtless ways in which these costs can be rationalized through the application
of good practice. One facet of costs and benefits noted in both the literature and in-
terviews is that positive change in fisheries management requires adequate financial
support for a long period of time to be effective. Ultimately this should be self-sustain-
ing. Even in conservation-related management measures where fishers are excluded,
there may be problems in financing the operations. Andrade and Rhodes (2012)
noted that the successful establishment and maintenance of protected areas requires
political and financial commitment in the long-term. Conservation International, in its
Seascapes approach, recognizes the importance of sustainable financing and market
mechanisms (Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, 2010).
The expert discussions, held as part of the review, highlighted the need for new and
innovative sources of financing for fisheries and marine ecosystem management. The
timeframes involved in establishing effective management processes and mechanisms
are generally long and tend to stretch beyond the normal period of donor funding and
project cycles, generally exceeding the mandates of politicians and administrators
whose support and engagement is so important in bringing about change. Clearly,
over these long timeframes, the priorities of donors, supporting agencies and politi-
cians will often change, and the destination of available funding will often shift as these
priorities evolve. For example, donors or government may prioritize setting up MPAs
as a key management intervention for 2–3 years in response to wider political agendas,
but this may subsequently be replaced by a desire to focus on climate change issues
or community resilience for the next funding cycle.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
63
This can make it extremely challenging to ensure the flow of resources required to
support a long-term intervention to develop fisheries management. Those involved in
implementing and supporting such processes on the ground often speak of the need
for managers to be “entrepreneurial” in knitting together different sources of short-
term funding in order to create a coherent program on the ground, and in molding
the way in which they present their work in order to respond to changing priorities.
Alternative and innovative mechanisms for ensuring a more consistent and long-term
flow of resources into the sector are therefore attracting increasing interest in fisheries
management, just as they are already playing an increasingly important role in sup-
porting marine conservation efforts in general. A variety of models for generating the
resources to support transition to more sustainable management approaches have
been proposed.
•	 The Financial Institution for the Recovery of Marine Ecosystems (FIRME),
currently being developed as part of the WWF Smart Fishing Initiative, proposes
establishing a fund that can provide resources for the upfront costs of develop-
ing and implementing management schemes on a loan basis, secured against the
value of future fish stocks based on credible sustainable fisheries management
plans. Initial potential financing for this fund has been identified to come from
the redirection of subsidies currently directed at the fisheries sector (which are
themselves partly responsible for existing management issues). Funding would
also come from socially responsible investment from private finance, with a po-
tentially important role for more traditional grant funds from governments and
philanthropic institutions to leverage more sustainable investment sources and
support higher risk initiatives (WWF, 2012).
•	 The development of markets for seafood products produced with ecologically and
socially responsible methods has attracted much attention in recent years, particu-
larly in developed countries. This provides, at least potentially, a means of generat-
ing revenue for producers and agencies through premium pricing that can be used
to cover the additional costs of management and to cushion the social and economic
impacts of changes in management. The costs associated with labeling schemes,
which are considerable, particularly for small-scale producers, have generally been
covered to date by grant funds from supporting organizations (MRAG, 2010).
•	 Trust funds for marine conservation have become popular over the last two
decades as a means of providing longer-term financing that is not dependent
on funding for specific projects or programs. These trust funds can take several
forms, including endowments, which provide a permanent capital fund which
generates investment from interest and investment earnings; sinking funds,
which may also invest the capital provided and therefore have a limited life span;
or revolving funds, where the capital provided is maintained through user fees,
fines or earmarked taxes, such as the Belize Protected Areas Trust Fund which
is maintained by a $4.00 fee for park visitors. Trust funds often tend to operate as
sources of small grants and can provide effective long-term flows of resources into
either fisheries management or marine conservation more generally, although
they can suffer from relatively high administrative costs and are dependent on the
performance of their investments (Spergel and Moye, 2004).
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
64
•	 Debt-for-nature swaps have also attracted attention, particularly from bilateral
donors who agree to cancel part of a country’s debt in return for guarantees on in-
vestment in nature conservation. The Philippines 2002 Debt-for-Nature swap with
the United States government provided funds for small grants for conservation
over a 10-year period, some of which was spent on marine conservation activities
(Spergel and Moye, 2004).
•	 Earmarked taxes, fees and levies have been widely used in fisheries to ensure a
sustainable flow of funding into fisheries management. Issues have been raised
on occasions regarding the specific “earmarking” of funds from these sources,
as opposed to their inclusion in the overall national budget. However, countries
such as New Zealand, which has a Fisheries Services Levy and also charges a
Conservation Services Levy on specific fisheries that have high levels of by-catch
or ecosystem impacts, and Namibia, which has a Fish Catch Levy, have effective
systems in place that ensure a flow of funds to fisheries research and fisheries
management. Worldwide, these levies are found in many different forms, ranging
from taxes on tourists, hotel guests and airport users, protected area entrance
fees, excise taxes, lottery revenues and pollution fines (Spergel and Moye, 2004).
•	 Payments for ecosystem services (PES) also provide a potential source of
financing for fisheries and marine ecosystem management. Although better
developed for terrestrial ecosystems, where initial valuation and monitoring is
easier, a market for the protection of marine ecosystem services is developing,
particularly for coastal habitats and coral reefs. The valuation of the ecosystem
services involved in marine habitats is particularly challenging, and the effective-
ness of these mechanisms is particularly dependent on good governance and
strong capacity to ensure compliance. The most widespread applications have
been in more developed nations where the rule of law is strong and monitoring
mechanisms are better developed (Forest Trends et al., 2008).
To date, the application of such mechanisms to fisheries is less developed, although
fisheries has also benefitted from existing tools and their application. However, the
majority of these tools have tended to be applied in more developed countries as they
almost all depend on the availability of data (for example on the values of ecosys-
tems), high levels of monitoring (for example to ensure compliance in the protection
of ecosystem services) and the availability of the resources and capacities required to
set them up and ensure their proper functioning.
Getting market measures right
Market measures to support the sustainable harvesting of fish are becoming more
popular in developed countries as a means to enhance the management process.
Thus far, they have had limited effects in developing countries, but there is increasing
pressure for these measures.
Markets have had profound effects on fisheries in many countries in recent years. Fish
is now a significant source of foreign exchange for many countries, which has raised
its profile among politicians. There is also a growing realization among consumers
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
65
that fisheries are having profound effects on
the environment. Sustainable fisheries labels
are becoming an increasingly important
marketing device, especially in developed
country supermarkets. The extent to which
this has influenced small-scale fisheries in de-
veloping countries is limited, but the number
of cases is growing (see Box 22).
An analysis of the Marine Stewardship
Council (MSC), undertaken by Gulbrand-
sen (2009), found that the MSC has contrib-
uted to more open management processes
in certified fisheries but that environmental
benefits from the scheme may take longer
to be seen. In a report on fish certifica-
tion and eco-labeling, the OECD and FAO
(2009) highlighted that sustainability is
difficult to market. It is becoming clear that
despite consumers’ stated interests in the environmental impacts of their purchasing
decisions, their actual buying behavior, especially in relation to food, is more likely to
be determined by other factors. The current global financial crisis has seen consumer
confidence fall and their behavior increasingly influenced by price. The industry
therefore cannot, at the moment, rely on consumers being prepared to pay a price
premium for sustainable fish and seafood.
Part of the debate at the 2009 OECD and FAO Round Table on Eco-labeling and Certi-
fication in the Fisheries Sector focused on the role that eco-labeling has played in man-
agement and fishers’ behavior. According to the meeting report, at that time, there
was little concrete evidence of the impact of eco-labeling and certification on improve-
ments in fisheries management and sustainability. It speculated that eco-labeling had
achieved more as a marketing tool than as a conservation one, although the report
did go on to say that increasing evidence indicated that eco-labeling and certification
might lead to better management through the purchasing behavior of the fish retail
industry rather than through the direct demands of the public.
While market demand can influence the way fisheries are managed, there is a need
to ensure that the poorer fishing communities are not excluded from these benefits
through the cost of certification. It is also necessary to ensure that the increased
revenues that certification may bring do not act as an incentive for increased movement
into the fishery.
The need for a better understanding of how market mechanisms such as eco-labeling
and certification work across international market chains was highlighted during
expert interviews. The experts noted that the expected premiums to producers from
such schemes did not always seem to materialize or were insufficient to cover the con-
siderable costs involved in compliance with such mechanisms. UK retailers’ concern
over the use of trawler by-catch in fish feed for prawns in Thailand was cited as a specific
BOX 22:
Certification helps community
fishery in Vietnam
Ben Tre province in Vietnam worked with
government officials to implement management
measures in its clam fishery through allocating
fishing rights to local cooperatives. This improved
management of the clams and attracted the
attention of WWF which provided partial funding
toward paying for the full Marine Stewardship
Council (MSC) assessment of the fishery. In 2009,
the fishery received full certification that it was
sustainable and well-managed. In total, the MSC
certification cost $120,000.
Source: MRAG, 2010
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
66
example of a situation in which realistic alternatives for feed producers were not always
readily available and, when they were, would be likely to incur costs that they were not
confident would be recouped through existing certification arrangements.
6.4	 Factors affecting community engagement
A number of factors relate specifically to the community and the individual fishers
themselves. These relate in part to the extent to which fisheries depend upon the
coastal fisheries resources for their livelihoods, and what alternatives they have to
engage in. Bringing about change in behavior requires understanding where fishers
are coming from – what drives them – and from that understanding, building their
commitment to change. This requires participation in all levels of decision-making,
not just for fishers but for all relevant groups in the community. This participation
includes making use of local knowledge systems and people’s ability to analyze and
advise on change processes.
Understanding dependency
The extent to which communities or households depend upon fisheries as a key part
of their livelihood strategies will be a significant driver of impact within any fisheries
management system. Livelihood dependency on fisheries can take many forms and is
often a complex mixture of these.
Coastal ecosystems and their associated fisheries resources provide a wide array of
ecosystem services (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005), and poor coastal
people have quite specific and diverse patterns of dependency on these services
(Campbell and Townsley, 2013). Whittingham et al. (2003) describe the forms that de-
pendency can take. Some people, households and communities are highly dependent
on fisheries resources for all or most of their needs. These needs may take the form
of food, income, employment, a resource for reciprocal relations and to demonstrate
power, cultural values, protection from the sea (e.g. coral reefs for coastal protection),
building materials (e.g. reefs and mangroves), and areas for recreation and social
engagement. Some people may depend upon the marine resources at times when
land-based activities are less productive. Other people may depend upon the fishery
at certain vital times of the seasonal calendar and, while they only spend a small pro-
portion of their time involved in fisheries, this may be key to their survival. Yet other
people may use fisheries as a safety net to fall back on when times are very hard.
This is most prevalent where government social protection programs are not very
strong (Bennett, 2005b). Cinner et al. (2010) have shown that poorer households have
a greater reliance on fishing for primary subsistence or for income.
It is assumed, to an extent, that if other opportunities exist, fishers will leave the
fishery and take up those opportunities. This was found to be the case in Cambodia
where many of the fishers did not have a long cultural history of fishing (IMM et
al., 2003) but not the case in Kenya where fishers have a longer tradition of fishing
(Cinner et al., 2010).
More indirect forms of dependency also occur when people depend upon fish for pro-
cessing and trade, and this can be a very significant part of household income. In
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
67
many communities, the income generated through fish sales and wages in the fishery
provides a diverse array of local industries that survive because of the fishery (IMM
et al., 2005). The management system adopted for fisheries and marine ecosystems
must be very aware of the dependency of different stakeholders and how manage-
ment arrangements will affect each group.
Balancing exclusion, livelihoods alternatives and the local economy
All too often, fisheries management is seen as separate from the economic activities
that surround it. But the local economy is one of the main drivers of over-exploitation
of resources – if fisheries is seen as a business that is more beneficial than other local
activities, more people will try to enter the fishery. This is particularly important for
the poor who often have limited means to invest in equipment or land and lack the
skills to enter other industries. Thus, if people are to be successfully excluded from
the fishery, they need to have access to alternative options for their labor and capital
that provide as good, or better, returns than fishing. This is often seen as an area of de-
velopment that stands outside of fisheries management but, in reality, it is crucial to it.
As coastal populations increase and where fisheries’ entry barriers are porous, more
people will join the fishery on a full-time, part-time, seasonal or safety-net basis. A key
part of fisheries management must ultimately be the decision to allow some people
to fish and others to be excluded. If this is to be done equitably, then the different
ways in which fishers depend on and use the coastal environment and its ecosystem
services will need to be accommodated in the management system. In describing the
underpinning rational for the need for closer links of fisheries in the wider economy,
Charles and Herrera (1994, 1315) noted “…fisheries of developing regions typically
face a trio of key problems: over-exploited stocks, an over-extended fleet and a lack of
alternative employment outside of the fishery. In addressing these, the late economist
Ian Smith (1981) expressed well a fundamental but oft-neglected reality: to be just,
feasible and effective, policies cannot be restricted to resolving one of two of these
problems alone.” Charles and Herrera (1994) also discussed the points that Smith
made regarding the consequences of not taking all three elements into account,
namely: i) inhumane impacts on the fishers, ii) political infeasibility due to community
reaction, or iii) failure due to fishers’ non-compliance.
Ultimately some people will need to seek alternatives, or at least reduce their depen-
dency through a more diversified livelihood portfolio, for some or all of the year. This
requires an understanding of how fisheries and the wider economy interact. Graham
et al. (2006) noted that “[m]uch has been written about economic development in
countries, in regions, and in communities, but little about the connection between
community-based fisheries management and economic development.” This is a sig-
nificant limitation, given how dependent those in the fisheries are on the wider local
and national economy. This economy generates markets for capital and labour that
affect investment in fisheries. Community-based fisheries management can be greatly
influenced by the economic viability of the surrounding community.
Limited diversity of livelihood opportunities are both a factor driving people into
fisheries and a barrier to their leaving. As a consequence, in coastal communities
where there are few alternatives, more people will join the fishery or will need to
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
68
migrate away from their communities. Kuperan and Jahan (2010), for instance, iden-
tified a lack of alternatives as a major obstacle to fisheries management in coastal
Bangladesh, where population pressure and non-compliance to fisheries regulations
is accelerating over-fishing, noting that “the resource can be better managed and the
compliance level can be improved if the fisherfolk have other means of generating
income to manage their losses for the regulatory measures” (Kuperan and Jahan,
2010, 112).
In many coastal fisheries where fishing is seen as the occupation of last resort, this
will be very difficult to achieve. As Tobey and Torell (2006, 853) noted, regarding
the poor “[w]ithout other income generating options in the near future, the loss of
nearshore marine fisheries could lead to a downward spiral of food security, income
and vulnerability of rural coastal households.”
Providing opportunities for the poor to move out of fisheries permanently, or at least
reduce their level of dependency, is also fraught with difficulties, given their multiple
deprivations: low income opportunities, weak market power, poor access to land-based
resources, weak political access and low inclusion in public services such as health
and education. Even under rights-based fisheries, Swan and Gréboval (2005) noted
that regulating access and dealing with displaced fishermen are particularly important
problems that must be overcome. This emphasized the need to view fisheries within
the wider local and national economies.
However, for many people involved in fisheries, the household will already support
a portfolio of livelihood activities reflecting, e.g. levels of wealth, skill, seasonal op-
portunities and available alternative or additional livelihood options (Allison and
Ellis, 2001; IMM et al., 2005; Walmsley et al., 2006; Cinner et al., 2010). These will
often be linked into the wider aspects of the local economy, and fisheries manage-
ment should, ideally, be seen as part of the wider process of community develop-
ment (Jentoft, 2000). Understanding fisheries from a livelihoods perspective can be
a useful way of understanding dependency and the linkages to the wider community
(Ferrol-Schulte et al., 2013). Livelihoods approaches encourage a focus on the con-
tribution of fisheries to wider local economic development, with the opportunities in
the wider economy providing livelihood alternatives for fishers which might lower
the pressure on stocks and improve the livelihoods of those involved. Closer inte-
gration of the fisheries economy with the wider local economic development should
also assist in shifting the safety net/buffering role that fisheries provide for rural
labor (Béné, 2003).
Co-management processes in the Philippines have started to move beyond fisheries
management issues and started to address wider development, eco-tourism, alterna-
tives to fishing and livelihood enhancement (Wilson et al., 2006). This has also been
recognized by ICM programs, which cover a much wider part of the economy and
need to include a diversity of livelihood opportunities (White et al., 2006). In Tanzania,
there are also efforts to promote livelihood diversity (see Box 23), and in South Asia,
efforts to develop a systematic approach to sustainable livelihood enhancement and
diversification (SLED) have proved successful (Cattermoul et al., 2008).
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
69
From studies in Costa Rica on the diversifica-
tion of livelihood opportunities for fisheries
households, Charles and Herrera (1994) de-
termined that the role of livelihood opportu-
nities for fisher households may be enhanced
by taking a more integrated approach to
management which addresses value addition
within the sector and by addressing both
micro-level (community) and macro-level
(industry) changes to alternative livelihood
options.
The sequencing of the introduction of liveli-
hood alternatives is very important (Catter-
moul et al., 2008). If restrictions on entry
to the fisheries are introduced as part of
a fisheries management process before
adequate and acceptable alternatives are developed, then fishers are likely to invest
in means to circumvent management measures. It is important to develop livelihood
opportunities early in the management process. Ideally, these should not be the sorts
of opportunities that are only services that rely solely on the income generated by
fisheries. This is likely to create a localized “resource curse” situation. The “resource
curse” reflects the poor potential of natural resource dependence to generate the
economy-wide innovation needed to sustain growth (Collier, 2007; Barbier, 2007).
This happens because a large amount of human, physical and financial capital often
gets directed at the development of those resources at the expense of the rest of the
economy (local or national). The spillover effects of natural resource exploitation tend
to be less than those of manufacturing and service sectors, which reduces the diversi-
fication effect in the wider economy. This may be particularly pronounced in smaller
economies where development resources are few anyway. Small-scale fisheries have
the potential to be a “growth pole” in many coastal communities but, all too often, they
tend to generate economic activity that perpetuates over-exploitation and dependency
on the fishery. In reality, small-scale fisheries are a valuable resource that can lead to
economic diversification if used properly.
While livelihood diversification is not always a successful approach to shifting pressure
from fisheries resources (Tobey and Torell, 2006), there are examples where a par-
ticipatory approach which facilitates the selection of livelihood opportunities by the
communities themselves, rather than imposed from outside, can work (Cattermoul et
al., 2008). Micro-finance is very important to stimulate or facilitate livelihood alterna-
tives (Tobey and Torell, 2006), as are wider mechanisms of support such as technical
training, market information and development of entrepreneurship skills (Salagrama
and Koriya, 2008).
Building capacity
Fishers and their wider communities have an important role to play in fisheries man-
agement, but first they need the skills to understand the management process and the
knowledge required of their roles and responsibilities. Good leadership can play an
BOX 23:
Livelihood diversification
In Tanzania, MPAs have used the generation of
diversified livelihood options as a way of reducing
pressure on resources. Some 19% of male-headed
and 16% of female-headed households surveyed
have been involved in these activities.
Diversified income-generating activities included:
agriculture, improved fishing techniques and
marketing, apiculture, tree nurseries, rabbit fish
cage culture, oyster farming, seaweed farming, and
handicrafts such as weaving, .
Source: Tobey and Torell, 2006
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
70
important part in this but can also distort the outcomes. Building community capacity
to participate, engage, share and cooperate can be equally as important.
Good leadership of communities and groups seems to be an important ingredient of
sound management as does good community cohesion. With an analysis of 130 co-
managed fisheries across 44 countries, Guttiérrez et al. (2011) identified strong lead-
ership as the most important attribute contributing to success, followed by individual
or community quotas, social cohesion and protected areas.
However, White et al. (2006) noted the importance of building durable institutions
that will be self-sustaining after leadership change. Processes such as ICM are seen as
valuable governance mechanisms that can help this and can enhance the local govern-
ment leadership role.
In his discussion of co-management on the Mekong River in Laos, Baird (1999)
mentioned that when solidarity increases through co-management, there may also be
other spin-offs such as community development.
A counter to good leadership can be dominant elites who look after themselves
and their immediate supporters and colleagues. Patronage systems can be seen as
powerful allies in management where a village chief or local elite is able to ensure
compliance to management by a particular group. Participation in co-management
does not always mean community empowerment and, even when the community
is more empowered, it does not necessarily mean that such empowerment is even.
Local elites may have a vested interest in moving the co-management process in
certain directions or in presenting personal choices as those of the wider community.
Such patronage is likely to exclude some key stakeholder groups, especially the
poorest and most marginalized. This can be particularly damaging when managers
or scientists assume a certain degree of homogeneity within communities and that
the leader represents different groups fairly. This is particularly so where the effects
and impacts of MPAs are being measured, and the exclusion of fishers is likely to
have very different effects on different groups of people. Women excluded from
gleaning local reefs on foot, for instance, are likely to suffer much more from a local
exclusion zone that men with boats who are able to travel further afield. Women may
lose not only local access rights but the ability to fish anywhere and the opportunity
for social engagement with other women in the community where gleaning is a col-
laborative activity.
But paradoxically, local elites are essential to providing the leadership and legitimacy
of co-management structures and processes (Wilson et al., 2006). NGOs can have
a role in reducing the adverse effects of these elites through building rights com-
mittees and other transparency mechanisms.6
Civil society more generally has a par-
ticular role to play in fisheries management where communities are poorly organized
(Jentoft, 2000). The power of such organization can be seen in Box 24.
6
	 The Hunger Safety Net Programme (HSNP) outlines rights committees in pastoralist communities in Kenya
http://www.hsnp.or.ke/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=142%3Arights&catid=34%3Aarticle
s&Itemid=1
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
71
Rudd et al. (2003) noted that social capital in
communities is very important for influenc-
ing decision-makers, for building solidarity
within communities and for forming bridges
among communities. This is important for
developing learning networks and sharing
ideas. According to Armitage et al. (2009),
successful adaptive management calls for
clear and identifiable sets of social entities
with shared interests.
The extent of the community’s ability to
organize itself to work within a co-manage-
ment arrangement is a significant issue
affecting the potential impact of such ar-
rangements. Abdullah et al. (1998) found that
it can take 3–5 years to develop effective in-
stitutions.
Wilson et al. (2006) found that many co-management initiatives give the role of
building capacity to NGOs operating in the areas. They provided examples in Philip-
pines, Cambodia, Laos, Thailand and Bangladesh where capacity was strengthened
by NGOs.
During expert discussions, participants also highlighted leadership issues as being
important at levels above the community, as initiatives for fisheries management or
conservation of marine areas have often tended to be highly dependent on specific
individuals with the commitment and charisma to encourage wider support for such
initiatives, whether in local government, the NGO sector or at higher policy-making
levels. They saw this dependence on specific leaders as representing vulnerability,
because such individual “champions” are subject to generational change or regular
transfer to other locations or fields of work, especially given the long timeframes often
involved in fisheries management development.
Work in Indonesia within the Coral Triangle Initiative is looking at how more systemic
incentives can be created – within schools, higher education and government depart-
ments – to encourage people to commit to and engage in marine management issues.
The goal is to generate a wider group of leaders of change across generations and
institutions who can provide more sustainable leadership for change processes in the
long-term.
Engaging with fishers’ motives and preferences
A key part of working in partnership with fishers in the management process is un-
derstanding their motives and preferences. Without this, management assumptions
can be well off mark.
In addition to understanding dependency of different groups, it is important to un-
derstand what drives fishers to do what they do and how they will react to change.
BOX 24:
Post-cyclone cooperation
On India’s Orissa coast, many migrant fishers had
coalesced into communities but lacked cohesion
and organization. After the Orissa cyclone in 2000,
the NGOs providing support insisted that the
community organize itself and form groups through
which support could be provided. Although it had
little previous experience of working in groups,
the community discovered the benefits of mutual
support and cooperation very quickly. Residents
reported that this alone had transformed the way
they function as a community and influenced all
aspects of their lives.
Source: IMM, 2001
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
72
Hilborn (1985, cited in Salas and Gaertner, 2004) suggested that the collapse of many
fisheries is due to misunderstanding fishers’ behavior rather than a lack of knowledge
of fisheries resources. Understanding what motivates fishers is an important part of
deciding how to manage a fishery according to Hilborn (2007a), who also noted (2007a,
286) that “… fishermen respond to regulation in ways that often surprised managers,
and managers must understand the motivation and incentives for fishermen to under-
stand how they respond.”
Thecontextinwhichfishersconvertpolicymeasuresintoactionsissubjecttoanumber
of influencing factors that can change the course of those actions. These include what
their priorities are, their cultural norms and expectations, their perceptions of risk,
their relationship with managers and politicians, conflict and cohesion with commu-
nities, and beliefs around the sustainability of the resource. In addition, these may
differ from those of managers. Salas and Gaertner (2004, 154) recognized this when
they said: “…fishers develop and implement strategies and tactics in response to the
constraints they encounter and their intended objectives given their particular human,
social, cultural and economic contexts. Managers in contrast, have generally made
simplistic assumptions about fishers’ nature and attitudes when defining management
policies.” This can be very important in a management context. As Hilborn (2007a,
290) noted: “[f]isheries management works much better when there is good coopera-
tion between managers, scientists and the fishing fleets …” This cooperation depends
on people understanding where each is coming from.
Understanding and responding to the motives of fishers is not straightforward. In
an attempt to counter the potential effects of a change in community attitudes about
MPAs, the Philippine government introduced the National Integrated Protected Areas
Systems (NIPAS) to replace community-based management with national government
direction. It did so because it feared the community might choose to turn its back on
conservation objectives and exploit the MPA for economic benefit. This has report-
edly generated much resentment within the communities and reduced effectiveness
of the MPA (Hind et al., 2010).
In many fishing communities, there is a tendency for boys and girls to follow in their
parents’ footsteps and join the sector. In some more traditional communities, fishing
may be seen as a right or an obligation as a career. This can influence people’s in-
clination to leave the fishery or not join the sector. This is not true in all situations,
especially where fishers are part-time or seasonal operators. Where viable alterna-
tives offer better benefits, those people will generally take them up. However, many
fisheries people have few other skills and knowledge, which may make leaving much
more difficult for them.
Fishers are apt to view resources in terms of their time preferences or the way they
discount future benefits in current prices. People who have high discount rates favor
current gains much more than the same gain in the future. Time preference influences
the behavior of fishers, as well as those people making policy and those implementing
it. For politicians the time horizons are generally short – 2 to 6 years (Sutinen, 2010)
– because of the time between elections. The time preference for donor agencies can
be even shorter, leading to substantial distortions of policy as their funding priori-
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
73
ties fluctuate in a given sector or policy area. Longer-term considerations are often
less important to them than short-term gains. This can become a significant problem
because when major institutional reform is needed for fisheries management change,
it may take many years. After reviewing the legal requirements for community-
based fisheries management in the Pacific, Kuemlangan (2004, 32) noted that “[a]ny
external programme for assistance (for CBFM) should be for a longer term duration
than normal technical assistance or development projects.” This is not only required
to address community-level institution building but also to build government under-
standing of the benefits of CBFM and to facilitate the necessary policy and legislative
changes.
Fishers also often focus on the short-term. In open access fisheries, where fishers
have no secure claim over future outcomes from the fishery, they are encouraged to
reap the benefits quickly before others do. There are also uncertainties about future
fisheries policy, markets and fish stocks. Poor people also sometimes have shorter
time horizons because they discount benefits at higher rates suggesting a lesser com-
mitment to environmental management (Holden et al., 1998). In Tanzania, Tobey and
Torell (2006) found that poverty may be a limiting factor to conservation efforts, in
that poverty often forces people to engage in destructive practices.
If the time preferences of managers and fishers are very different, then giving fishers
or local communities the rights to harvest fish resources may not always generate
the expected results. For example, rights do not necessarily confer a commitment
to sustainability. As Bromley (2009, 282) noted, “if the ‘time preference’ of a private
owner is such that income now trumps income in the future, then private owners
will be quite intent on liquidating (destroying) a renewable natural resource in order
to spend the proceeds or invest them elsewhere.” Investing current catches in your
child’s education may seem like a good investment even if it destroys future stocks.
It is also worth noting that the motivations and preferences of fishers are dynamic
and constantly changing in response to their surrounding social and economic envi-
ronment. Experience in India indicated how a combination of people’s perceptions of
the increasing competition for fisheries resources, exposure to outside ideas (in this
case during the post-tsunami relief efforts after 2004), improved communications and
access to education had led, over the course of a generation, to a significant change
in the attitudes of many fishers in South India regarding the future of fisheries and
their desire for their children to enter the fishery in the future (Townsley et al., 2011).
Understanding these different motives is important for ensuring that fisheries man-
agement systems accommodate them and work with them.
Addressing commitment, compliance, conflict and enforcement
The enforcement of regulations represents a large part of the cost of any management
process. This can be very high where fishers must be forced to comply with regula-
tions rather than where they have a commitment to those regulations. Moving from
compliance to commitment can be an important step in increasing management’s ef-
fectiveness and reducing its cost.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
74
Rights imply an entitlement which is generally supported in law. With those rights are
responsibilities which often require the sustainable use of the resources. Enforcement
involves both protecting those rights and ensuring that rights holders adhere to their
responsibilities. In traditional fisheries, the enforcement of rights and responsibilities
were often controlled by traditional authorities. The importance of these institutions
should not be underestimated. As Jentoft (2000) noted, if the community disintegrates
socially or morally, it becomes a threat to fish stocks. In many developing countries
that have introduced more formal and centralized licensing systems, the enforcement
of regulations has become more difficult with many vessels operating from many
small landing sites. In many small-scale developing fisheries, the government lacks
the funds to implement effective enforcement (Arthur, 2005).
Non-compliance to fisheries regulations undermines the effectiveness of manage-
ment measures and is a major problem in most fisheries. In their review of compli-
ance in the coastal fisheries in Bangladesh, Kuperan and Jahan (2010) recommended
examining the level and causes of non-compliance and exploring policies for encour-
aging or securing compliance because, at that moment, the chances of detection
and conviction in fisheries rule breaking in coastal Bangladesh were reported to be
virtually nil. One solution to the compliance issue, suggested by Kuperan and Jahan
(2010), called for moving towards co-management in fisheries where the additional
transparency of the approach would support greater compliance.
Unless there is commitment to the operation of management measures, there are
likely to be difficulties in getting compliance. For example, Christie and White (2007)
found that MPAs were one of the preferred coral reef fisheries management measures
– covering (at the time) 18.7 percent of the world’s reef. Yet less than 0.01 percent of
coral reefs were within no-take zones, with no poaching and at low risk. This suggested
considerable lack of adherence to the rules. Rules not only need the legal framework
to enforce them and the political will to implement enforcement but also legitimacy in
the eyes of the fishers. Furthermore, legitimacy should also be in the eyes of wider
society, but these forms of legitimacy can sometimes conflict (Jentoft, 2000).
The use of graduated sanctions is seen as important in resource management systems
(Ostrom, 2009b), particularly in relation to rights, as well as very important to the
success of fisheries management. However, all too often, this is missing, especially
in countries where the rule of law is not well established. According to Christie and
White (2006), lack of clear tenure rules can undermine MPAs, and fair and effective
law enforcement, knowledge of the law, and consistency between national and local
laws and institutional goals are important to MPA effectiveness. In-migration and
conflicts outside of the community often require the government to intervene to
resolve disputes (Wilson et al., 2006). Where communities are more homogeneous,
co-management seems to work better. Francis and Bryceson (2001, 94) noted that
“[c]onflicts of interest can be resolved or avoided by fair processes respecting coastal
communities’ systems of land/sea tenure and common property rights.”
Andrade and Rhodes (2012) implemented a meta-analysis of 55 published studies to
understand the key factors that lead to community compliance with protected area
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
75
(PA) regulations. These included:
•	 establishing cooperative relationship among all stakeholders
•	 building relationships on voluntary compliance rather than draconian enforce-
ment
•	 promoting enforcement through participatory decision-making
•	 setting rules that are clear and easy to understand
•	 setting internal and external boundaries that are well defined and recognized by
resource used and officials
•	 ensuring well trained, equipped and motivated personnel
•	 determining penalties and applying and enforcing them consistently.
Fisheries management works best if there is good cooperation among the fishers,
managers and scientists (Hilborn, 2007a), which enables the beginning of a shift
from mere compliance with regulation to a sense of commitment to making the
fishery work. As Bennett (2005b) noted, when fishers believe a stock needs sup-
porting, they will agree to limit effort. A key part of the move towards effective man-
agement must be a move from fishers’ coerced compliance to management regula-
tion towards one where fishers are committed to the success of the management
measures. Otherwise, there will be need to spend large amounts of funds and effort
to ensure compliance, which is unlikely to be achieved in developing countries that
have financial constraints. Understanding what incentivizes fishers is central to that
process (Hilborn, 2007a).
Ensuring participation and inclusion
A part of generating compliance and commitment is building support for the manage-
ment process, which requires involving fishers and their communities in the decision-
making process. This means bringing in a much wider group than just the fishers
because, in most communities, the whole local economy is closely linked to fishing
and decisions are likely to have far reaching effects. The quality of that participation
is also very important. Extractive participation – meaning the community is mined for
its knowledge and consent – is likely to be less effective than where participation is
more collegial (Campbell and Salagrama, 2001).
Participation of fishers in management decisions and processes that affect their lives
and livelihoods is important for several reasons. It generates buy-in and support
for the process, it empowers communities, it incorporates local knowledge and ex-
perience, and it can reduce costs. Recognizing that communities are not made up
of people who all have the same needs and wants is key to effective participation
(Bennett, undated).
Andrade and Rhodes (2012) found that compliance is driven primarily by local in-
volvement in the protected areas’ decision-making processes. This is because those
decisions are likely to impact upon the livelihoods of people in adjacent communi-
ties. Many protected areas around the world have been developed using exclusion-
ary top-down methods and, as such, failed to consider other important issues such
as social, cultural and political concerns. Opponents of no-take MPAs consider that
such measures have failed largely because they have been imposed on fishermen, and
they argue for the assignation of property rights to fish stocks and co-management
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
76
through the greater involvement of fishermen in decision-making processes (Jones,
2007). The effects of exclusion of fishers from MPAs will have effects and impacts that
are determined in part by the size of the enclosed area relative to the non-enclosed.
MPAs that force the same number of fishers to catch from a smaller area are in danger
of increasing over-exploitation in the areas outside the MPA at a much faster rate.
Respect for participation and inclusion is seen across the literature. Allison (2011,
11) found that “[o]nly meaningful engagement with and deliberation amongst stake-
holders can yield goals that will be seen as legitimate.” Similarly, Hall and Mainprize
(2004) said that while it may not be possible to get complete agreement on the aims
and potential outcomes of fisheries management, it is important that the views of all be
heard. Aswani and Weiant (2004) noted that when local communities are excluded from
protected area management systems, and their needs and aspirations are ignored, it
becomes very difficult to enforce conservation policies. Andrade and Rhodes (2012)
also noted that while the cost of patrolling big protected areas can be reduced by in-
volvement of local people in patrolling and management, such stewardship will only
take place if local communities feel included in the decision-making process. While
biodiversity conservation may be achieved in the short-term, marginalizing participa-
tion in decision-making, not engaging in capacity building, not enhancing governance
processes or enforcing regulations fairly is likely to lead to biodiversity loss in the
long-term. In addition there seems to be a growing recognition that stakeholder par-
ticipation needs to be sought throughout the monitoring and adaptive management
process, not just in initial planning, given the limited knowledge of how ecosystems
function (Arkema et al., 2006).
In relation to community-based natural resources management (CBNRM) in general,
Roe et al. (2009) pointed out that, to be successful, it must prioritize local interests,
agency and capacity. Bell et al. (2006) noted that in China, if the state took over stock
enhancement programs, they tended to fail because it was difficult to see who should
pay for the benefits, while those operated by local fishermen worked much better.
The role of women in decision-making around fisheries management should not be
forgotten (Bennett, 2005a). While women may play a smaller role than men in fish
harvesting in most countries, their role in fish processing and trade is vital. Fisheries
management measures can influence how much fish is landed, what sort of fish is
landed, where it is landed, when it is landed and the condition in which it is landed. A
recent study of women fish traders in Cambodia found that changes in the market for
fish had changed significantly over an eight-year period, demonstrating the dynamic
nature of the fish trade process (Asian Fisheries Society, 2013). Such changes can
be driven by the fishery itself or by outside forces, but they can radically change the
interface between fisheries management and fisheries trade.
All of these characteristics affect fish processors and traders, but can be dealt with quite
differently by men and women, the poor and the wealthy, those who are able to travel
and those who are restricted to the village for religious or family reasons (see Box 25).
Alpízar (2006) noted that the quality of participation is very important. This begs the
question: who will be involved, how are they selected and what role will they take?
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
77
The degrees of participation of small-scale fishers in fisheries research were reviewed
by Campbell and Salagrama (2001) who noted the important and valuable role that
fishers can play in research but also the limitation of such practice. Charles et al. (2009,
178) noted that participatory research and
community-based management “have consid-
erable, yet often unrealized, potential in coastal
fisheries of the world. They are, to a great
extent, two sides of the same coin. In thinking
about participatory research, we envision the
building of a co-learning environment that is
empowering for all participants…” DFID’s
Fisheries Management Science Programme
identified the role that fishers can play in stock
assessment work and how feedback from that
process improved management decision-mak-
ing (Howard and Arthur, 2005).
Jentoft (2000) recognized the relationship
between community and fisheries management
as fundamental. Fishers are often born in and
live in communities, and are enmeshed in the
social and cultural structures and processes. If
the management systems exclude the community, there is a danger that the fishers
will act in their own interests only and ignore those of wider society. This role of the
community will be important both in the design and implementation of fisheries man-
agement plans. However, Van Tuyen et al. (2010) noted that the livelihoods of coastal
people in Vietnam are often in a state of flux (as they are in most places) adding to
the complexity of planning and management in fisheries. They suggested that there
is “growing recognition among authorities of the value of engaging local fishers and
fish farmers in participatory process to resolve complex livelihood challenges, and
the development of local management bodies (newly formed Fishing Associations) as
a basis for emerging co-management of aquatic resources” (Van Tuyen et al., 2010,
327).
However, as Belsky (2000) noted, we should be careful not to replace a more top-down
theory of conservation with another where we assume that rural communities are
“ecological noble communities” or make them central to every conservation effort.
This is reiterated by Alpízar (2006) who pointed out that communities are heteroge-
neous and multidimensional, so conflicts, divisions and inequalities are likely to exist,
and decisions are not always going to be environmentally benign. Belsky (2000) also
found that not all communities have the necessary skills, governance and social struc-
tures to enable management to occur, that a focus on community management takes
the focus off the role of multi-nationals, international treaties and institutions, and
that those in control of conservation policy often do not have a strong understanding
of how communities work. In relation to reef decline, Whittingham et al. (2003, 52)
noted that “… participation is not a panacea to ensure that interventions succeed in
preventing reef decline and assuring sustainable reef benefits for poor stakeholders.”
Other key elements include: i) when participation occurs in the management process,
BOX 25:
Factors influencing fish processors
in India
Increased capitalization of the India coastal fisheries
has had a generally positive effect on the fishers
although future catches are more vulnerable to
overexploitation. However, increased landings into
fewer ports has adversely affected many of the
small-scale processors and traders. Centralization of
landings has affected access to landed fish processing
practices (especially the increased use of ice) and
fish market opportunities. These have had knock-on
effects on fishers’ household incomes.
Source: IMM and ICM, 2003
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
78
ii) how it is sustained, iii) the equitability of the participation process, iv) the extent to
which the poorer and other marginalized groups are included and v) how systems of
patronage are included.
People also need to be included in understanding the need for change. In relation
to ICM in the Philippines, White et al. (2006, 299) noted that “[p]roviding effective
feedback on biological and socioeconomic information and quantitative indicators on
fisheries and habitats as a result of effective management contributes to the under-
standing of why ICM is needed.”
An important element of inclusion often omitted from fisheries management discus-
sions is that of poverty. Where do the poor fit into fisheries management systems?
Walmsley et al. (2006) expressed that fisheries is often poorly addressed in national
poverty reduction strategies. In addition, because of their often marginalized positions,
the poor are often excluded from fisheries management systems.
Linking different knowledge management systems
A key element of participation and building commitment is recognizing the value
of local ecological knowledge and the experience-based knowledge of local fishers.
All too often, fishers are regarded as ignorant and their traditional knowledge as
inferior to that generated by more formal knowledge systems, which has often proved
incorrect. There is a growing awareness of the value of these informal knowledge
systems in fisheries management.
Knowledge management can be thought of as being composed of three components: i)
generating knowledge, ii) sharing knowledge and iii) using knowledge. Even though
knowledge is often considered that which is generated through formal science, fisher
societies have both traditional knowledge that is transferred between generations
with its roots in history, and experience-based knowledge which comes from working
in the sector. Many fishers have profoundly detailed knowledge of their environment,
the species of fish they target, changes in the waters they fish and its navigation, the
seasons which influence their fishing and the techniques which preserve fish (see, for
instance, von Brandt, 1972; Johannes, 1981; and Worsley, 1997 cited in Campbell and
Salagrama, 2001).
Customary marine tenure systems are often underpinned by the existence, value and
application of traditional ecological knowledge to management (see: Christy, 1982;
Ruddle and Johannes, 1985; Scudder and Connelly, 1985; Cordell, 1989; and Johannes,
1981 cited in Campbell and Salagrama, 2001).
Berkes et al. (2000) discussed the importance of traditional ecological knowledge and
acknowledged the similarity between such knowledge-based systems and adaptive
management. Francis and Bryceson (2001, 94) researching the situation in the coast
of Tanzania noted that “[b]oth traditional and scientific knowledge systems of coastal
ecology and ecosystem management exist, but there are many gaps and there is a need
for much improved dialogue and mutual respect between these knowledge systems.”
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
79
In all aspects of knowledge management, a more collaborative approach is emerging
as a key mechanism for shared understanding and decision-making in governance
and policy processes more generally. The greater use of indigenous knowledge in
fisheries management is a case in point. In fisheries research, participatory approach-
es to knowledge generation through all stages of the research cycle are becoming
more prevalent (Campbell and Salagrama, 2001). Wilson et al. (2006) expressed that
experience-based knowledge of fishers can be very useful for fisheries management.
In the UK, the government’s recent (2010–2013) process for the identification of
marine conservation areas involved a very significant consultation and engagement
with a wide array of stakeholders including fishers, sports divers, boat operators and
conservation specialists. This was supported by marine scientists and policy makers.
The extent and relevance of indigenous knowledge to fisheries is clearly demonstrat-
ed in Johannes’ (1981) work among island communities in the Pacific.
The expert discussions generally found consensus that local knowledge and experi-
ence offer a crucial contribution to the knowledge base required for effective fisheries
management. However there was less clarity regarding how this could be married
with scientific knowledge. Some respondents, for example, were skeptical regarding
the reliability of purely community-based mechanisms for monitoring and evaluat-
ing the impacts of management, particularly on the ecosystem and its functioning.
Inputs by trained scientists were seen as indispensable in some fields. Others felt
strongly that a large proportion of key information-gathering roles could be taken on
by resource users themselves, and that this could represent an important cost-saving
mechanism while also contributing to building local commitment and engagement in
the whole process.
However, even when new knowledge is shared, it often is not used to inform policy
and policy implementation. The work done through the Global Environment Facility
(GEF) on its Large Marine Ecosystem projects, for instance, has generated a large
amount of information about the biophysical, socio-economic, fisheries and gover-
nance aspects of marine management. However GEF is reported to have been less
enthusiastic about funding improved practice, new management actions and pro-
tection of priority sites, according to Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010), who also
noted that “[o]verall, the LME approach is a powerful generator of information and
financial resources and promotes transboundary cooperation but we suggest that, in
a developing country context, GEF and LME proponents should redirect emphasis
and resources from natural sciences to effective, sustainable governance” (2010, iii).
Mutual respect for, and trust in, different knowledge systems can take several
decades to develop (Armitage et al., 2012). Without trust, the incentive to commit to
management regimes based upon shared knowledge can be lost (Campbell and Cat-
termoul, 2009). The incorporation of local knowledge into policy-making processes is
becoming more common in fisheries management, as is sharing more formal sources
of knowledge within communities in ways that can be understood and used.
80
©Michael Cowan
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
81
7
7.	 Discussion, conclusions and 		
	 ways forward
7.1	 Discussion
A large body of literature, both peer reviewed and institutional reports, covers the
area of small-scale fisheries management. This synthesis reviews a small proportion
of those to provide an understanding of the existing knowledge field. The emphasis
of the study has been on “reviewing reviews” of experiences in the field, as much of
the literature stands one step removed from the field itself. As a consequence, the
synthesis represents the findings and opinions of thought leaders in the field who
have assessed the evidence, cross referenced by discussion with some 20 key infor-
mants across the field.
There was widespread agreement that the fisheries sector is very important to global
food and nutrition, to livelihoods, to foreign exchange earnings, to local community
development and as a safety net for the poor. It was also agreed that fisheries are in
a fairly poor state with most over-capitalized and many over-exploited. But there was
also a sense of optimism that this could be turned around and that there were already
signs of hope that this was being achieved.
A number of major themes in fisheries management that hold center stage in the
discussions tend to focus on the degree of emphasis placed on different aims. Yield
maximization, conservation, economic maximization and social policy are all entry
points into fisheries management that color the focus of the management efforts. In-
creasingly, however, there is recognition of the need to balance these different themes
and to look at fisheries management much more holistically.
This holistic approach brings recognition of the complex nature of fisheries manage-
ment that is changing in the face of globalized markets and climate change. It is that
complexity which needs to be embraced through much more integrated approaches
to management that work across different scales and levels. This requires horizontal
integration into the wider economy at local, national and global levels, and vertical
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
82
integration to link the local fisheries situation to wider concerns of migratory stocks,
cross-boundary effects, water pollution, IUU fishing and global markets.
There is also recognition that there is no “silver bullet”, no universal answer for all
the problems of fisheries. Each situation is ecologically, socially, economically, cul-
turally and politically different. Local context is very important, particularly as more
holistic approaches are adopted. The aims and objectives of different stakeholders
and the local context will differ, making the definition of revitalized fisheries different
in different locations. However, there does appear to be considerable support for the
idea that a number of factors influence success in a number of locations around the
globe. There is also a growing consensus of the need to use a combination of these
factors to set a general trend of improvement in motion.
An important element in this consensus is that the process by which fisheries man-
agement is developed and implemented is more important than the specific measures
through which it is implemented. In part, this is dictated by the fact that the timeframes
involved in bringing about change in the way fisheries and marine ecosystems are
managed are long, which means that the process by which stakeholders, institutions
and decision-making mechanisms are engaged over time needs careful attention. Col-
laborative approaches seem to play an important role in such processes, but the exact
roles played by government, the community, community representatives, NGOs and
the private sector will tend to vary according to context and the stage of development
of the process itself. The way the management process develops will also depend very
much on the broader context of governance, subsidiarity, institutional capacity and fit,
rights to resources, the legal framework, inclusiveness and scale, and it will be influ-
enced strongly by the prevailing political economy in different locations.
Ensuring the long-term viability of the resource and the wider ecosystem was generally
accepted as a key element, but one which needs to be balanced by other concerns
around the ability of stakeholders, particularly the poor, to respond to change and
around how benefits from protected ecosystem services might be distributed. It was
also clear that adaptation to change is likely to play a larger part in fisheries man-
agement in the future – climate change is introducing uncertainty that needs to be
incorporated into the planning process. There was considerable support for the use of
more adaptive approaches to respond to change and to build greater resilience in com-
munities. Given both the level of change in the management process and the change
in the fishery itself, it was felt that fisheries management needs to be introduced in-
crementally, as this approach allows adaptation in policy, policy implementation and
community structures and processes. However, creating the capacity at all levels –
within policy mechanisms, communities and agencies – to work in an adaptive fashion
is itself a challenge for which they require support and assistance.
This suggests that introducing and establishing major shifts in the management
process will not occur quickly in most situations. A long-term commitment by funders
to this change process will be necessary, requiring more sustainable funding mecha-
nisms to be identified and put in place without further adding to the subsidies to the
sector. Improved market chains have a role to play in improving the benefit flows to
fishers, but will require sequencing.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
83
There was also widespread recognition that greater inclusion of fishers and their
communities in the decision-making process is key. This builds on recognition of the
importance of rights and responsibilities at all levels, and goes beyond the inclusion
of fisher’s representatives in the form of local elites. It recognizes that fishers are a
disparate group of people who depend upon fisheries in quite different ways. It also
recognizes that other members of coastal communities are affected by how fisheries
management is conducted. Women in their roles as fish processors and traders are
greatly influenced by management decisions. Children are affected by future em-
ployment opportunities. The wider society is affected by the benefits that flow from
fisheries into the local economy.
Ultimately, fisheries management decisions will involve some people being included
in the right to fish and some being excluded. Those excluded may be current fishers
or future generations who may wish to join the fishery. Those who are excluded will
need alternative livelihood options, otherwise they are likely to become impoverished
or will try to circumvent entry regulations. Fisheries are generally closely linked to
the local economy in which they operate, and ensuring that they become a vital part of
local economic development is essential. Getting the balance right between exclusion,
alternative livelihoods and linkages with the local economy will be very important
to the sustainable and equitable development of small-scale fisheries. Embedding
fisheries management into the wider context of the local economy is essential if the
livelihoods of the poor are to be enhanced.
It will also be important to get the sequencing of decisions around controls over
entry, market chain development and livelihood alternatives right. Introducing im-
provements in market chains before the rights to fish are established will encourage
movement into the fishery. Restricting entry to the fishery before alternative invest-
ment and labor opportunities are established can push the poor into a state of despera-
tion.
There was considerable concern about getting the motives of fishers in line with those
of managers and recognizing the importance of different time frames for management
decisions. Given differences between people, there would likely be conflicts and viola-
tions of regulation that would need good enforcement, sound leadership, community
cohesion and a greater sense of commitment to the management process. This again
requires support for capacity building at the community level and building a sense
of trust among the different players. A shared recognition of the value of formal and
informal knowledge systems would provide a basis for starting to build that trust.
7.2	 Conclusions
It is clear from this work that there is no simple universal cure for the problems that
face small-scale coastal fisheries. These fisheries are complex, confused and difficult
to deal with, as well as locally specific. However, this does not mean that fisheries
cannot achieve a much more balanced equitable and sustainable trajectory into the
future. The 20 factors identified in this synthesis could help achieve this – when
combined into a process for change. There are doubtless others that would emerge
from a more comprehensive study.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
84
There is much that needs to be done to celebrate the areas of success that have been
achieved so far but also to recognize that widespread success will take a considerable
number of years, substantial financial support and a commitment to building capacity
at all levels.
Lessons can be learned from outside of small-scale coastal fisheries, such as those
that have emerged from inland fisheries, such as Bangladesh and Cambodia where
co-management systems are well developed. There also have been lessons from other
resource management systems such as forestry, livestock and game which have
parallels with fisheries. An approach to fisheries management which seeks examples
and solutions beyond fisheries is likely to generate more useful approaches.
Efforts to distill these different factors into principles for management began with
the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries. The specific needs of small-scale
fisheries that go beyond the Code have been progressively recognized and FAO is
currently producing a draft International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-
Scale Fisheries to address many of the emerging issues associated with fisheries man-
agement. These Guidelines are intended to enhance the contribution of small-scale
fisheries to poverty alleviation, food security and economic growth.
An important development in fisheries management is the greater interest in operating
at higher scales as well as the community levels. Regional recognition of, and support
for, good practice creates normative pressure for others to adopt. Learning networks
around fisheries and marine ecosystem management are important in supporting the
exchange of positive experience. While the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries
has not been universally applied, it has become a standard against which practice is
measured. The proposed Guidelines have the potential to go much further but will
need time, commitment and financial support to achieve this potential.
7.3	 Ways forward
There is much that can be done to bring the successful experiences of different
fisheries together into a more coherent and consistent process – a process supported
by tools and mechanisms and learning materials that will facilitate a more incremen-
tal but more coordinated approach to management change. This would need to be
done on an iterative basis where experience and learning is shared through networks
and exchanges, particularly in the face of climate change where so much remains
unknown.
The evolving FAO International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-Scale
Fisheries provides a framework for moving more equitable and sustainable fisheries
forward. This is still being developed and needs to be piloted to enable the different
tools and mechanisms for implementation to be developed.
In addition, as this report has shown, there are knowledge gaps in the process that
should be given consideration for future work, investment or development in the
sector, such as: how to combine these success factors into an effective process; to
what extent will they complement or conflict with one another; how can the appro-
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
85
priateness of different elements in the fisheries management process for different
locations be assessed and understood; what form would adaptive planning take to
address fisheries management in a rapidly changing marine environment; how can
we generate revenues from small-scale coastal fisheries that will fund local man-
agement initiatives, create alternative investment and livelihood opportunities, and
stimulate the wider local economy; how do we get the sequencing of interventions
right for different stakeholder groups; and how do we ensure long-term funding for
the process?
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
86
References
Abdullah, N.M.R & Pomeroy, R.S. (1998) Transaction Costs and Fisheries Co-Man-
agement. Marine Resource Economics, 13: 103-114.
Acheson et al. (1998 cited in Berkes et al., 2000, Acheson, J. M., Wilson J. A. &
Steneck R. S. 1998) Managing chaotic fisheries. Pages 390-413 in F Berkes & C.
Folke, eds. Linking social and ecological systems: management practices and social
mechanisms for building resilience. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Alban, F., Boncoeur, J. & Roncin N. (2011) Socio-Economy – Assessing the Impact of
Marine protected Areas on Society’s well-being: An economic perspective. In J.
Claudet, ed. Marine Protected Areas: A Multidisciplinary Approach. Cambridge
University Press.
Allen, C.R. & Gunderson, L.H. (2011) Pathology and failure in the design and imple-
mentation of adaptive management. Journal of Environmental Management, 92:
1379-1384.
Allison E. (2011) Aquaculture, Fisheries, Poverty and Food Security. WorldFish
Center, Working Paper 2011-65. Penang.
Allison, E. H. & Ellis, F. (2001) The Livelihoods Approach and Management of Small-
scale Fisheries. Marine Policy 2001, 25: 377-88.
Alongi, D.M. (2002) Present state and future of the world’s mangrove forests. Envi-
ronmental Conservation, 29(3): 331-349.
Alpízar, M.A.Q. (2006) Participation and fisheries management in Costa Rica: From
theory to practice. Marine Policy, 30: 641-650.
Anderson T.L. & Libecap G.D. (2010) The Allocation and Dissipation of Resource
Rents: Implications for Fishery Reform. In D. Leal, ed. Political Economy of
Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: Agriculture
and Rural Development Department, the World Bank.
Andrade, G.S.M & Rhodes, J.R. (2012) Protected Areas and Local Communities: An
Inevitable Partnership toward Successful Conservation Strategies? Ecology and
Society, 17(4): 14.
Arias Schreiber, M. & Halliday, A. (2013). Uncommon among the commons? Dis-
entangling the sustainability of the Peruvian anchovy fishery. Ecology and
Society, 18(2): 12 (available at http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-05319-180212).
Arkema, K.K., Abramson, S.C. & Dewsbury, B.M. (2006) Marine ecosystem-based
management: From characterization to implementation. Frontiers in Ecology and
the Environment, 4: 525-532.
Armitage, D.R., Plummer, R., Berkes, F., Arthur, R.I., Charles, A.T., Davidson-Hunt, I.J.
et al. (2009) Adaptive co-management for social-ecological complexity. Frontiers
in Ecology and Environment, 7(2): 95-102.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
87
Armitage, D., de Loe, R. & Plummer, R. (2012) Environmental governance and its
implications for conservation practice. Conservation Letters, 5(4): 245-255.
Arthur, R.I. (2005) Co-management: a synthesis of the lessons learned from the DFID
Fisheries Management Science Programme. MRAG Ltd. London (available at:
http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/pdf/outputs/R8470d.pdf).
Asian Fisheries Society (2013) Gender and Change In the Spotlight: Report on the
4th Global Symposium on Gender in Aquaculture and Fisheries. 1-3 May 2013,
Yeosu, Korea.
Aswani, S. & Weiant, P. (2004) Scientific evaluation in women’s participatory manage-
ment: Monitoring marine invertebrate refugia in the Solomon Islands. Human
Organization, 63(3): 301-319.
Baird, I.G. (1999) Towards Sustainable Co-Management of Mekong River Inland
aquatic resources, including fisheries. In Proceedings of the international
workshop on fisheries co-management, Penang, Malaysia, 23-29 August, 1999.
Barbier E. (2007) Natural Resources and Economic Development. Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Baticados. D.B (2004) Fishing cooperatives’ participation in managing nearshore
resources: the case in Capiz, central Philippines. Fisheries Research, 67: 81-91.
Bellamy, J.A., Walker, D.H., McDonald, G.T. & Syme, G.J. (2001) A systems approach
to the evaluation of natural resource management initiatives. Journal of Environ-
mental Management, 63(4): 407-423.
Belsky, J.M. (2000) Changing human relationships with nature: Making and remaking
wilderness science. In D.N. Cole, S.F.McCool, W. Freimund. & J. Oloughlin, eds.
Wilderness Science in a Time of Change Conference, Vol 1: Changing Perspectives
and Future Directions. 1999 May 23–27, Missoula, MT. Proceedings RMRS-P-
15-VOL-1. Ogden, Utah: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky
Mountain Research Station.
Bene, C., Hersoug, B. & Allison, E.H. (2010) Not by Rent Alone: Analysing the
Pro-Poor Functions of Small-Scale Fisheries in Developing Countries. Develop-
ment Policy Review, 28(3): 325-358.
Bene, C. & Neiland, A.E. (2003) Fisheries development issues and their impacts on
the livelihoods of fishing communities in West-Africa: An overview. Journal of
Food Agriculture and Environment, 1(1): 123-134.
Bennett, E. (2005a) Gender, Fisheries and Development. Marine Policy 29, 451-459.
Bennett, E. (2005b) Success in Fisheries Management: A review of the literature. In
S. Cunningham & T. Bostock, eds. Successful Fisheries Management: Issues, case
studies and perspectives. SIFAR/World Bank Study. Eburon Academic Publishers,
The Hague.
Bennett (undated). The Challenges of Managing Small Scale Fisheries in West Africa.
In The Management of Conflict in Tropical Fisheries (R7334) Final Technical
Report.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
88
Bensted-Smith, R. & Kirkman, H. (2010) Comparison of Approaches to Management
of Large Marine Areas. 144 pp. Publ. Fauna & Flora International, Cambridge,
UK, and Conservation International, Washington, DC.
Berkes, F., Mahon, R., McConney, P., Pollnac, R. & Pomeroy, R. (2001) Managing
Small-scale Fisheries: Alternative directions and methods. IDRC.
Berkes, F. (2006) From Community-Based Resource Management to Complex
Systems: The Scale Issue and Marine Commons. Ecology and Society, 11(1): 45.
Berkes, F. (2008) Community conserved areas: policy issues in historic and contem-
porary context. Conservation Letters, 2: 19-24.
Berkes, F., Colding, J. & Folke, C. (2000) Rediscovery of traditional ecological
knowledge as adaptive management. Ecological Applications, 10(5): 1251-1262.
Berkstrom, C., Gullstrom, M., Lingborg, R., Mwandya, A.W., Yahya, S.A.S., Kautsky,
N. & Nystrom, M. (2012) Exploring ‘knowns’ and ‘unknowns’ in tropical seascape
connectivity with insights from East African coral reefs. Estuarine Coastal and
Shelf Science, 107: 1-21.
Blaikie, P., Cannon, T., Davis, I. & Wisner, B. (1994) At Risk: Natural Hazards, People’s
Vulnerability and Disasters. Routledge.
Bromley, D.W. (2009) Abdicating Responsibility: The Deceits of Fisheries Policy.
Fisheries, 34(6): 280-302.
Bryant, D., Burke, L., McManus, J. & Spalding, M. (1998) Reefs at Risk: A map-based
indicator of threats to the World’s Coral Reefs. A joint report by WRI, ICLARM,
WCMC & UNEP published by WRI.
Burke, L., Reytar, K., Spalding, M. & Perry, A. (2011) Reefs at Risk Revisited, 130.
World Resources Institute: Washington, DC.
Campbell, J. (1996) Participatory and Integrated Policy: A field guide for policy formu-
lation in small-scale fisheries. IMM Ltd, UK.
Campbell, J, & Beardmore, J.A. (2001) Poverty and aquatic biodiversity. In: J.
Saunders. ed. Living off biodiversity: exploring livelihoods and biodiversity issues in
natural resources management. International Institute for Environment and De-
velopment, London, 191–229.
Campbell, J. & Cattermoul, B. (2009) The Socio-economic Impacts of Fisheries Man-
agement and Policy Designed to Achieve Biodiversity Conservation. Report for
the Tubney Charitable Trust, Reading, UK (available at http://www.tubney.org.
uk/The%20Socio-economic%20Impacts%20of%20Fisheries%20Management%20
and%20Policy.pdf).
Campbell, J. & Salagrama, V. (2001) New Approaches to Participation in Fisheries
Research. FAO Fisheries Circular no. 965, FIPL/C965. FAO, Rome.
Campbell, J. & Townsley, P. (2013) Biodiversity and Poverty in Coastal Environments,
in Biodiversity Conservation and Poverty Alleviation: Exploring the Evidence for a
Link. Roe, D., Elliott, J., Sandbrook, C. & Walpole, M., eds. John Wiley & Sons,
Ltd, Chichester, UK.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
89
Campbell, J., Whittingham, E. & Townsley, P. (2006) Responding to Coastal Poverty:
Should We be Doing Things Differently or Doing Different Things? In Hoanh,
C.T., Tuong, T.P., Gowing, J.W. & Hardy, B., eds. Environment and Livelihoods in
Tropical Coastal Zones. CAB International, London.
Cattermoul, B., Townsley, P. & Campbell, J. (2008) Sustainable Livelihoods En-
hancement and Diversification (SLED): A Manual for Practitioners. IUCN,
Gland, Switzerland and Colombo, Sri Lanka; CORDIO, Kalmar, Sweden; &
ICRAN, Cambridge, UK (available at http://www.imm.uk.com/PS/Main.
aspx?projectid=22cbb689-4e26-41f2-9077-48ee89ef4de3).
CFDO & IMM (2004) PRIAC Policy Reform Impact Assessment Cambodia: Impacts
of the fisheries policy reforms in Kampong Cham, Pursat & Takeo Provinces.
First Round Assessment Report. Department of Fisheries, Cambodia (available
at http://www.imm.uk.com/PS/Main.aspx?projectid=7c00d7a5-81d2-4821-a1e9-
5be6dc302b48).
Charles, A.T. & Herrera, A. (1994) Development and Diversification: Sustainability
Strategies for a Costa Rican Fishing Cooperative. In M. Antona, J. Catanzano &
J.G. Sutinen, eds. Proceedings of the 6th Conference of the International Institute
of Fisheries Economics. Paris, IIFET/ORSTROM. pp. 1315-1354.
Charles, A. (2011) Human Rights and Fishery Rights in Small-scale Fisheries Man-
agement. In Pomeroy, R.S. & Andrew, N.L., eds. Small-Scale Fisheries Manage-
ment: Frameworks and Approaches for the Developing World. CAB International,
Oxfordshire.
Charles, A. (2008) The Rights Form of Rights. Samudra Report No 51 OR Charles,
A. (2008) Robust Management, Risk and the Ecosystem Approach to Fisheries.
ICES CM 2008/O:05 Theme Session: Governmental quality and risk manage-
ment.
Christie, P. & White, A.T. (2007) Best practices for improved governance of coral reef
marine protected areas. Coral reefs, 26: 1047-1056.
Christie P. & White A.T. (2006) Best Practice in Governance and Enforcement of
Marine Protected Areas: An overview. Paper produced for the FAO Expert
Workshop on Marine Protected Areas and Fisheries Management: Review of
issues and considerations, 12-14 June, 2006.
Christy F. (1982) Territorial Use Rights in Marine Fisheries: Definitions and Condi-
tions. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper 227, Rome.
Cinner, J.E., McClanahan, T.R. & Wamukota, A. (2010) Differences in livelihoods,
socioeconomic characteristics, and knowledge about the sea between fishers and
non-fishers living near and far from marine parks on the Kenyan coast. Marine
Policy, 34(1): 22-28.
Claudet, J. (2011) Introduction. In Claudet, ed. Marine Protected Areas: A Multidisci-
plinary Approach. Cambridge University Press.
COBSEA (2011) Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region:
Integrating Emerging Issues and Modern Management Approaches.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
90
Cochrane, K.L. (2002) Fisheries Management. In Cochrane, K.L.,ed. A fishery
manager’s guidebook. Management measures and their application. FAO
Fisheries Technical Paper. No. 424, 231 p. FAO, Rome.
Cochrane, K., De Young, C., Soto, D. & Bahari,,T., eds. (2009) Climatic Change Impli-
cations for Fisheries and Aquaculture: Overview of current scientific knowledge.
FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Technical Paper. No. 530. FAO, Rome.
Collier, P. (2007) Growth Strategies for Africa. A paper presented at the Spence Com-
mission on Economic Growth. Centre for the Study of African Economies, De-
partment of Economics, Oxford University.
CI (Conservation International) (2011) Ecosystem-based adaptation for terrestrial,
marine and coastal regions, fact sheet (available athttp://www.conservation.org/
Documents/CI_IKI_Ecosystem-based_Adaptation_Factsheet.pdf ).
Copes, P. & Charles, A.T. (2004) Socioeconomics of Individual Transferable Quotas
and Community-Based Fishery Management. Agricultural and Resource
Economics Review, 33(2): 171-181.
Costello, C.J., Gaines, S.D. & Lynham, J. (2008) Can Catch Shares prevent fisheries
collapse? Science, 321:1678-80.
Costello, C., Kinlan, B. P., Lester S.E. & Gaines S.D. (2012) “The Economic Value of
Rebuilding Fisheries”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 55,
OECD Publishing.
Cunningham, S., Neiland, A.E., Arbuckle, M. & and Bostock, T. (2009) Wealth-based
Fisheries Management: Using Fisheries Wealth to Orchestrate Sound Fisheries
Policy in Practice. Marine Resource Economics, 24: 271-287.
DeFries, R., Hansen, A., Turner, B.L., Reid, R. & Liu, J. (2007) Land Use Change
Around Protected Areas: Management To Balance Human Needs and Ecological
Function. Ecological Applications, 17(4): 1031-1038.
Degnbol, P., Gislason, H., Hanna, S., Jentoft, S., Nielsen, J.R., Sverdrup-Jensen, S. &
Wilson, D.C. (2006) Painting the floor with a hammer: Technical fixes in fisheries
management. Marine Policy, 30(5): 534-543.
Degnbol, P. (2009) Coastal Management for Sustainability (speech), Common
Fisheries Policy Conference, London (available at http://ec.europa.eu/fisheries/
reform/docs/tom_appleby_en.pdf).
DFID (2012) Annual review of International Partnership for African Fisheries Gov-
ernance and Trade, synthesis draft (available at http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/pdf/
outputs/EoD/EoD_Consultancy_Summary_Oct2012_PAF_Review.pdf)
Dickson M.W. (undated) The CBFM-2 project: proving the case for community based
and co-management of fisheries in Bangladesh. Conference Paper no 1 (available
at http://www.worldfishcenter.org/resource_centre/WF_765.pdf).
Donnelly J. (2003) Universal Human Rights in Theory and Practice. Cornell Univer-
sity Press. Ithaca, NY, USA.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
91
Dryzek, J.S. (2005) The Politics of the Earth: Environmental Discourses. Oxford Uni-
versity Press, UK.
Evans, L., Cherrett, N. & Pemsl, D. (2011a) Assessing the impact of fisheries co-
management interventions in developing countries: A meta analysis. Journal of
Environmental Management, 92: 1938-1949.
Evans, L.S., Brown, K. & Allison, E.H. (2011b) Factors Influencing Adaptive Marine
Governance in a Developing Country Context: a Case Study of Southern Kenya.
Ecology and Society, 16(2): 21.
Fabinyi, M., Knudsen, M. & Segi, S. (2010) Social Complexity, Ethnography and
Coastal Resource Management in the Philippines. Coastal Management, 38(6):
617-632.
FAO (2008) Fisheries and Aquaculture Report No. 884 FIMF/R884 (En). Workshop
held in Rome, 26–29 February 2008. FAO, Rome.
FAO (1993) Marine Fisheries and the Law of the Sea: A decade of change. FAO
fisheries circular no. 853: FAO, Rome.
FAO (1996) FAO Technical Guidelines for Responsible Fisheries – Precautionary
Approach to Capture Fisheries and Species Introductions. FAO, Rome.
FAO (2007) Marine Protected Areas as a Tool for Fisheries Management. MPAs,
fisheries management and the ecosystem approach. FI Project Websites. In: FAO
Fisheries and Aquaculture Department [online]. Rome (available at http://www.
fao.org/fishery/topic/16200/en).
FAO (2008) FAO Newsroom. US$50 billion lost by marine fishing each year (available
at http://www.fao.org/newsroom/en/news/2008/1000931/).
FAO (2010) Report of the APFIC/FAO Regional Consultative Workshop: Securing
sustainable small-scale fisheries: Bringing together responsible fisheries and social
development, Bangkok, Thailand, 6-8 October 2010. FAO Regional Office for Asia
and the Pacific. RAP Publication 2010/19. 56 pp.
FAO (2012a) The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture, 2012. FAO, Rome.
FAO (2012b) International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-Scale Fisheries.
Zero Draft. FAO, Rome.
Ferrol-Schulte, D., Wolff, M., Ferse, S. & Glaser, M. (2013) Sustainable Livelihoods
Approach in tropical coastal and marine social-ecological systems: A review.
Marine Policy, 42: 253-258.
Fisheries Administration (2010) Fishing for the Future: Strategic Planning Framework
for Fisheries 2010–2019. Fisheries Administration, Phnom Penh, Cambodia.
Folke, C., Pritchard, L., Berkes, F., Colding, J. & Svedin, U. (1998) The problem
of fit between ecosystems and institutions. International Human Dimensions
Programme on Global Environmental Change, Bonn, Germany.
Forest Trends, The Katoomba Group & UNEP (2008) Payments for Ecosystem
Services. Getting Started: A Primer. Forest Trends/The Katoomba Group /
UNEP, Nairobi. 74pp.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
92
Francis, J. & Bryceson, I. (2001) Tanzanian coastal and marine resources: some
examples illustrating questions of sustainable use. Cited in Ahmed, J., Bergstrøm,
C., Bryceson, I., Child, B., Francis, J., Khan, P., Ousmane, B.G., Price, T.L.,
Senaratna, S., Tareen, N. & van Dam, C., eds. In Lessons learned – Case Studies
in Sustainable Use. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland, in pp 76–102.
Gell, F.R. & Roberts, C.M. (2002) The Fishery Effects on Marine Reserves and
Fishery Closures. WWF-US, Washington, DC.
Gondo, T. (2008) Adaptive co-management of natural resources: A solution or part of
the problem? Journal of Human Ecology, 33(2): 119-131.
Graham, J., Charles, A. & Bull, A. (2006) Community Fisheries Management
Handbook. Gorsebrook Research Institute, Saint Mary’s University.
Greiber, Thomas, ed. (2009) Payments for Ecosystem Services. Legal and Institution-
al Frameworks. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland. xvi + 296 pp.
Gulbrandsen, L. (2009) The Emergence and Effectiveness of the Marine Stewardship
Council. Marine Policy, 33: 654–660.
Gutierrez, N.L., Hilborn, R. & Defeo, O. (2011) Leadership, social capital and incen-
tives promote successful fisheries. Nature, 470: 386-389.
Hall, S.J. & Andrew, N.L. (2011) Recent developments in fisheries science and their
prospects for improving fisheries contributions to food security. In Foresight
Project on Global Food and Farming Futures. Foresight, Government Office for
Science, London.
Hall, S.J. & Mainprize, B. (2004) Toward ecosystem-based fisheries management.
Fish and Fisheries, 5: 1-20.
Hanna, S.S. (1995) User participation and fishery management performance within
the Pacific Fishery Management Council. Ocean & Coastal Management, 28(1-3):
23-44.
Hilborn, R. (1985) Fleet dynamics and individual variation: why some people catch
more than others. Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Science, 42, 2–13,
cited in Salas & Gaertner (2004)
Hiborn, R., Branch, T.A., Ernst, B., Magnusson, A., Minte-Vera, C.V., Scheuerell, M.D.
& Valero, J.L. (2003) State of the World’s Fisheries. Annual Review of Environ-
ment and Resources, 28: 359-99.
Hilborn, R. (2007a) Managing fisheries is managing people: what has been learned?
Fish and Fisheries, 8: 285-296.
Hilborn, R. (2007b) Moving to Sustainability by Learning from Successful Fisheries.
Ambio, 36(4): 296-303.
Hilborn, R. (2007c) Defining success in fisheries and conflicts in objectives. Marine
Policy, 31(2): 153–158.
Hind, E.J., Hiponia, M.C. & Gray, T.S. (2010) From community-based to central-
ised national management – A wrong turning for the governance of the marine
protected area in Apo Island, Philippines? Marine Policy, 34(1): 54-62.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
93
Holden, S.T., Shiferaw, B. & Wik, M. (1998) Poverty, market imperfections and time
preferences: Of relevance for environmental policy? Environment and Develop-
ment Economics, 3: 105-130.
Howard, C. & Arthur, R.I. (2005) Lessons for co-management: experiences from the
FMSP programme. MRAG Ltd, London, 12pp.
Huppert, D.D. (2005) An Overview of Fishing Rights. Reviews in Fish Biology and
Fisheries, 15(3): 201-215.
IMM (2001) Learning Lessons from the Cyclone: A study of DFID’s Support for the
Post-Cyclone Livelihoods Rehabilitation in Orissa, India (available at: http://www.
imm.uk.com/PS/Main.aspx?projectid=671dac8e-85c7-4965-bc89-c53b2dd20da9).
IMM & ICM (2003) Major Trends in the Utilisation of Fish in India: Poverty-Policy
Consideration. Output of the India Fish Utilisation and Poverty Project, RNRRS,
DFID, London (available at http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/Search/SearchResults.aspx?s
earch=advancedsearch&SearchType=3&Projects=false&Documents=true&Doc
umentsOnly=true&ProjectID=2480).
IMM, CFDO & CBNRM LI. (2005) Understanding the Factors that Support or Inhibit
Livelihood Diversification in Coastal Cambodia. An output from DFID-funded
research in Cambodia. IMM Ltd, Exeter, UK. (available at http://www.imm.
uk.com/PS/Main.aspx?projectid=dd1e357e-9594-43c1-8266-c7be839098fa).
IPCC (2011) IPCC special report on managing the risks of extreme events and
disasters to advance climate change adaptation: fact sheet (available at www.ipcc.
ch/news_and_ events/docs/srex/SREX_fact_sheet.pdf). Accessed 19 March
2012.
Jentoft, S. & McCay, B. (1995) User participation in fisheries management: Lessons
drawn from international experiences. Marine Policy, 19(3): 227-246.
Jentoft, S. (2000) The Community: a missing link in fisheries management. Marine
Policy, 24, 53-59.
Jentoft, S. & Chuenpagdee, R. (2009) Fisheries and Coastal Governance as a Wicked
Problem. Marine Policy, 33(4): 553-560.
Johannes, R. E. (1981) Words of the Lagoon: Fishing and Marine Lore in the Palau
District of Micronesia. University of California Press, Berkeley, USA.
Jones, P.J.S. (2007) Point of View – Arguments for conventional fisheries management
and against no-take marine protected areas: only half of the story? Reviews in Fish
Biology and Fisheries, 17(1), 31-43. doi: 10.1007/s11160-006-9016-8.
Kuemlangan, B. (2004) Creating legal space for community-based fisheries and
customary marine tenure in the Pacific: issues and opportunities. FishCode
Review, No. 7(En). 2004. 65p., FAO, Rome.
Kuperan, V.K. & Jahan, K.M. (2010) Noncompliance a major threat in fisheries
management – Experiences from the artisanal coastal fisheries of Bangladesh.
Journal of International Studies, 6: 97-113.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
94
Leal, D.R. (2010) Lessons for Fisheries Reform and Development Assistance. D. Leal,
ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Wash-
ington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Department, the World Bank.
Lennox, M. (2012) Monies for Marine Conservation: a White Paper Examining
New Funding Sources for Oceans and Coasts. The Nature Conservancy, 56 pp
(available at http://www.marineplanning.org/pdf/Monies_for_Marine_Conser-
vation.pdf.
Link, J.S. (2010) Ecosystem-Based Fisheries Management: Confronting trade-offs.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Lowry, G.K., White, A.T. & Christie, P. (2009) Scaling Up to Networks of Marine
Protected Areas in the Philippines: Biophysical, Legal, Institutional, and Social
Considerations. Coastal Management, 37(3-4): 274-290.
Mahon, R., McConney, P. & Roy, R.N. (2008) Governing fisheries as complex adaptive
systems. Marine Policy, 32: 104-112.
Maliao, R.J., Pomeroy, R.S. & Turingan, R.G. (2009) Performance of community-
based coastal resource management (CBCRM) programs in the Philippines: A
meta-analysis. Marine Policy, 33(5): 818-825.
Manta Consulting (2011) Financing Fisheries Change: Learning from Case Studies.
120pp. Manta Consulting, Inc.
MARES (undated) Marine and Coastal Ecosystem Service Payments & Markets.
Powerpoint presentation, 17 pp. (available at http://redlac.org/winnie%20lau%20
-%20marine%20and%20coastal%20ecosystem%20service%20payments%20and%20
markets%202.pdf).
McConney, P. & Charles, A. (2008) Managing Small-Scale Fisheries: Moving Towards
People-Centred Perspectives. In Grafton, R.Q., Hilborn, R., Squires, D., Maree, T.
& Williams, M. (eds.) Handbook of Marine Fisheries Conservation and Manage-
ment. Oxford University Press, UK.
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MA) (2005) Ecosystems and Human Well-Being:
A Framework for Assessment. Island Press, Washington, DC.
Moberg, F. & Galaz, V. (2005) Resilience: Going from Conventional to Adaptive Fresh-
water Management for Human and Ecosystem Compatibility. Swedish Water
House Policy Brief Nr. 3. SIWI, 2005.
MRAG, IDS & University of Sterling (2013) Fisheries and Aquaculture and their
Potential Roles in Development: an assessment of the current evidence. Report
produced for DFID, London.
MRAG (2009) Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated Fishing. Policy Brief No. 8.
MRAG, London.
MRAG (2010) Towards sustainable fisheries management: international examples of
innovation. MRAG Ltd, London: 93 pages (available at http://www.pcfisu.org/
wp-content/uploads/2010/12/MRAG-report_best-practice-examples1.pdf).
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
95
OECD & FAO (2009) Round Table on Eco-labeling and Certification in the Fisheries
Sector. Proceedings of a round table workshop 22-23 April 2009 The Hague,
The Netherlands (available at http://www.globefish.org/upl/Papers/Final%20
Report%20Roundtable_720.pdf).
Ostrom, E. (2009a) A General Framework for Analyzing Sustainability of Social-Eco-
logical Systems. Science, 325: 419-422.
Ostrom, E. (2009b) Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex
Economic Systems. Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana
University, Bloomington, Indiana, USA, and Center for the Study of Institutional
Diversity, Arizona State University, Tempe, Arizona, USA.
Pearse, P.H. (1992) From Open Access to Private Property – Recent Innovations in
Fishing Rights as Instruments of Fisheries Policy. Ocean Development and Inter-
national Law, 23(1): 71-83.
Pitcher, T.J., Watson, R., Haggan, N., Guenette, S., Kennish, R., Sumaila, R., Cook. D.,
Wilson. K. & Leung, A. (2000) Marine reserves and the restoration of fisheries
and marine ecosystems in the South China Sea. Bull. Mar. Sci. 66(3):543-566.
Pomeroy, R.S. (1994) Community management and common property of coastal
fisheries in Asia and the Pacific: Concepts, methods and experiences – Intro-
duction. In Pomeroy, R.S. (ed.) Community Management and Common Property
of Coastal Fisheries in Asia and the Pacific: Concepts, Methods and Experiences.
ICLARM Conf. Proc. 45, 189 p.
Pope, J.G. (1983). Fisheries resource management theory and practice. In Taylor,
J.L., Baird, G.G., eds. New Zealand finfish fisheries: the resources and their man-
agement. Auckland New Zealand: Trade Publications Limited, 1983. p. 56–62.
Raakjaer Nielsen, J. & Vedsmand, T. (1995) Fisheries Co-Management: An Alternative
Strategy in Fisheries – Cases from Denmark. An issue paper for the OECD study
on the efficient management of living resources.
Roberts, C.M. (2007) The Unnatural History of the Sea. Island Press, Washington,
DC.
Roberts, C.M., Hawkins, J.P. & Gell, F.R. (2005) The role of marine reserves in
achieving sustainable fisheries. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B,
360(1453):123-132.
Roberts, C.M., Bohnsack, J.A., Gell, F., Hawkins, J.P. & Goodridge, R. (2001) Effects
of Marine Reserves on Adjacent Fisheries. Science, 294: 1920-1923.
Robinson, J.A. (2010) The Political Economy of Institutions and Resources. In D. Leal,
ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Wash-
ington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Department, the World Bank.
Roe, D., Nelson, F. & Sandbrook, C., eds. (2009) Community Management of
Natural Resources in Africa: Impacts, experiences and future directions. Natural
Resources Issues No. 18, International Institute for Environment and Develop-
ment, London, UK.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
96
Rudd, M.A., Tupper, M.H., Folmer, H. & van Kooten, G.C. (2003) Policy analysis for
tropical marine reserves: challenges and directions. Fish and Fisheries, 4(1):
65-85.
Ruddle, K. & Hviding, E. (1992) Marine Resources Management in the Context of
Customary Tenure. Marine Resource Economics, 7: 249-273.
Ruddle, K. & Johhannes, R. (1985) The Traditional Knowledge and Management of
Coastal Systems in Asia and the Pacific. Papers presented at the UNESCO-ROT-
SEA Regional Seminar at UNESCO Regional Office for Science and Technology
for Southeast Asia, 5-7 December 1983. UNESCO, Jakarta.
Salagrama, V. (2005) Traditional Community-Based Management Systems (TCBMS)
in two Fishing Villages in East Godavari District, Andhra Pradesh, India. In Cun-
ningham S. & Bostock T., eds. Successful Fisheries Management: Issues, case
studies and perspectives. SIFAR/World Bank Study. Eburon Academic Publishers,
The Hague.
Salagrama, V. & Koriya, T. (2008) Assessing Opportunities for Livelihood Enhance-
ment and Diversification in Coastal Fishing Communities in Southern India.
United Nations Team for Tsunami Recovery Support (UNTRS), Chennai.
Salas, S. & Gaertner, D. (2004) The Behavioural Dynamics of Fishers: Management
implications. Fish and Fisheries, 5: 153–167.
Samonte, G., Karrer, L. & Orbach, M. (2010) People and Oceans. Science and
Knowledge Division, Conservation International, Arlington, Virginia, USA.
Scott, A. (2010) New Direction in Fishery Management. In Leal, D., ed. Political
Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Agriculture
and Rural Development Department, the World Bank, Washington, DC.
Scudder, T. & Connelly, T. (1985) Management Systems for Riverine Fisheries. FAO
Fisheries Technical Paper (263) 85pp.
Sen, S. & Nielsen, J.R. (1996) Fisheries co-management: a comparative analysis.
Marine Policy, 20(5): 405-418.
Smith, I.R. (1981) Improving fisheries incomes when resources are overfished.
Marine Policy, 5: 17-22.
Spergel, B. & Moye, M. (2004) Financing Marine Conservation A Menu of Options.
WWF Center for Conservation Finance, Washington, DC, 74pp.
Stobutzki, I.C., Silvestre, G.T. & Garces, L.R. (2006) Key issues in coastal fisheries in
South and Southeast Asia, outcomes of a regional initiative. Fisheries Research,
78(2-3): 109-118.
Sugiyama, S., Staples, D. & Funge-Smith, S.J. (2004) Status and potential of fisheries
and aquaculture in Asia and the Pacific. FAO Regional Office for Asia and the
Pacific (RAP) Publication 2004/25. 53 pp.
Sumaila, U.R., Khan, A.J., Dyck, A., Watson, R., Munro, G., Tyedmerset, P. & Pauly,
D. (2010) A Bottom-up Re-estimation of Global Fisheries Subsidies. Journal of
Bioeconomics, 12(3): 201–225.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
97
Sutinen, J. (2010) Governance and Fiscal Requirements for Marine Resources Man-
agement. In Leal, D., ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for
Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Depart-
ment, the World Bank.
Swan, J. & Greboval, D. (2004) Overcoming Factors of Unsustainability and Over-
exploitation in Fisheries, Selected Papers on Issues and Approaches. Interna-
tional Workshop on the Implementation of International Fisheries Instrument
and Factors of Unsustainability and Overexploitation in Fisheries. Siem Reap,
Cambodia, 13-16 September 2004: FAO Fisheries Report, 782.
Silvestri, S. & Kershaw, F., eds. (2010) Framing the flow: Innovative Approaches to
Understand, Protect and Value Ecosystem Services across Linked Habitats, UNEP
World Conservation Monitoring Centre, Cambridge, UK.
The Western Star (2009). Hilborn, R. video conference from University of Washington.
http://www.thewesternstar.com/Business/2009-09-18/article-1479752/Cod-
quotas-cant-be-increased-even-if-stocks-are-recovering:-fisheries-specialist/1
Thompson, B.T. (2010) Legal Issues in Fisheries Reform: Lessons from Resource
Management. In Leal, D., ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons
for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development De-
partment, the World Bank.
Tobey, J. & Torell, E. (2006) Coastal poverty and MPA management in mainland
Tanzania and Zanzibar. Ocean & Coastal Management, 49: 834-854.
Townsley, P., Chandra Mohan, G.M. & Karthikeyan, V. (2011) Fisheries Stakehold-
ers and Their Livelihoods in Tamil Nadu and Puducherry. A Report prepared
for the Fisheries Management for Sustainable Livelihoods (FIMSUL) Project,
undertaken by the FAO in association with the World Bank, the Government of
Tamil Nadu and the Government of Puducherry. Report No. FIMSUL/R2. FAO/
UTF/IND/180/IND. New Delhi, Chennai and Puducherry, India (available at
https://38549c75-a-62cb3a1a-s-sites.googlegroups.com/site/fimsulreports/
home/reports/R2L.pdf?attachauth=ANoY7cq8-ODJEt4Da7ok-LHoDyUG53IIXh-
75hckKvA9h2RmN7vUVwa0TyCZbyZ3KKv-UucLTbWQt8b8RSGPLMkLKQOR-
murlZkQZyRmLcDMHkOYyq_Y4E_n_pWwtAC9-23xiA_0LKAJsmkON3EnSrqz-
B15wdHDSpGeCenAbjiAic0j8PufftpKOLmzVQP-lN-H52wTRE8gmbSA-98XYYT
6z7fVVeUBFAMJ2qUWine1VsLw10Q8K9aUTo%3D&attredirects=0
Tupper, M.H. & Rudd, M.A. (2003) Species-specific impacts of a small marine reserve
on shellfish production and fishing productivity in the Turks and Caicos Islands.
Environmental Conservation, 29: 484-492.
van Tuyen, T.V., Armitage D. & Marschke, M. (2010) Participatory planning for co-
management in Tam Giang Lagoon. Ocean and Coastal Management, 53: 327-335.
von Brandt, A. (1972) Fish Catching Methods of the World. Fishing News (Books) Ltd,
West Byfleet, UK.
Walmsley, S., Purvis, J. & Ninnes, C. (2006) The role of small-scale fisheries manage-
ment in the poverty reduction strategies in the Western Indian Ocean region.
Ocean & Coastal Management, 49: 812-833.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
98
Wakumota, A.W., Cinner, J.E. & McClanahan, T.R. (2012) Co-management of coral
reef fisheries: A critical evaluation of the literature. Marine Policy, 36(2): 481-488.
Waycott, M., Duarte, C.M., Caruthers, T.J.B., Orth, R.J., Dennison, W.C. & Olyarnik,
S. (2008) Accelerating loss of seagrasses across the globe threatens coastal eco-
systems. PNAS, 106(30): 12377-12381.
Weeratunge, N., Bene, C., Siriwardane, R., Charles, A., Johnson, D. & Allison, E.H.
(2013) Small-scale fisheries through the wellbeing lens. Fish and Fisheries,
doi: 10.1111/faf.12016.
White, A., Deguit, E. & Jautlan, W. (2006) Integrated Coastal Management in Philip-
pine Local Governance: Evolution and Benefits. Coastal Management, 34: 287-302.
Whittingham, E., Campbell, J. & Townsley, P. (2003) Poverty and Reefs. DFID-IMM-
IOC/UNESCO, UNESCO, Paris, France.
Wilson, D.C., Ahmed, M., Siar, S.V. & Kanagaratnam, U. (2006) Cross-scale linkages
and adaptive management: Fisheries co-management in Asia. Marine Policy, 30:
523-533.
Willmannm, R. (2010) Good Practices in the Governance of Small-Scale Fisheries,
with a Focus on Rights-Based Approaches. In Report of the APFIC/FAO Regional
Consultative Workshop “Securing sustainable small-scale fisheries: Bringing
together responsible fisheries and social development”, Bangkok, Thailand, 6-8
October 2010. FAO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific (RAP) publication
2010/19. 56 pp.
World Bank & FAO (2009) The Sunken Billions: The economic justification for
fisheries reform.
Worsley, P. (1997) Knowledges: What Different Peoples Make of the World. Profile
Books Ltd, London.
WWF (2012) Raising the Sunken Billions: a new model for financing fisheries
reform. WWF Factsheet July 2012, 2pp (available at http://awsassets.panda.org/
downloads/fact_sheet_the_firme.pdf).
Zhou, S., Smith, A.D.M., Punt, A.E., Richardson, A.J., Gibbs, M., Fulton, E.A., Pascoe
S., Bulman C., Bayliss P. & Sainsbury K. (2010) Ecosystem-based fisheries man-
agement requires a change to the selective fishing philosophy. PNAS, 107(21):
9485-9.
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
99
Annexes
ANNEX 1:
A: Electronic database search log
DATE OF
SEARCH
SEARCH DATABASE SEARCH TERMS SEARCH FIELD NO. OF
RESULTS
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge –Web of
Science
Fish* *manage* Topic 29,916
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Fish* *manage* coast* Topic 5,189
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Fish* community-based Topic 550
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Fish* adaptive NEAR/3 manage* Topic 447
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Ecosystem *manage* Topic 32,823
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Ecosystem *manage* coast* Topic 4,267
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Ecosystem community-based Topic 438
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Ecosystem adaptive NEAR/3 manage* Topic 1,041
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Natural resource *manage*	 Topic 15,408
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Natural resource *manage* coast*	 Topic 1,288
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Natural resource community-based Topic 622
02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of
Science
Natural resource adaptive NEAR/3
manage*
Topic 460
03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* Complete
document
Query too
general
03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* coast* Complete
document
Query too
general
03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* Title 18,445
03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* coast* Title 514
03/07/13 Scirus Fish* community-based Complete
document
2,095,331
03/07/13 Scirus Fish* community-based Title 342
03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* Complete
document
Query too
general
03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* coast* Complete
document
Query too
general
03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* Title 9,323
03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* coast* Title 72
03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem community-based Completed
document
772, 268
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
100
DATE OF
SEARCH
SEARCH DATABASE SEARCH TERMS SEARCH FIELD NO. OF
RESULTS
10203/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem community-based	 Title 102
03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* Complete
document
4,725,634
03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* Title 8,874
03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* coast* Complete
document
937, 141
03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* coast* Title 105
03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource community-based Complete
document
1,858,356
03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource community-based Title 360
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Fish* *manage* All Fields No matches
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Fish* *manage* Title No matches
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Fisheries management All Fields 32+
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Fish* community-based All Fields 4+
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Ecosystem *manage* All Fields No matches
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Ecosystem *manage* Title No matches
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Ecosystem management All Fields 3+
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Ecosystem community-based All Fields 3+
04/04/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Natural resource *manage* All Fields No matches
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Natural resource *manage* Title No matches
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Natural resource management All Fields 1+
04/07/13 Directory of Open Access
Journals
Natural resource community-based All Fields 5+
04/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index
and Abstracts
Fish* *manage* All Fields 10+
08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index
and Abstracts
Fish* community-based All Fields 2+
08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index
and Abstracts
Ecosystem *manage* All Fields 0
08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index
and Abstracts
Ecosystem community-based All Fields 0
08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index
and Abstracts
Natural resource *manage* All Fields 1+
08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index
and Abstracts
Natural resource community-based All Fields 0
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Fish* *manage* All Fields 94, 247
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Fish* *manage* coast* All Fields 21, 127
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
101
DATE OF
SEARCH
SEARCH DATABASE SEARCH TERMS SEARCH FIELD NO. OF
RESULTS
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Fish* *manage* coast* Abstract 7, 248
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Fish* *manage* coast* Document Title 316
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Fish* community-based All Fields 923
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Ecosystem *manage* All Fields 49, 666
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Ecosystem *manage* coast* All Fields 13, 184
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Ecosystem *manage* coast* Abstract 3,811
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Ecosystem *manage* coast* Document Title 111
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Ecosystem community-based All Fields 516
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Ecosystem community-based coast* All Fields 155
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Natural resource *manage* All Fields 38,446
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Natural resource *manage* coast* All Fields 9,953
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Natural resource *manage* coast* Abstract 1,438
10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries
Abstracts
Natural resource *manage* coast* Document Title 9
+ results screened for language and relevance criteria
B: Institutional grey literature search log
DATE OF
SEARCH
INSTITUTION WEBSITE: SEARCH AREA NO. OF
RESULTS
14.07.2013 http://www.coopesolidar.org/ Sent by author 2
14.07.2013 http://www.wcs.org/ Sent by co-author 2
15.07.2013 http://fish.washington.edu/ Sent by co-authors 7
15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/13261/en FAO
Fish
Ecosystem
7
15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/mpas//en FAO
Fish
Ecosystem
Marine protected areas
1
15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/2880/en FAO
Fisheries
Ecosystems
1
15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/3542/en FAO
Fisheries
Ecosystems
Coastal & marine ecosystems
1
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
102
DATE OF
SEARCH
INSTITUTION WEBSITE: SEARCH AREA NO. OF
RESULTS
15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/3320/en FAO
Fisheries
Ecosystems
Coastal & marine ecosystems
Types of ecosystems
1
15.07.2013 ftp://ftp.fao.org/fi/DOCUMENT/eaf/eafguidelines_278364.pdf Sent by co-author 1
18.07.2013 http://toobigtoignore.net/ Books 2
18.07.2013 http://toobigtoignore.net/ Articles 1
19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/Pages/
partnerlanding.aspx
Marine -
19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/initiatives/
fisheries/Pages/sustainable_fisheries.aspx
Sustainable fisheries -
19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/initiatives/
seascapes/pages/seascapes.aspx
Seascapes 2
19.07.2013 http://www.science2action.org/ Research and innovation 8
19.07.2013 http://www.science2action.org/files/sciencereports/ Science reports 4
19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/publications/ Marine, Resources and publications 2
19.07.2013 http://equatorinitiative.org/ -
19.07.2013 http://sfg.msi.ucsb.edu/current-projects/sustainable-ocean-
solutions
Sustainable Oceans Solutions -
19.07.2013 http://sfg.msi.ucsb.edu/current-projects/unassessed_fisheries Un-assessed fisheries 1
19.07.2013 http://www.ifad.org/ ‎ Sent by author 1
19.07.2013 http://sfg.msi.ucsb.edu/ Sent by co-author 1
23.07.2013 http://www.mrcmekong.org/ Sent by author 1
23.07.2013 http://www.mrcmekong.org/publications/topic/
fisheries?start=20
Publications Fisheries 1
23.07.2013 http://www.rflp.org/co_management Co-management 7
25.07.2013 http://www.protectplanetocean.org/ Tools and resources 1
27.07.2013 https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/
browse?order=ASC&rpp=20&sort_by=-1&etal=-
1&offset=200&type=topic
Fisheries and aquaculture 1
27.07.2013 http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/
EXTARD/0, contentMDK:23070469~pagePK:148956~piPK:216
618~theSitePK:336682,00.html
World Bank Profish 20
29.07.2013 http://www.iucn.org/about/union/commissions/sustainable_
use_and_livelihoods_specialist_group/
Lessons learned 2
30.07.2013 http://www.afma.gov.au/resource-centre/research/reports/ Research reports 5
30.07.2013 http://www.afma.gov.au/search/?query=ecosystem+based+m
anagement
Ecosystem-based management
guidelines
2
30.07.2013 http://www.afma.gov.au/ Sent by author 1
30.07.2013 http://www.cdu.edu.au/ Sent by author 4
01.08.2013 http://www.lmmanetwork.org/resourcecenter Resource center 3
14/08/13 http://www.idrc.ca/EN/Resources/Publications/Pages/
default.aspx
Publications - Co-management 2
14/08/13 Publications - Fisheries
management
0
14/08/13 Publications – Fish 1
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
103
DATE OF
SEARCH
INSTITUTION WEBSITE: SEARCH AREA NO. OF
RESULTS
14/08/13 http://www.idrc.ca/EN/Resources/Publications/Pages/
IDRCBooksList.aspx
IDRC Books – Co-management 0
14/08/13 IDRC Books – Fisheries
management
0
14/08/13 IDRC Books - Fish 2
14/08/13 http://www.smu.ca/webfiles/Dr.TonyCharles.pdf Co-management; community-
based; ecosystem approach to
fisheries; fishery management and
governance; international fisheries;
rights based management; small-
scale fisheries; successful fisheries
26
14/08/13 http://www.southampton.ac.uk/oes/research/publications.
page?
Publications 0
14/08/13 http://www.enaca.org/modules/library/tag.php?label_type=1 Better management practices 0
14/08/13 Livelihoods, gender and social
issues
1
14/08/13 http://www.afdb.org/en/documents/environment/12/ Environment 0
14/08/13 http://www.adb.org/publications/search/448?keyword=fish Agriculture and natural resource
– Fish
2
15/08/13 http://www.worldfishcenter.org/worldfish-publications Fisheries management – open
access
23
15/08/13 http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/Search/SearchResults.aspx
?search=advancedsearch&SearchType=3&Projects=
false&Documents=true&DocumentsOnly=true&Any
word=fisheries+management&AnywordCondition=
AND&AnyWordPhrase1=1&AnyWordChooseField1=-
1&Keywords=2188&PageNo=7
Fisheries management 7
15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/ Co-management 2
15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat.
php?cid=59
Fishery and aquaculture policy 1
15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat.
php?cid=57
Ecosystem approach to fisheries 3
15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat.
php?cid=67
Promoting co-managemenet 2
15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat.
php?cid=76
Gender in fisheries and aquaculture 1
15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/singlefile.
php?cid=68&lid=274
Participatory development
approaches
1
16/08/13 http://caricom-fisheries.com/PublicationsandDocuments/
CRFMResearchPaperCollection/tabid/86/Default.aspx
CRFM Research Paper Collection 2
16/08/13 http://caricom-fisheries.com/PublicationsandDocuments/
CRFMTechnicalandAdvisoryDocuments/tabid/87/Default.aspx
CRFM Technical and Advisory
Documents
4
20/08/13 http://www.macfound.org/press/publications/conservation-
sustainable-development-white-papers/
Conservation and Sustainable
development white papers
1
20/08/13 http://www.castlefoundation.org/grants-marine.htm Nearshore Marine Resource
Conservation
0
20/08/13 http://www.waltonfamilyfoundation.org/environment/marine-
conservation
Marine Conservation 0
20/08/13 http://www.oakfnd.org/library Environment 0
20/08/13 http://www.packard.org/what-were-learning/program-area/
children-families-and-communities/
Conservation and Science; Children,
Families and Communities
0
KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
104
ANNEX 2:
Informal knowledge search checklist
NAME(S) ORGANIZATION(S) POSITION(S) LOCATION DATE
The checklist below lays out some broad questions about your knowledge and experience of eco-system based community management
approaches (left hand column) while the middle column contains some additional more specific issues that you may want to consider
while writing your responses in the right hand column. Please feel free to treat these questions as freely as you wish and by all means
make suggestions regarding their relevance. In your responses to some of the questions, you might want to make a distinction between
your personal opinions and experience, and those of the organization that you work for.
GENERAL QUESTIONS PROMPTS KEY KNOWLEDGE AREAS/OUTPUTS
What do you feel are the key characteristics
or defining features of an ecosystem-based
community management (ECM) approach?
What experience have you had of these
approaches?
What ECM initiatives have you been
involved with / are you familiar with?
Describe the key features of the
approaches used?
What do you regard as the strengths and
weaknesses of ECM approaches (based
on your experience) and what factors
contribute to them?
How would you define a successful
ECM approach?
What are/were the strengths of the
approaches you have experienced
or used?
What were the weaknesses?
What specific factors contribute/d to their
success or positive impacts / failure?
Ecological / resource
characteristics?
Social setting?
Governance arrangements?
Characteristics of the organisations
involved?
Wider institutional context?
Scale?
Markets?
Wider economy?
Timing?
Cost-effectiveness?
Can you suggest key initiatives, individuals
or organisations who work on ECM who
we should be in contact with as part of this
review?
What other individuals or
organisations are you aware of
working on ECM and/or community-
based management?
What documents would you regard as
the most useful for understanding ECM
approaches?
Papers. Reports. Books. Guidelines
and manuals. Articles.
Financial support provided by
www.rockefellerfoundation.org

More Related Content

PDF
The Rockefeller Foundation's Bellagio Center
PDF
A Synthesis Review of Key Lessons in Programs Relating to Oceans and Fisheries
PDF
ACCCRN Cities Poject - May 2013
PDF
Asian Cities Climate Change Resilience Network Initiative Final Evaluation
PDF
Rebuild by Design Phase 1 Evaluation Report
PDF
Situating the Next Generation of Impact Measurement and Evaluation for Impact...
PDF
Effective Public Health Communication in an Interconnected World: Enhancing R...
PDF
Joint Learning Update
The Rockefeller Foundation's Bellagio Center
A Synthesis Review of Key Lessons in Programs Relating to Oceans and Fisheries
ACCCRN Cities Poject - May 2013
Asian Cities Climate Change Resilience Network Initiative Final Evaluation
Rebuild by Design Phase 1 Evaluation Report
Situating the Next Generation of Impact Measurement and Evaluation for Impact...
Effective Public Health Communication in an Interconnected World: Enhancing R...
Joint Learning Update

What's hot (20)

PDF
The Urban Resilience Summit: Executive Summary (2014)
PDF
Conservation Finance. From Niche to Mainstream: The Building of an Institutio...
PDF
City Resilience Framework
PDF
Ten Cities, Four Countries, Five Years: Lessons on the Process of Building Ur...
PDF
Equity and inclusive growth background paper - sept 2016
PDF
Final Evaluation - Disease Surveillance Networks Initiative
PDF
City Resilience Framework
PDF
Guidelines for Resilience Systems Analysis: How to analyse risk and build a r...
PPT
Understanding and Measuring Urban Resilience: A new UN-Habitat's initiative
PDF
BdaCal OU Project.public
PDF
The Rockefeller Foundation–Lancet Commission on Planetary Health: Safeguardin...
PDF
Global debt relief and donor funding
PPTX
Trialling Demand-led Climate Finance in Ethiopia: Is DFID onto a Winner?, Jul...
PDF
Strengthening Disaster Risk Governance-Full-Report
PDF
Reflection 3
PDF
Grf synergy in drr bangladesh experience 30 aug 2012
PDF
Disaster Management Systems: Building Capacity for Developing Countries and ...
ODP
Disaster Management Systems: Building Capacity for Developing Countries and ...
PDF
UNHABITAT_BG
PDF
Women's Insecure Property Rights
The Urban Resilience Summit: Executive Summary (2014)
Conservation Finance. From Niche to Mainstream: The Building of an Institutio...
City Resilience Framework
Ten Cities, Four Countries, Five Years: Lessons on the Process of Building Ur...
Equity and inclusive growth background paper - sept 2016
Final Evaluation - Disease Surveillance Networks Initiative
City Resilience Framework
Guidelines for Resilience Systems Analysis: How to analyse risk and build a r...
Understanding and Measuring Urban Resilience: A new UN-Habitat's initiative
BdaCal OU Project.public
The Rockefeller Foundation–Lancet Commission on Planetary Health: Safeguardin...
Global debt relief and donor funding
Trialling Demand-led Climate Finance in Ethiopia: Is DFID onto a Winner?, Jul...
Strengthening Disaster Risk Governance-Full-Report
Reflection 3
Grf synergy in drr bangladesh experience 30 aug 2012
Disaster Management Systems: Building Capacity for Developing Countries and ...
Disaster Management Systems: Building Capacity for Developing Countries and ...
UNHABITAT_BG
Women's Insecure Property Rights
Ad

Viewers also liked (20)

PDF
Sustainable Knowledge Management
PDF
Oceans & Fisheries
PDF
Knowledge Management at AT Kearney - Case Study
PDF
The Evaluation of the Design Competition of Rebuild by Design
PDF
Knowledge Management in Organizations: Case Study
PDF
Final Evaluation: The Rockefeller Foundation's Program-Related Investments Po...
PDF
PartnershipPPT
PPT
Health & Safety
PPTX
Evidence based practice jeopardy quiz 1
PPTX
CMO's Guidance on Alcohol and Young People
PDF
Key Factors Supporting Small Scale Coastal Fisheries Management
PPTX
Nuevas profesiones
PPTX
Planificacion De La Gestion Escolar
PDF
Gamification - Reputation System
PDF
The Return of The Sun - Vera Ema Tataro
PPTX
Captains of Industry
PPTX
GSEEM 2012 (int.week_malardalen_may2012)
DOCX
Planificación de ciencias naturales de 4° Año
DOCX
9 enterprise tech trends for 2016 and beyond
PDF
Collection Cards of The Life - Vera Ema Tataro
Sustainable Knowledge Management
Oceans & Fisheries
Knowledge Management at AT Kearney - Case Study
The Evaluation of the Design Competition of Rebuild by Design
Knowledge Management in Organizations: Case Study
Final Evaluation: The Rockefeller Foundation's Program-Related Investments Po...
PartnershipPPT
Health & Safety
Evidence based practice jeopardy quiz 1
CMO's Guidance on Alcohol and Young People
Key Factors Supporting Small Scale Coastal Fisheries Management
Nuevas profesiones
Planificacion De La Gestion Escolar
Gamification - Reputation System
The Return of The Sun - Vera Ema Tataro
Captains of Industry
GSEEM 2012 (int.week_malardalen_may2012)
Planificación de ciencias naturales de 4° Año
9 enterprise tech trends for 2016 and beyond
Collection Cards of The Life - Vera Ema Tataro
Ad

Similar to Synthesis Review: Key Factors Supporting Small-Scale Coastal Fisheries Management (20)

PDF
Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management
PDF
GRP120_Perceptions and misconceptions of aquaculture
PDF
Climate Smart Rural Development Synthesis Review
PDF
5technical guide line ECOSYSTEM APPROACH TO AQUACULTURE FAO.pdf
PDF
Water resourcers group
PDF
Performance Evaluation USAID Oceans.pdf
PPT
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations
PDF
Globalisation And Fisheries Proceedings Of An Oecdfao Workshop Oecd
PDF
Aquaculture Planning Policy Formulation And Implementation For Sustainable D...
PDF
OSF-Evaluation_Final-Report_07.23.2020.pdf
PDF
Benefiting from Innovations in Sustainable and Equitable Management of Trans-...
PDF
Sustainable seafood sourcing conference brochure
PPT
Fisheries and Aquaculture Department
PDF
State of fisheries and aquaculture
PDF
The state of world fisheries and aquaculture
PDF
CoP-PPLD Inception Workshop. Workshop report. 12-13 January 2009 IFAD Headqua...
PDF
Towards global sustainable fisheries
PDF
Social and Economic Dimensions of Carrageenan Seaweed Farming
PPTX
Ccrf(code of conduct for responsible fisheries_
Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management
GRP120_Perceptions and misconceptions of aquaculture
Climate Smart Rural Development Synthesis Review
5technical guide line ECOSYSTEM APPROACH TO AQUACULTURE FAO.pdf
Water resourcers group
Performance Evaluation USAID Oceans.pdf
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations
Globalisation And Fisheries Proceedings Of An Oecdfao Workshop Oecd
Aquaculture Planning Policy Formulation And Implementation For Sustainable D...
OSF-Evaluation_Final-Report_07.23.2020.pdf
Benefiting from Innovations in Sustainable and Equitable Management of Trans-...
Sustainable seafood sourcing conference brochure
Fisheries and Aquaculture Department
State of fisheries and aquaculture
The state of world fisheries and aquaculture
CoP-PPLD Inception Workshop. Workshop report. 12-13 January 2009 IFAD Headqua...
Towards global sustainable fisheries
Social and Economic Dimensions of Carrageenan Seaweed Farming
Ccrf(code of conduct for responsible fisheries_

More from The Rockefeller Foundation (20)

PDF
Transforming Health Systems Final Evaluation
PDF
Thinking Strategically About Networks for Change
PDF
Putting “Impact” at the Center of Impact Investing: A Case Study of How Green...
PDF
Integrating mini grids with india's evolving electricity system may 2017
PDF
Smart Power Connect May 2017
PDF
Expanding Opportunities for Renewable Energy-Based Mini-Grids in Rural India
PDF
Implementation Models - Synthesis of Findings
PDF
Smart Power Impact Report
PDF
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study Brief
PDF
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study
PDF
Reducing food waste by changing the way consumers interact with food
PDF
Impact hiring survey results
PDF
National Disaster Resilience Competition's Resilience Academies - Emerging In...
PDF
NDRC Resilience Academies Evaluation Report 2016
PDF
Resilience Week 2016 Hosted by The Rockefeller Foundation
PDF
Inclusive Economy Indicators Full Report Dec 2016
PDF
Inclusive Economy Indicators Exec Summary
PDF
100x25 CEO & Gender Media Audit Infographic
PDF
Building Capacity for Innovation and Systems Change: Innovation Fellowship Pr...
PDF
Assessing Market-Based Solutions: Lessons from Evaluating a Youth Employment ...
Transforming Health Systems Final Evaluation
Thinking Strategically About Networks for Change
Putting “Impact” at the Center of Impact Investing: A Case Study of How Green...
Integrating mini grids with india's evolving electricity system may 2017
Smart Power Connect May 2017
Expanding Opportunities for Renewable Energy-Based Mini-Grids in Rural India
Implementation Models - Synthesis of Findings
Smart Power Impact Report
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study Brief
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study
Reducing food waste by changing the way consumers interact with food
Impact hiring survey results
National Disaster Resilience Competition's Resilience Academies - Emerging In...
NDRC Resilience Academies Evaluation Report 2016
Resilience Week 2016 Hosted by The Rockefeller Foundation
Inclusive Economy Indicators Full Report Dec 2016
Inclusive Economy Indicators Exec Summary
100x25 CEO & Gender Media Audit Infographic
Building Capacity for Innovation and Systems Change: Innovation Fellowship Pr...
Assessing Market-Based Solutions: Lessons from Evaluating a Youth Employment ...

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
Strategic Planning for Child Rights and Protection Programming.pdf
PDF
Strategic Planning 2025-2026 (Bambang PWD Association, Inc.)
PPTX
5th week.pptxazqzqxqxqqxwxwxwxwsxwswxwxwxw
PPTX
Proposed Odisha State Highways Authority OSHA Act 2025 Draft
PPTX
AMO Pune Complete information and work profile
PPTX
Nur Shakila Assesmentlwemkf;m;mwee f.pptx
PDF
ISO-9001-2015-internal-audit-checklist2-sample.pdf
PDF
ISO-9001-2015-gap-analysis-checklist-sample.pdf
PDF
NDR Week Motorcade 2025 of Pasig City PDAO (Bambang PWD Association, Inc. Par...
PPTX
DFARS Part 247 - Transportation - DFARS
PPTX
Intro+to+Afr+studies_week4_slides_lecture+two.pptx
PDF
Storytelling youth indigenous from Bolivia 2025.pdf
PPTX
NATIONALISM-AND-PATRIOTISM RA 6713 REPORT
PPTX
GSA Q+A Follow-Up To EO's, Requirements & Timelines
PPTX
Chapter_12_Public_Enterprises_Presentation.pptx
PPTX
The DFARS - Part 250 - Extraordinary Contractual Actions
PPTX
PCCR-ROTC-UNIT-ORGANIZATIONAL-STRUCTURE-pptx-Copy (1).pptx
PDF
सुशासन सप्ताह भारत रत्न श्री अटल बिहारी बाजपेयी जी जन्मदिवस समारोह 19-24 दिसं...
PPTX
Vocational Education for educational purposes
PPT
Adolescent Health Orientation and Health care
Strategic Planning for Child Rights and Protection Programming.pdf
Strategic Planning 2025-2026 (Bambang PWD Association, Inc.)
5th week.pptxazqzqxqxqqxwxwxwxwsxwswxwxwxw
Proposed Odisha State Highways Authority OSHA Act 2025 Draft
AMO Pune Complete information and work profile
Nur Shakila Assesmentlwemkf;m;mwee f.pptx
ISO-9001-2015-internal-audit-checklist2-sample.pdf
ISO-9001-2015-gap-analysis-checklist-sample.pdf
NDR Week Motorcade 2025 of Pasig City PDAO (Bambang PWD Association, Inc. Par...
DFARS Part 247 - Transportation - DFARS
Intro+to+Afr+studies_week4_slides_lecture+two.pptx
Storytelling youth indigenous from Bolivia 2025.pdf
NATIONALISM-AND-PATRIOTISM RA 6713 REPORT
GSA Q+A Follow-Up To EO's, Requirements & Timelines
Chapter_12_Public_Enterprises_Presentation.pptx
The DFARS - Part 250 - Extraordinary Contractual Actions
PCCR-ROTC-UNIT-ORGANIZATIONAL-STRUCTURE-pptx-Copy (1).pptx
सुशासन सप्ताह भारत रत्न श्री अटल बिहारी बाजपेयी जी जन्मदिवस समारोह 19-24 दिसं...
Vocational Education for educational purposes
Adolescent Health Orientation and Health care

Synthesis Review: Key Factors Supporting Small-Scale Coastal Fisheries Management

  • 1. Key Factors Supporting Small-Scale Coastal Fisheries Management September 2013 SYNTHESIS REVIEW THE RockefellerFoundation EVALUATIONOFFICE Financial support provided by
  • 2. THE RockefellerFoundation EVALUATIONOFFICE About IMM IMM is a leading research, development and consultancy group providing innovative solutions to global development problems, by promoting inclusive policy and planning; responsive and effective institutions for service provision; empowered, capable and innovating communities; sustainable and equitable use and governance of the environment and natural resources; and expanded opportunities for disadvantaged, low income and vulnerable communities and groups. IMM specializes in building partnerships between government, civil society and communities to provide equitable and sustainable strategies for growth and development. About the Foundation Center Established in 1956 and supported by close to 550 foundations, the US-based Foundation Center is the leading source of information about philanthropy worldwide. Through data, analysis and training, it connects people who want to change the world to the resources they need to succeed. The Center maintains the most comprehensive database on US and, increasingly, global grantmakers and their grants. It also operates research, education and training programs designed to advance knowledge of philanthropy at every level. Thousands of people visit the Center’s website each day and are served in its five regional library/learning centers and its network of 450 funding information centers located in public libraries, community foundations and educational institutions nation-wide and beyond. About the Rockefeller Foundation Evaluation Office For more than 100 years, the Rockefeller Foundation’s mission has been to promote the well-be- ing of humanity throughout the world. Today, the Rockefeller Foundation pursues this mission through dual goals: advancing inclusive economies that expand opportunities for more broadly shared prosperity, and building resilience by helping people, communities and institutions prepare for, withstand and emerge stronger from acute shocks and chronic stresses. Committed to supporting learning, accountability and performance improvements, the Evaluation Office of the Rockefeller Foundation works with staff, grantees and partners to strengthen evaluation practice and to support innovative approaches to monitoring, evaluation and learning. For this synthesis review, the Rockefeller Foundation provided financial support, the Foundation Center was involved in project and technology development and IMM authored the report. IMM authors included Jock Campbell, Philip Townsley, Emma Whittingham and Jessica Marsh. This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 Unported License. Cover photo © Cristina Rumbaitis Del Rio
  • 3. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW i Tableofcontents Acronyms iii Foreword v Acknowledgements vi Executive summary vii 1. Background to the synthesis 1 2. Research process and methods 3 2.1 Stage 1: Study design 3 2.2 Stage 2: Formal knowledge search and screening 4 2.3 Stage 3: Informal knowledge search 5 2.4 Stage 4: Analysis and report writing 6 3. Background to coastal fisheries 7 3.1 The importance of coastal fisheries 7 3.2 The state of coastal fisheries 11 3.3 The potential of coastal fisheries 12 4. Fisheries management approaches and themes 13 4.1 Customary marine tenure (CMT) 15 4.2 Yield maximizing approaches 16 4.3 Conservation of resources 16 4.4 Economic maximization 18 4.5 Rights-based approaches 19 4.6 Ecosystem-based management 20 4.7 Co-management 22 5. Impacts 25 6. Critical factors that influence success 29 6.1 Some frameworks of success factors 30 6.2 Factors affecting policy and planning 32 6.3 Factors affecting technical implementation 51 6.4 Factors affecting community engagement 66 7. Discussion, conclusions and ways forward 81 7.1 Discussion 81 7.2 Conclusions 83 7.3 Ways forward 84 References 86
  • 4. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW ii ANNEXES Annex 1: A: Electronic database search log 99 B: Institutional grey literature search log 101 Annex 2: Informal knowledge search checklist 104 LIST OF TABLES Table 1: Principal topics and keywords search strategy 4 Table 2: Summary of formal knowledge search results 5 Table 3: Summary of the informal knowledge search 6 Table 4: Global fish production by year and source in millon tonnes 8 LIST OF BOXES Box 1: Overfishing in Asia 11 Box 2: Reef destruction 12 Box 3: Soufrière marine management area in St Lucia 17 Box 4: Impact of marine protected areas (MPAs) in Tanzania 18 Box 5: An economic approach in practice 19 Box 6: Ecosystem-based adaptation (EbA) in the Philippines 21 Box 7: Co-management in inland water bodies in Bangladesh 22 Box 8: Assessing community perceptions of impact in Cambodia 25 Box 9: Design principles for the Peruvian anchovy fishery 30 Box 10: Wicked problems of fisheries management 33 Box 11: Examples of variables in a framework for analysing social-ecological systems 35 Box 12: Linkages across scales of management 41 Box 13: The Conservation International (CI) seascape approach 43 Box 14: The drivers of fish abundance 46 Box 15: Community-based coastal resource management – success or failure? 47 Box 16: Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region 49 Box 17: Management approaches for different situations 49 Box 18: Local management of lobster stocks 52 Box 19: Rights in small-scale fisheries 53 Box 20: Lessons from ICM in the Philippines 54 Box 21: A sector wide approach in Cambodia 58 Box 22: Certification helps community fishery in Vietnam 65 Box 23: Livelihood diversification 69 Box 24: Post-cyclone cooperation 71 Box 25: Factors influencing fish processors in India 77
  • 5. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW iii Acronyms ADB Asian Development Bank ASFA Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts ASSIA Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts CAOPA African Confederation of Small-Scale Fisheries Professional Organisations CBO Community-based organization CBRM Community-based resource management CBCRM Community-based coastal resource management CBNRM Community-based natural resource management CBFM Community-based fisheries management CFDO Community Fisheries Development Office of the Fisheries Administration of Cambodia CI Conservation International CMSP Coastal and Marine Spatial Planning CMT Customary marine tenure COBSEA Coordinating Body on the Seas of East Asia COFI Committee on Fisheries (FAO) CRM Coastal resource management DFID Department for International Development (UK government) DOAJ Directory of Open Access Journals EAF Ecosystem approach to fisheries EbA Ecosystem-based adaptation EBM Ecosystem-based management ECM Ecosystem-based community management EEZ Exclusive economic zone FAO Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations FiA Fisheries Administration, Cambodia FIRME Financial Institution for the Recovery of Marine Ecosystems GDP Gross domestic product GEF Global Environment Facility GSSF Guidelines for Small-Scale Fisheries (FAO) HDI Human Development Index ICCAS Indigenous and community conserved areas ICM Integrated coastal management ICSF International Collective in Support of Fish Workers ITQ Individual transferrable quota IUCN International Union for the Conservation of Nature IUU Illegal, unreported and unregulated fishing LME Large marine ecosystem MEY Maximum economic yield MJY Maximum job yield MMA Marine management area MPA Marine protected area
  • 6. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW iv MRAG Marine Resources Assessment Group MSC Marine Stewardship Council MSW Minimum sustainable whinge MSY Maximum sustainable yield NGO Non-governmental organization OECD Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development PAF Partnership for African Fisheries PPP Purchasing power parity TAC Total allowable catch TNC The Nature Conservancy TURF Territorial use right in fisheries UK United Kingdom WBFM Wealth-based fisheries management WCS World Conservation Society WFFP World Forum of Fisher People WWF World-Wide Fund for Nature
  • 7. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW v Foreword This synthesis review is part of a broader collaboration between the Rockefeller Foun- dation and the Foundation Center aimed at helping the Foundation and our partners build more effectively on what works and what does not in a given sector. As such, this review aims to help identify the role that the Foundation could play in small-scale coastal fisheries. The Foundation Center engaged Integrated Marine Management (IMM), a leading research and development group with expertise in fisheries, aquaculture and coastal zone management, to undertake a rapid review of key sources of knowledge (evalu- ations, literature reviews and key informant interviews) and to identify key factors believed to influence success in small-scale coastal fisheries management. While there are no simple universal solutions to the problems that small-scale coastal fisheries face, IMM was able to identify 20 key and interconnected success factors. Identifying these factors helped the Foundation in three specific ways. First, it helped to improve the focus of its fisheries strategy and programmatic investments. The review provided a broad overview of the different areas of knowledge in the fisheries and marine conservation spaces, which allowed us to narrow the focus of our grant- making into a subset of an extremely complex, globalized and interconnected system. Second, recognizing the contribution of many different factors in successful outcomes for fisheries pointed the Foundation and our partners towards interventions and ap- proaches that seek to negotiate and resolve the various tradeoffs among success factors. For example, determining whether or not fisheries should be managed for wealth creation, sustainability or social benefit would suggest three very different interventions. This review helped guide the Foundation to focus on processes that bring in various diverse viewpoints – such as co-management or a fisheries improve- ment partnership – and work to create governance mechanisms that can resolve the differences in those viewpoints. Third, the review serves as an entry point for our grantees and partners to examine their own perspectives on what works and what doesn’t with evidence from other sectors in marine conservation and fisheries. For example, one grantee that had pre- viously focused its work more on grassroots capacity building came to see the value (and risks) inherent in connecting those capacity-building efforts to the markets for seafood, which can simultaneously create and inhibit opportunity for fishermen. We are grateful to Gabi Fitz at the Foundation Center and to Jock Campbell and his team at IMM for their diligent and creative efforts in undertaking this synthesis review, and to John Thomas for his capable stewardship of the synthesis process internally at the Foundation. We look forward to continuing to build on our collec- tive knowledge in this and other fields. It should also be noted that the 20 success factors can be explored in detail through an interactive data visualization tool online at fisheries.issuelab.org. Nancy MacPherson Fred Boltz MANAGING DIRECTOR, EVALUATION MANAGING DIRECTOR, ECOSYSTEMS THE ROCKEFELLER FOUNDATION THE ROCKEFELLER FOUNDATION
  • 8. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW vi The IMM team would like to thank the following key informants who so generously shared their time and knowledge in the development of this report: Rolf Willmann, Gabriella Bianchi, Daniela Kalikoski, Susana Siar, Nicole Franz and Carlos Fuente- villa at the Fisheries Department of the FAO; Simon Funge-Smith at the Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO); Peter Degen at the Mekong River Commission; Marea Hatziolos at the World Bank; Vidhisha Samarasekara at the Asian Development Bank Office in India; Nigel Brett at IFAD; Hary Christijanto at the Directorate of Fisheries, Indonesia; Jim Prestcott at the Australian Fisheries Management Authority; Terrence Phillips at the Caribbean Regional Fisheries Mechanism; Steve Gaines at the Univer- sity of California Santa Barbara; Ray Hilborn and Chris Anderson at the University of Washington; Daniel Pauly at the University of British Columbia; Natasha Stacey and Dirk Steenberg at Charles Darwin University; Tim McClanahan at World Conserva- tion Society (WCS), Mombasa; Rosie Cooney at the Sustainable Use and Livelihoods Specialist Group at the International Union for the Conservation of Nature (IUCN); Tundi Agardy at Forest Trends; Nicola Frost and Helen Anthem at Fauna & Flora International; Sebastien Troeung and Kathleen Flower at Conservation International; Julie Robinson at The Nature Conservancy, Belize; Lena Westlund, Independent con- sultant; Naseegh Jaffer at the World Forum of Fisher People (WFFP); Vivienne Solis Rivera at CoopeSoliDar; Gaoussou Gueye at African Confederation of Small-Scale Fisheries Professional Organisations (CAOPA); V. Vivekandan, independent fisheries specialist and activist; and Brian O’Riordan at International Collective in Support of Fish Workers (ICSF). We would express appreciation for the support and encouragement of Cristina Rumbaitis Del Rio, John Thomas and Nancy MacPherson from the Rockefeller Foun- dation, Gabriela Fitz from the Foundation Center and Robbie Gregorowski from ITAD. Acknowledgements
  • 9. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW vii This synthesis review of key factors supporting small-scale coastal fisheries man- agement was undertaken by the Foundation Center with financial support from the Rockefeller Foundation. The work was carried out by a team based at IMM Ltd, in Exeter, UK, from July to September 2013. It was designed to provide an evidence base on the success factors in small-scale coastal fisheries management in developing countries and, in turn, to assist the Rock- efeller Foundation in developing its strategy for its Oceans and Fisheries Initiative. In doing so, it identifies and describes some 20 key factors believed to influence success in small-scale coastal fisheries management. The synthesis first presents an outline of the methods used in the study followed by a background of coastal fisheries, an introduction to fisheries management themes, and a review and discussion of some of the critical factors that influence success. It then offers some conclusions and possible ways forward. The review process This report was completed via a rapid review of key sources of knowledge from formal published literature, institutional literature, key informants and Internet searches. The focus was on key success factors in achieving a balance of social, economic and ecological benefits from the management of small-scale coastal fisheries. Background to coastal fisheries Small-scale coastal fisheries is an important sector. It contributes very significantly to food and nutrition security, employment, income and providing livelihoods for many very poor people. The diversity of coastal resources creates opportunities for these people, and the ease of becoming a fisher means that many people depend on fisheries for all or part of their household livelihood strategies. However, as people are often able to enter the fishery with ease, many fisheries are over-capitalized with too much investment in fishing capacity, some are over-exploited and their contribution to wider economic development is being poorly used. Today, 87.3 percent of fisheries are either over-exploited or fully exploited (FAO, 2012a). These issues are compounded by a number of other human activities that result in coastal pollution and habitat destruction, further depleting resources. Subsidies to the fisheries sector in the past have increased the excessive pressure on resources, and destructive fishing methods are threatening wider ecosystem functions in many coastal areas. Growing global demand for fish by a variety of users and the penetra- tion of global marketing chains to almost all corners of the world are also creating incentives to over-exploit fisheries. Climate change is also beginning to affect coastal habitats, such as coral reefs which are under severe threat. These are some of the richest habitats and provide a wide diversity of opportunities for coastal people. Executivesummary
  • 10. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW viii Climate change is likely to have other effects on both the ecology and the liveli- hoods of people who live near the coast, including increasing their exposure to natural hazards. The climate is only one of a number of factors that are changing. Today’s fishers are faced with fuel and food price rises, changes in demand for fish and changes in market structures which are forcing fisheries and fisheries manage- ment to confront issues in the much broader contexts of the wider ecology and local and national economies. Fisheries management Much of the current situation of poorly managed fisheries results from past policies and practices. On the back of historic views that fisheries could not be depleted, national governments and intergovernmental organizations promoted the expansion of fisheries and subsidized expansion in capital, technology and skills. The momentum of this growth meant that fishing capacity has now expanded beyond that required for full and efficient utilization of the fisheries. Many different forms of fisheries management have evolved, depending on the perceived aims of the management process. Early forms of customary marine tenure focused on the locally controlled management of resource access and benefits. As fisheries developed, yield maximization approaches were adopted which, in turn, gave rise to concerns for the environment and for maximizing sustainable economic returns from fisheries management. Thus, approaches have been added that confer rights – individual, community and human – on the people in the sector to achieve both efficiency and equity gains. This recognition of the wider ecological and economic implications of poor fisheries management also has stimulated an interest in more holistic approaches that go beyond fisheries and include ecosystem-based approaches and integrated coastal management. Such approaches are increasingly looking closely again at community involvement in fisheries management through co-management arrangements, under which the community and government share roles and responsibilities. Impacts The social, economic and ecological impacts of fisheries management are hard to measure. However, in the big picture, it can be said that a balance of sustainability, efficiency and equity goals have not been achieved. In fact, with the current state of the world’s fisheries, most people would conclude that, overall, the management process has largely failed. Key success factors In spite of this rather negative picture of the management process, there are indica- tions that some elements of fisheries management – in some locations and under some circumstances – have contributed to success. While there is no single approach or management system that addresses all the problems facing fisheries management globally, there is a growing belief that if enough of the factors affecting success are brought together, they have the potential to reverse fisheries’ downward spiral.
  • 11. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW ix This report identifies 20 of these key success factors, grouping them under three broad headings: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical implementation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. This division is more for ease of presentation, as there are considerable overlaps between levels. In many cases, these overlaps are as important as the factors themselves. The key factors are summarized below. Factors affecting policy and planning These factors tend to operate at the policy and planning levels, but also can influence what happens at the policy implementation and community engagement levels. 1. Embracing complexity and integration. Fisheries encompass interactions among people, the environment, political and social institutions, and markets, making for a complex system. In the past, the focus tended to be on simplifying fisheries in order to understand them, e.g. using single species models of management from temperate fisheries on multi-species small-scale fisheries. However, this did not fully address the complexity of these fisheries and the biodiversity upon which they tend to depend. These small-scale fisheries are also very closely linked to local economies, which greatly influences the movement of people in and out of the fishery. At the same time, this com- plexity is rapidly changing as climate change and other global pressures affect the way fisheries operate – all of which indicates that engaging with complexity is becoming more urgent. If the management of small-scale coastal fisheries is to be successful, then a greater emphasis needs to be placed on understanding and responding to this complexity rather than externalizing it. Fisheries man- agement must embrace that complexity and integrate with the wider local and national economies and development process. 2. Addressing conflicting aims. The inherent complexity of fisheries has been compounded by confusion over the aims of fisheries management. The aims of fisheries, and therefore fisheries management, are often diverse and mixed. Different stakeholders have different objectives, as is often reflected in contradictory policies and management plans. Effective means of linking the aims of the sector to the wider development aims of resolving conflicts between different objectives and prioritizing those objec- tives are usually lacking. This leads to confusion as to what the management process is trying to achieve, and contributes to the lack of success of fisheries management approaches. It is important to recognize and address these con- flicting and contradictory aims if fisheries management is to be successful and contribute to national development aims. 3. Recognizing the importance of context. Part of the complexity of fisheries is that each fishery has developed within, and responds to, the local ecology, culture, economy, social patterns and political forces that operate around it. Efforts to seek a common solution are bound to be frustrated by this local diversity. This does not mean that solutions cannot be found, but they must take the local context into account. A key part of this
  • 12. x process will be the full and meaningful engagement of local communities in the management process. 4. Operating at multiple scales. Although the local context is important, there is also a need to understand the in- terconnectedness of different local situations. This interconnectedness operates through ecological, economic, social, cultural and political structures and processes at local, national, regional and global scales. Increasingly, it is recog- nized that working at multiple scales is needed to understand the wider context and to accommodate it in the fisheries management process. A variety of ap- proaches to this are being piloted and used, including large marine ecosystems (LMEs), Seascapes, Marine Ecoregions, Regional Seas and Integrated Coastal Management (ICM). ICM has been used most extensively in the context of linking coastal fisheries to wider development processes, but all these approach- es have wider and more holistic elements that attempt to integrate fisheries more realistically with other ecological and economic development areas. 5. Ensuring institutional coherence. Recognizing the complexity of fisheries management and the need to link fisheries much more closely to other economic, social, ecological and political processes at different scales indicates the importance of ensuring institutional coherence across these processes and at different levels. This is particularly so in terms of policy coherence, legislative coherence and the incentives provided by policy instruments. For example, where the establishment of well-defined rights to access fisheries resources is seen as an important part of fisheries man- agement, it also needs to be recognized in policy and legislation at all levels. 6. Ensuring the viability and sustainability of ecosystem function. Fisheries cannot survive if there are no fish to catch. Ensuring the viability and sustainability of ecosystem function underpins the long-term survival of fisheries and the benefits that flow from them. Management measures such as marine protected areas have an important role to play in this process. However, it is important to understand this role in terms of the local ecological as well as socio- economic context. In particular, environmental management measures will have different effects on different groups of stakeholders in the fishery. In many situ- ations, fishing opportunities will decline in the short to medium term for at least some people, and the fishers’ abilities to react will also differ. Thus, management interventions should pay particular attention to sequencing interventions and measures to support fishers during transition to better management. 7. Adapting to external pressure and change. Even under the best fisheries management system, change is inevitable. This is becoming more pronounced as climate change takes effect and the forces that drive markets for labor, capital and fish become more globalized. In addition, in the face of outside opportunities, local economies are rapidly changing and coastal populations are increasing. With global media reaching even the KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW
  • 13. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW xi most remote parts of the world, people’s perceived needs and aspirations are changing. Adapting to all of these external pressures and changes must become an important part of the fisheries management process. Efforts to address change by incorporating more adaptive planning and processes into fisheries management are increasing. This can be facilitated through greater recognition of the inherent adaptive capacities of fishing communities and using these ca- pacities to support greater community resilience in the face of change. Factors affecting technical implementation These are factors that address more of the practical implementation aspects of fisheries management. 8. Establishing legal group rights and responsibilities. There seems to be widespread agreement that the allocation of clearly defined and limited rights in fisheries is essential if we are to stop further over-capitaliza- tion of the fishery and provide a basis for rebuilding many fisheries into viable, sustainable and equitable entities. Although there is less agreement about the form of those rights, there is increasing recognition of the value of group-held rights in developing countries where peer pressure can be a valuable force for improved management. Establishing group rights and responsibilities in fisheries can create clear incentives and a sense of commitment to making man- agement work and stimulate a sense of responsibility for the sustainable use of those resources. However, a group’s right to harvest can also become the group’s right to over-exploit if adequate checks and balances are not in place. This would suggest the importance of users and the state sharing roles and responsibilities through some form of co-management structure. These rights should not just be rights to harvest resources but should also include the right to a livelihood, good health care and education, and other human rights so often unavailable to the poor. 9. Incrementally changing to allow for capacity, reflection and negotiated response. Changes in both policy and policy implementation will require substantial changes: in the way fisheries are managed; in the skills, attitudes and knowledge for management; and in new institutional structures, processes and linkages that can facilitate that change. This will require both the courage to make significant changes in what is often a knowledge vacuum, and the humility to accept that other groups of people may have something important to say about fisheries management – including the young, the old, women, processors, traders and shopkeepers. Such massive changes cannot occur quickly, they need time for reflection, experimentation, negotiation and acceptance. It is important to adopt change incrementally to assist this process and provide space for change. 10. Institutional fit and subsidiarity. This change process also requires allocating institutional roles and responsibili- ties at different levels, although decisions should ideally be made as close to the
  • 14. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW xii fishery as is possible while remaining effective. This will often link closely with the administrative devolution processes increasingly being adopted in develop- ing countries. Getting the right institutional fit and the right level of subsidiarity for different roles and responsibilities is important, as is recognizing that it is an iterative and adaptive process that evolves over time. 11. Incorporating politics and political choices. In the past, many of the political influences on fisheries were externalized and left unresolved. Even today, fisheries management remains a contested area, with access and benefits often decided for political reasons, some for the public good, others for the private benefit of politicians or other powerful elites. In- corporating politics and political choices into the planning and implementation of fisheries management is important for achieving a balance between social, economic and environmental objectives. It is also important for gaining access to government funding and support for implementing change, and for achieving coherence between national development policies and sector policies. 12. Sustainably and equitably addressing costs and benefits. Even when there is a budget and political commitment for reform, it is still important to implement management efficiently and to share the costs and benefits of fisheries management in ways that are fair – and seen to be fair. Ad- dressing costs and benefits sustainably and equitably is vital if fisheries man- agement is to gain support from the community and wider society. However, at present, the understanding of costs and benefits is poorly documented. More needs to be done to improve understanding in order to allow informed decisions at all levels, such as by investigating the role of fishers in the funding of the management process based on the improved gains and how that links into local economic growth. 13. Getting market measures right. There is potential for the markets to improve the livelihoods of fishers through better returns for fish caught sustainably and equitably. With the public’s in- creasing awareness of the damage poorly managed fisheries can inflict on coastal ecosystems, their willingness to pay for such damage is being tested through certification schemes and eco-labeling. However, changes in the way fish har- vesting is carried out generally has costs, particularly for producers, making it important to introduce these market-driven measures in support of better fisheries management in the correct sequence and in ways that avoid having adverse effects on poor and vulnerable producers. Given women’s important role in fish processing and trade, it is important that they are fully engaged in all decision-making around this and other fisheries management decisions. Factors affecting community engagement These factors are concerned with engagement at the community and household levels. They will influence, and be influenced by, technical implementation factors and those concerned with policy and planning.
  • 15. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW xiii 14. Understanding dependency. A key factor that affects the way people behave in response to management decisions is their level of dependency on the resource. Some people are full-time fishers and have no other income source. Others are part-time or seasonal fishers, or use the resource as a safety net. For many poor people, fisheries will be part of a portfolio of household livelihood activities which may involve more than one household member. Understanding how different stakeholder groups depend on the fishery is essential to ensuring fair and sustainable management decisions. 15. Balancing exclusion, livelihoods alternatives and the local economy. Ultimately, fisheries management decisions will involve some people being included in the right to fish and some being excluded. Those excluded may be current fishers or future generations that may wish to join the fishery. There need to be alternative livelihood options for those who are excluded because, otherwise, they are likely to become impoverished or will try to circumvent entry regulations. Fisheries are generally closely linked to the local economy in which they operate, making it essential that they become a well-integrated part of the local economic development process. Getting the right balance among exclusion, alternative livelihoods and local economic growth is important to the sustainable and equitable development of small-scale fisheries. It is also important to get the sequencing of decisions around controls over entry requirements and livelihood alternatives right. 16. Building capacity. If fishing communities are to play a greater role in both decision-making and management implementation, then many will also need support in building their capacity to take on these new roles. Good leadership skills are essential, especial- ly those which encourage inclusiveness and negotiation. Bringing communities together to work in collaboration is important, as is clearly defining what their roles and responsibilities are under the law and how far they extend geographi- cally. Ensuring that the poor are fully included in this process is important. 17. Engaging with fishers’ motives and preferences. While many assumptions have to be made about the social, economic and ecolog- ical development factors surrounding fisheries management, perhaps one of the most important areas of knowledge to get right is understanding and engaging with fishers’ motives and preferences. Many fisheries management efforts have gotten into trouble because managers have made assumptions about the way fishers will behave that have proved to be wrong. For example, considerable conflict arises over time preference – fishers, managers, politicians and funders all have different time horizons and meshing them is particularly difficult. 18. Addressing commitment, compliance, conflict and enforcement. Addressing many of the factors above will encourage a greater commitment of fishers to the management process. However, there also will be a need to
  • 16. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW xiv address compliance, conflict and enforcement in order, for example, to enforce regulations quickly and effectively, and to develop conflict resolution processes. A greater emphasis on co-management of small-scale coastal fishers is likely to increase group pressure to comply, but enforcement is likely to remain with gov- ernment and must be recognized as effective. 19. Ensuring participation and inclusion. Implicit in all of these factors is a greater level of participation and inclusion of fishers and their wider communities in decision-making around fisheries man- agement. This should include fish traders and processors, money lenders, gear suppliers and those responsible for wider community and local economic devel- opment. Men and women, the poor and the well-off, the old and the young, ethnic and religious groups, all have different perspectives and need to be involved. This will make for more representative decision-making while also supporting a more empowering process. 20. Linking different knowledge management systems. An important part of inclusion is recognizing the value of both traditional eco- logical knowledge and experience-based knowledge in the management process. A sharing of roles and responsibilities across formal and informal systems of knowledge generation, sharing and use is likely to reduce costs and, at the same time, increase the relevance of knowledge used. The linking of knowledge man- agement systems will provide a very important reflection of mutual trust and cooperation. Discussion, conclusions and ways forward As this research has shown, there is no simple universal cure for the problems that small-scale coastal fisheries face in many developing countries. It is likely that this is also true for fisheries more generally. However, this does not mean that fisheries cannot achieve a much more balanced equitable and sustainable trajectory into the future. The 20 factors identified in this report could help to achieve this, and there are doubtless others that would emerge from a more comprehensive study. Already, a number of these factors are starting to combine and to have a positive effect in some fisheries. There is also increasing recognition that a greater emphasis on getting the process right for specific contexts, rather than adopting a uniform approach for all fisheries, is likely to lead to better outcomes. Efforts to distill some of these factors into principles for management began with the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries. The specific needs of small-scale fisheries that go beyond the Code have been progressively recognized and the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) is currently producing the International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-Scale Fisheries which address many of the emerging issues associated with fisheries management. These Guidelines are intended to enhance the contribution of small-scale fisheries to poverty alleviation, food security and economic growth.
  • 17. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW xv It is important to recognize that achieving success in fisheries management will take a long time, a substantial financial commitment, enhanced sharing of knowledge and experience, political support and a commitment to building capacity at all levels.
  • 19. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 1 1 1. Background to the synthesis As part of its new model of operation, the Rockefeller Foundation is undertaking synthesis reviews to strengthen its knowledge and evidence base of what works and what does not work in its key areas of interest. The primary purpose of synthesis reviews is to enable Foundation initiative teams and their grantees to build on what is known, avoid the pitfalls of others and add value to the area of endeavor by not dupli- cating efforts. The Foundation’s Oceans and Fisheries Initiative aims to determine effective ways to integrate natural ecosystems into their economic and social systems. Research under- taken by the Foundation shows that oceans are in a state of crisis due, in large part, to rampant overfishing that has occurred for several decades. Millions of people, par- ticularly the poor and vulnerable who depend on the productivity of marine resources for their food security and livelihoods, are seeing these eroded because of declining ocean health. Efforts to emphasize resource conservation and sustainable manage- ment while addressing the social and economic vulnerabilities of fishing communities will have high potential to deliver joint benefits for ecosystems and for people. The Foundation’s body of work aims to shift paradigms in the environmental community in order to incorporate powerful new approaches including innovative financing, ap- proaches and diffusion, and more purposeful planning for scale. Oceans and Fisheries is a new Initiative in Development for the Rockefeller Founda- tion. Consistent with the Foundation’s operating model, the dual objectives of Initia- tives in Development are to quickly synthesize a wide variety of knowledge to inform internal decision-making for larger-scale investment while contributing significant public goods to the field, regardless of the Foundation’s potential future investment in this space. In its Search process (the stage prior to Development), the Foundation explored the potential for grant making in the areas of fisheries, aquaculture, poverty and food security as a means of improving the lives of poor and vulnerable populations. In addition to generating significant knowledge, the results of the Search concluded that this area of work had significant potential. As a result, the Foundation approved a 15-month Initiative in Development spanning late March 2013 until April, 2014. To learn quickly from existing knowledge in the field, the Initiative team wished to learn from “a synthesis of knowledge and evidence of critical success factors for in-
  • 20. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 2 terventions aimed at improving natural resource management and their potential scal- ability, with a particular emphasis on the field of coastal/near shore fisheries manage- ment and the links to poor, vulnerable, or marginalized populations” (the Rockefeller Foundation, internal document). The objectives for this synthesis are built upon the Foundation team’s latest understanding of the field and, to the extent of its knowledge, reflect insufficiently studied areas of inquiry. Its focus is on integrating the socio- ecological factors in the management of coastal small-scale fisheries in developing countries and their effects and impacts. Thus, in order to undertake a rapid review1 of key formal and informal knowledge sources and identify factors influencing the success, failure and potential scalability of fisheries management that combine ecological and socio-economic objectives, this report: • synthesizes key lessons from past and on-going ecosystem-based community management efforts and programs, with a focus on fisheries and, where possible, other sectors • identifies key insights in terms of factors contributing to the success and failure of ecosystem-based community management (ECM) and their implications for the Foundation’s work • provides a preliminary assessment of critical success factors for their potential to be catalytic in achieving (or inhibiting) impact at scale • identifies outliers of interest to the Foundation • identifies key players and their areas of expertise in relation to key lessons. It focuses on the lessons learned regarding key success factors from past and ongoing work on managing small-scale fisheries in developing countries to achieve a balance between social, economic and environmental benefits in sustainable and equitable ways, and presents a synthesis of the lessons emerging from the key documents reviewed and interviews held around this area of work. The report starts with an outline of the methods used in the synthesis work. This is followed by a background section on coastal fisheries, an outline of key fisheries management approaches and the impacts that fisheries management has had. It then identifies 20 critical factors that influence success in coastal small-scale fisheries management. These factors are reviewed at three levels: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical implementation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. These factors are then discussed, conclusions drawn and ways forward briefly outlined. 1 The study took place over a 10-week period from July to September 2013.
  • 21. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 3 2 2. Research process and methods Theresearchprocesswasorganizedintofourstages:studydesign, formal knowledge search and screening, informal knowledge search, and analysis and report writing. The elements of each stage are outlined in the sections below. 2.1 Stage 1: Study design The study design was developed from Terms of Reference (TORs) drafted by the Rockefeller Foundation and based on an analysis of knowledge gaps around fisheries management that needed to be addressed to inform its development strategy for en- gagement with the sector. On the basis of the TORs, IMM’s research team prepared a research protocol. The study design outlined in the research protocol proposed a search strategy focusing on both formal and informal knowledge sources. Formal knowledge search This search focused on documented knowledge from two key areas: academic peer review literature and institutional grey literature. The academic literature search was based on five electronic reference databases: • Web of Knowledge: Web of Science • Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts (ASFA) • Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts (ASSIA) • Directory of Open Access Journals (DOAJ) • Scirus. The institutional grey literature search was carried out using institutional website search engines and online library databases. To guide the search, an institutional map was developed of key institutions likely to be involved in the areas covered by the synthesis. These included academic institutions, donors and funding agencies (including foundations), intergovernmental agencies, regional fisheries management organizations and NGOs.
  • 22. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 4 Informal knowledge search. This search focused on the experiential knowledge of key informants working in the field of fisheries management. Key informants were also asked to identify important formal knowledge resources, which were obtained through online searches or sent directly to us by the informant. 2.2 Stage 2: Formal knowledge search and screening Keyword search strategy The search of formal knowledge sources applied a keyword search strategy based on the principal topics of relevance to this synthesis (see Table 1). TABLE 1: Principal topics and keywords search strategy TOPIC 1 AND TOPIC 2 AND TOPIC 3 Fish* Ecosystem Natural Resource *Manage* Community-based Adaptive NEAR *manage Coast* * / AND / NEAR represent Boolean search operators Initially searches combined Topic 1 and 2 keywords and applied this strategy to the whole document. To further narrow the search (for searches yielding over 6,000 results), Topic 3 was applied. Then if necessary, the search was applied to fewer document fields (e.g. title or abstract). Once a search yielded less than 6,000 results, it was exported to EndNote, a library software package. The keyword search strategy was applied consistently to all five electronic reference databases. Where possible this strategy was also adopted for the institutional grey literature search. However, if a searchable library database was not available, a manual search of publication lists for relevant topics (e.g. fishery management and governance, co-management, ecosystem approach to fisheries) was undertaken. In total, 26 institutional websites were searched. In addition, the IMM office library and reference libraries of team members were searched to identify additional grey litera- ture that, from experience, was considered useful. All searches were recorded in a search log which indicated the number of results for each search and which searches were downloaded into EndNote (see Annex 1). Inclusion criteria An initial set of inclusion criteria, developed to ensure the documents compiled for the review were accessible and relevant, included: • YEAR OF PUBLICATION: the study must be published in or after 1990 • LANGUAGE: the study must be published in English • GEOGRAPHIC RELEVANCE: the study must be based on evidence from developed countries • TOPIC RELEVANCE: the study must pertain to management initiatives and factors of their success/failure in relation to coastal marine fisheries, including articles that examined relevant management concepts or theories.
  • 23. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 5 For the institutional grey literature searches, documents were screened for inclusion criteria based on their title, and only those meeting the criteria were exported to EndNote. In total, 141 accessible and relevant documents were identified from the institutional grey literature search. Further grey literature documents were identified from the IMM and team libraries. For the academic literature searches, the year of publication criteria was combined with the initial keyword search. In total, 16,923 academic references were compiled from the five electronic databases. Of these, 7,304 were identified as duplicates and removed, leaving a library of 9,619 documents to be screened for language and relevance inclusion criteria.2 Inclusion screening was applied to the title and abstract of each document. A coding system was used during screening to identify the reason for exclusion. This provided an outlier library resource, containing documents which may have potential insights for the synthesis but may be outside the geographical relevance (e.g. developed country) or topic relevance (e.g. inland fishery or forestry management). Following inclusion screening, a total of 1,166 documents were identified as accessible and relevant for the synthesis. Included academic literature documents were further screened to identify documents of particular relevance to the synthesis. These included overviews or reviews of fisheries management initiatives at multiple sites. In total, 195 documents were identi- fied as key documents, with snowball sampling from citation lists of key documents also yielding further documents. The overall formal knowledge search and screening yielded 1,379 relevant documents for review, as summarized in Table 2. TABLE 2: Summary of formal knowledge search results ACADEMIC LITERATURE SEARCH RESULTS Keyword search results Included documents Key documents Excluded: Developed country Excluded: Relevant off topic 9,613 1,166 195 2,940 1,045 GREY LITERATURE SEARCH RESULTS Website search results IMM library search & snowball sampling 150 63 2.3 Stage 3: Informal knowledge search From the institutional grey literature search and from the research team’s experience of the sector, a number of key informants were contacted to take part in semi-struc- 2 Due to the export functionality of the Directory of Open Access Journals (DOAJ) and Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts (ASSIA) databases, inclusion screening for language and relevance criteria was carried out as documents were exported to EndNote. This yielded 45 documents.
  • 24. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 6 tured interviews. Interviews were conducted in person, by telephone or email, and were guided by a checklist of topics and questions (see Annex 2). In total, the team contacted 55 individuals, of whom 20 were interviewed and 4 replied to an email checklist, as summarized in Table 3 below. Approximately half of those contacted were unavailable, or failed to respond, which may be explained by the fact that the synthesis was conducted during a holiday season. TABLE 3: Summary of the informal knowledge search INSTITUTIONS CONTACTS MADE INTERVIEWS CONDUCTED In person Telephone Email Intergovernmental/multi-lateral organizations 7 2 - 1 International development banks 3 - 3 - Government organizations 2 - 1 1 Regional fisheries management organizations 3 - - 1 Research institutions 18 - 5 - Non-governmental organizations 15 - 6 Fisher organizations 7 - 3 1 2.4 Stage 4: Analysis and report writing Analysis of documents initially focused on the full text of key documents identified from the academic literature search. As the review progressed, documents identi- fied through snowball sampling of citation lists and from the institutional grey litera- ture search were also analyzed. This analysis revealed a number of preliminary key success factors, which were reviewed and revised to fit more closely to the available evidence as the analysis developed. These factors were finally grouped into three areas: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical implemen- tation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. This analysis was cross refer- enced against the results of the informal knowledge search in order to triangulate the results. This provided the basis for the report’s results and discussion. Given that the study had only two months to complete the search and analysis, only a limited number of documents could be reviewed in the time available. Ultimately, the scope of knowledge included in the report reflects the limitations imposed by this time schedule. In total, approximately 170 documents were reviewed. As such, it is recognized that a continued review of the formal knowledge search results would reveal additional information that may be of benefit. However, the level of repetition in the results suggests that the synthesis represents an acceptable level of convergence of thought.
  • 25. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 7 3 3. Background to coastal fisheries This section provides a brief summary of the global fisheries sector: its importance, its current state, the effectiveness of fisheries management measures and the potential of the sector. The coastal environment is one of the most diverse parts of the planet with many ecosystems and species. This diversity, combined with the dynamic and changing nature of coasts, creates conditions for the provision of a wide range of ecosystem services which benefit humans as individuals and societies including: food from fish, building materials from reefs and mangroves, storm protection for coastal communi- ties, medicines and cultural traditions, as well as wider regulatory support services. Fish are harvested from all coastal countries throughout the world. In developing countries, fisheries are particularly important for providing food and nutrition security, income and employment. The diversity of species and habitats in coastal areas provides a range of opportunities for the livelihoods of men, women and children, and the open access nature of many resources provides opportunities for the poor. However, the vital role of coastal ecosystem services is being undermined by over-fish- ing, habitat destruction and pollution. As a consequence, many of the world’s fisheries are at, or beyond, their sustainable limits of harvesting. Fisheries management has been used to try to halt or reverse this adverse situation, but overall it has failed to improve matters significantly. If fisheries can be successfully managed, then their potential con- tribution to food, employment, foreign exchange generation and poverty reduction can be both large and sustainable. This is discussed in more detail below. 3.1 The importance of coastal fisheries The coast is one of the most ecologically diverse ecosystems – a diversity that creates many livelihood opportunities for different groups of people. Because of the relatively open access nature of coastal fisheries and the low cost of entering, these opportuni- ties attract many poor people into the fishery and, in turn, the fishing supports many different forms of livelihoods for different groups of people. The main attraction of the
  • 26. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 8 coastal waters is the ability to harvest fish for food and to sell, but this is only part of the engagement of the community with the coastal system. Fisheries ecology The sea covers 71 percent of the surface of the earth and constitutes 96.5 percent of all water by volume. It is one of the most biologically diverse parts of the planet in terms of both ecosystem diversity and species diversity. Much of that diversity is concentrated in coast fringes where small-scale fisheries often operate (Campbell and Beardmore, 2001). Key habitats include: • open sea • deep ocean floor • continental slopes • sea mounts • mud/sand banks • inshore coastal areas • coral reefs • mudflats • sandy beaches • kelp forests • estuaries • mangroves • deltas • lagoons These different habitats are often mutually supporting with, for example, reefs providing shelter for sea grass areas and sand for beaches. The habitats also link the different lifecycles of fish, some as nursery areas and others as adult feeding and breeding areas. Connectivity between these is important in the wider ecological balance. Although coral reefs cover less than 0.1 percent of the ocean (250,000 km2 ), they are the most productive and biologically rich ecosystems on earth with around 25 percent of all known marine species (Burke et al., 2011). They occur mainly in coastal areas where fisheries are particularly important. Fish production The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) monitors the world’s fisheries on a regular basis. Capture fisheries and aquaculture supplied the world with an estimated 154 million tonnes of fish in 2011 (with a total value of $217.5 billion), of which about 131 million tonnes was utilized as food for people (FAO, 2012a) (See Table 4). Fish production maintained a growth rate of 3.2 percent per year in the period 1961–2009, outstripping population growth. TABLE 4: Global fish production by year and source in millon tonnes 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 CAPTURE Inland 9.8 10 10.2 10.4 11.2 11.5 Marine 80.2 80.4 79.5 79.2 77.4 78.9 Total 90.0 90.3 89.7 89.6 88.6 90.4 CULTURE Inland 31.2 33.4 36 38.1 41.7 44.3 Marine 16.0 16.6 16.9 17.6 18.1 19.3 Total 46.3 49.9 52.9 55.7 59.9 63.6 TOTAL WORLD PRODUCTION 137.3 140.2 142.6 145.3 148.5 154.0 Source: FAO, 2012a
  • 27. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 9 Table 1 shows that while wild capture fisheries have remained relatively static in recent years, aquaculture has grown considerably. Aquaculture now makes up 41 percent of total fish availability compared with 51 percent from marine capture fisheries (FAO, 2012a). The global fishing fleet is comprised of 4.36 million vessels, of which 74 percent work in marine fisheries. Asia has the largest fleet with 73 percent, Africa has 11 percent and Latin America and the Caribbean has 8 percent (FAO, 2012a). Food and nutrition security World per capita food fish supply increased from an average of 9.9 kg (live weight equivalent) in the 1960s to 18.4 kg in 2009 and is set to increase further (FAO, 2012a). In 2010, fish production provided a global fish consumption rate of 18.7 kg/person/ year with consumption rates varying across the globe from 9.1 kg/person/year in Africa to 24.6 kg/person/year in Oceania. Fish makes up 16.6 percent of all animal protein consumed and 6.5 percent of all protein consumed by people. Globally, fish provides about 3.0 billion people with almost 20  percent of their intake of animal protein, and 4.3 billion people with about 15 percent (FAO, 2012a). Fish also provide other benefits such as micro-nutrients (MRAG et al., 2013) that are particularly important in the diets of the poor. In most developing countries, fish is sold mainly in live or fresh form (representing 56  percent of fish destined for human consumption in 2010). Cured forms of fish (dried, salted, smoked or fermented) still remain important in developing country markets, although the share of fish that is processed is declining (FAO, 2012a). Fish and fishery products are among the world’s most traded food commodities. In 2010, fishery trade represented about 10  percent of total agricultural exports (excluding forest products) and 1 percent of world merchandise trade in value terms (FAO, 2012a). Fisheries livelihoods and poverty reduction There are some 54.8 million people involved in the production of fish. An estimated 660–820 million people, or 10–12  percent of the global population, depend upon fisheries and aquaculture for their livelihoods: 87 percent of them in Asia, 7 percent in Africa and 3.6 percent in Latin America and the Caribbean (FAO, 2012a). Of the people directly employed in capture fisheries (production and processing), 97 percent live in developing countries and 90 percent work in small-scale fisheries (Hall and Andrew, 2011). It is thought that, on average, 30 percent of people employed in fisheries overall are women mainly in fish processing and trade (FAO, 2012a). Many of the people involved in small-scale fisheries in developing countries are poor, marginalized or vulnerable to adverse change. According to Pomeroy (1994, 3), “[i]n many parts of the world, rights to common property are all that separate the poor from destitution.” While many of these people are poor, vulnerable and margin- alized, an important question is “are they poor because they are fishers, or are they fishers because they are poor?” (Béné, 2003). The answer is complex and is probably a mixture of both.
  • 28. 10 Coastal fishers live in one of the most dynamic and contested parts of the world where risk is a part of their livelihood strategies (Campbell et al., 2006). This creates oppor- tunities for poor people that others may consider too costly or unpredictable, but it also creates threats to life, assets, income and savings, which means there is consider- able movement into and out of poverty in fishing communities. Fishers often live adjacent to areas of high biological diversity which creates a diversity of opportunities to employ different combinations of labor, skill, experience- based knowledge, capital, technical knowledge, risk-avoidance strategies, market knowledge and access, and seasonal time allocation (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). This diversity often, at least initially, reduces competition from other fishers that require the economies of scale afforded by less ecologically diverse environments. Increasingly, however, such biological diversity is attracting tourism which offers both threats (land acquisition, pollution, habitat destruction) and opportunities (markets for seafood, alternative employment opportunities). Where barriers to entry are low, such as open access fisheries, where there is low competition or where entry requires little investment in, e.g. skills or equipment, poor people can often find niches as in- dividual fishers or as hired crew. While there is high gender differentiation in most fisheries (generally with men catching fish and women processing and trading), some habitats, such as coral reefs, provide opportunities for women to glean food for domestic consumption or trade, an activity which often provides an important social and cultural function (Whittingham et al., 2003). In addition, women in many parts of the world play an important role in owning and financing fishing operations. However, while open access coastal fisheries attract poor people, they often remain poor, because: • they have inherent risks working in such difficult environments, where catch pre- dictability is low • they have few enforceable rights over land and fish resources • they have competition in harvesting combined with pollution, habitat destruction, increasing climate change and decreasing catches • they may be marginalized to poorer parts of the fishery or excluded at certain times • they are dealing with highly perishable products, where market access is difficult and market knowledge poor • their investment in boats, gear, fuel and labor is often dependent on loans from middle men and women who are able to charge high costs for their services • their lack of rights over land and access to fisheries resources (especially for the very poor, migrant workers, certain classes and castes of people, and ethnic mi- norities) often means that their activities fall outside of the law and the decision- making processes (Béné, 2003; Campbell et al., 2006). For small-scale processors and traders, increasing competition for supply, changing market and quality-control demands, concentration of landings in fewer landing sites, and changes in investment levels in processing and trade are often leading to signifi- cant shifts in the structure of the post-harvest fisheries sector – changes that often marginalize small-scale operators. In some areas where women previously played key roles in post-harvest fisheries, more men may be found entering processing and trade, which is leading to reduced opportunities and increased competition for small-scale female traders and processors (IMM and ICM, 2003).
  • 29. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 11 3.2 The state of coastal fisheries There can be little doubt that the world’s fisheries are in suboptimal condition (see Box 1). In 2009, 29.9 percent of global fish stocks were overexploited, 57.4 percent were fully exploited and 12.7 percent were not-fully exploited (FAO, 2012a). Most of the fully exploited stocks are at their maximum sustainable yield (MSY) and therefore not achieving their full economic potential. FAO (2012a, 200), in its analysis of global fisheries in 2012, stated that the results “are troubling from a resource exploitation perspective and suggest a global system that is overstressed, reducing in biodiversity and in imminent danger of collapse.” In addition, many key ecosystems on which the health of marine fisheries depend are being degraded. Mangrove forests have been widely depleted and, over the past 50 years, approximately one-third of the world’s mangrove forests have been lost (Alonghi, 2002), 29  percent of sea grasses have been lost (Waycott et al., 2008) and more than 75 percent of coral reefs are under immediate threat from local and global forces (Burke et al., 2011). In addition, 60 percent of coral reefs are threatened by local pressures such as over-fishing, destructive fishing, coastal development, watershed-based pollution, or marine-based pollution and damage (Burke et al., 2011). In addition to pressures on species and eco- systems, there are also significant economic losses from the sector. World Bank-FAO (2009) estimated global losses of net economic benefit at some US$50 billion, due to excess harvesting capacity and effort, linked with capital and operating-cost subsidies. In 2003, subsidies primarily to support overfishing were estimated at $16.2 billion out of a total of $27 billion globally (Sumaila et al., 2010). In addition, illegal, unreported and unregulated (IUU) fishing is now a major concern for many fisheries, with global losses estimated at between $9 billion and $24 billion annually, representing between 11 and 26 million tons of fish or between 10 percent and 22 percent of total fisheries production (MRAG, 2009). These losses impact directly on the availability of fish for small-scale fishers. Marine and, in particular, coastal habitats and resources are under increasing threat from a variety of sources (Campbell, 1996; Bryant et al., 1998; Whittingham et al., 2003) (see Box 2) including: • habitat loss, destruction and fragmentation as a result of agriculture, aquaculture, fishing, urban growth, port developments and tourism • pollution from industry, mining, farming, aquaculture and urban development • changes in water sediment loads from agriculture, forestry and mining BOX 1: Overfishing in Asia An Asian Development Bank (ADB)-funded, WorldFish-implemented regional fisheries project in Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and Sri Lanka identified the central issue of fisheries as drastically depleted resources – resulting from overfishing and compounded by environmental degradation. All fisheries had harvesting rates that were greater than those required to achieve maximum sustainable yields or maximum economic yields. Overfishing was found to be intimately linked to poverty among fishing communities, where fishing was seen to be the income of last resort. The de facto open access regime of the fishery allowed more and more people to join the fishery. Source: Stobutzki et al., 2006
  • 30. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 12 • changes in water flows as a result of deforestation, abstraction for irrigation and human consumption, and hydroelectric dams • excessive or inappropriate exploitation of resources • inappropriate genetic manipulation and selection in aquaculture • introduction of exotic species from aquaculture, the aquarium trade, ships ballast tanks • climate variability resulting in periodic coastal shocks • climate-related changes such as changes in sea level, sea temperatures and pred- ator-prey relations. The reasons for the poor state of global fisheries are complicated (Rudd et al., 2003). They are complex systems that combine social, economic, ecological and political forces which are difficult to reconcile. Fisheries management has been a major component of the wider sector development process that has been used to address some of these issues. However, fisheries management has not been very successful across global fisheries. According to Bromley (2009), “the imperiled status of global fish stocks offers clear evidence of the comprehensive failure of nationalgovernmentstoprovidecoherentman- agement to protect those stocks.” This reflects the complex nature of fisheries management as will be discussed later. As Hilborn noted, “fisheries management isn’t rocket science, it is actually quite a bit harder” (Western Star, 2009). 3.3 The potential of coastal fisheries In spite of these management issues, the potential of fisheries, if managed well, is con- siderable. What form that potential will take will depend on how and why fisheries are managed. The ability of depleted fisheries to recover and achieve their maximum potential will depend, to an extent, on how that potential is measured, i.e. in terms of production max- imization, economic return maximization, environmental protection or employment maximization. The length of time required to return fisheries to their desired state will also vary, depending on the current state of the stocks and the species concerned. Even with management, multiple-species stocks are likely to evolve gradually towards an equilibrium which may or may not be the same as before exploitation. There is, however, broad recognition of the potential of fisheries to bounce back from the current state of mismanagement and to continue to provide benefits into the future. What those benefits are and who benefits from them are largely political decisions that countries will have to decide. The following section reviews a variety of management themes that have been used in the quest to achieve that potential. BOX 2: Reef destruction Coral reefs are seen as an important source of food and income through the sale of fish in many coastal communities. However, there are also examples where the sustainability of this ecosystem service is being threatened by coral mining. In Tanzania, live and dead coral was extracted for lime production in the 1990s. On Mafia Island, coral mining was ranked third among income- earning activities, in terms of the number of people involved. After commercial lime production was made illegal this fell rapidly. Source: Tobey and Torell, 2006
  • 31. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 13 4 4. Fisheries management approaches and themes This section discusses the concept of fisheries management, its evolution and how it manifests itself in modern fisheries. It looks at the broad management themes that have been adopted and briefly discusses each of these. Fisheries management has been defined as: “The integrated process of information gathering, analysis, planning, consultation, decision-making, allocation of resources and formulation and implementation, with enforcement as necessary, of regulations or rules which govern fisheries activities in order to ensure the continued productiv- ity of the resources and the accomplishment of other fisheries objectives”(Cochrane, 2002, 3). In the past, there was widespread discussion of the different merits of economic, social and biological objectives and management strategies for fisheries. Much of the focus was on the maximization of productivity and production targets, which remains the key indicator of success used by many governments around the world. However, as the realization has grown that fish stock harvesting cannot be continuously increased, the focus has increasingly shifted towards environmental management. The social aspects also have taken a more prominent role in strategies, due to a greater focus on reduction of global poverty and recognition that fish and fisheries play an important role in the livelihoods of many poor people. The conflicts among the different management schools of thought continue. However, efforts are being made to bring these disparate threads together into a management process that harmonizes different aims and strategies to achieve a balance across social, economic and environmental sector objectives. In reality, a fishery is a complex system which links individual human endeavor, en- terprise, risk, culture, the physical world, technology, the natural world, the political economy and wider society’s beliefs, aspirations and values (Campbell and Catter- moul, 2009). According to Ostrom (2009a), all human-used resources are embedded
  • 32. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 14 in complex, social-ecological systems composed of multiple subsystems and the internal variables within these subsystems at multiple levels. Scientists have often responded by developing simple theoretical models to analyze aspects of the resource problems and to prescribe universal solutions (Ostrom, 2009a). In their attempts to understand and interact with fisheries, scientists have often tried to simplify or break down the complexity. Thus they can work with its separate parts by, for example, focusing on specific components of fisheries, such as gear/vessel classification, or over-simplifying relationships implicit in bio-econom- ic models. As the crisis in world fisheries deepens, the pressure to find workable solutions increases. The combination of complexity and urgency has created a market for quick and technical solutions to management problems (Degnbol et al., 2006). But these rarely do more than explain a part of what is happening in localized situations at a given time. As Dengbol et al. explained, these “fixes” often lead to tunnel vision. The responsibility for the management of fisheries has been disputed for many years. In many traditional communities, management has been a function of the community itself. In the Pacific, for instance, the rights to resources are often part of a complex web of social and cultural relations between and within communities and kinship groups. More recently, and particularly as fisheries have come under increasing pressure, the state has taken on a greater role in their management. However, governments are no longer the only source of decision-making in fisheries or other environmental fields (Armitage et al., 2012) where collaborative approaches involving a number of stakeholders are becoming accepted. This is important because different groups of people want different things from the resource, at different times and collected in different ways. Armitage et al. (2012) argued that while “command and control” management systems have yielded success in terms of flows of ecosystem services, they have done so at social and environmental cost – social cost related to compliance, enforcement and conflict, and environmental cost due to declines in regulating and providing ecosystem services. They noted that management and gov- ernance systems are not mutually exclusive and suggested that cooperative models of governance are more likely to work effectively within an enabling system of govern- ment regulation. However, the very concept of management is sometimes questioned and the broader approach of governance, which considers the wider processes and institutions through which society makes decisions, is often seen as more appropriate (Armitage et al., 2012). Governance of resources raises questions that go far beyond narrow manage- ment concerns and start to address more philosophical issues about wider benefit flows to society and to future generations. The form and function of governance often reflect the wider changes in society’s approaches, concerns and priorities, the market realities, and the cost-cutting motives of government to hand over responsibility for that management. Whiletherearenoclear-cutorseparatemodelsoffisheriesmanagement,therearebroad approaches or themes that reflect the emphasis of a particular management process in a particular situation. Some are suited to some circumstances, others to other cir- cumstances. Management methods developed for single species fisheries in temperate waters, for example, may be unsuited to tropical multi-species inshore fisheries (Rudd
  • 33. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 15 et al., 2003) where ecological and fish landing data are poor, where there are few formal property rights, where many operators compete for resources with different gear from many sites, and where people regularly move in and out of the fishery. Often these approaches or themes are combined, as in the use of marine protected areas with co- management, to address different aspects of the management process. These management themes can be grouped in numerous ways. We have identified seven broad themes reflecting different aims: i) customary marine tenure, ii) yield maximization, iii) conservation of resources, iv) economic maximization, v) rights- based approaches, vi) ecosystem-based management and vii) co-management. There is much overlap between them, and which ones are used depends very much on the local context. These are reviewed in the following sections. 4.1 Customary marine tenure (CMT) Traditional community-based resources management systems have been document- ed across the world by, e.g. Ruddle et al. (1992) and Kuemlangan (2004). Berkes et al. (2000) noted that resource monitoring has been a regular feature of traditional systems that note and act upon the abundance of different species. Sacred sites may have provided some protection to species much as a marine protected area does. For example, Berkes et al. (2000) recalled how some indigenous people “rested” their fisheries on a periodic basis, and that traditional fisheries sometimes used methods that are only beginning to be adopted by more formal systems. Some traditional com- munities have tended to conceptualize their fisheries as multi-species, rather than single species, and also to view the interconnectedness of land and water systems. In their review of the similarities among some 30 traditional fishing societies throughout the world, Acheson et al. (1998 cited in Berkes et al., 2000) suggested that the similari- ties indicate some geographic transfer of knowledge. Many customary marine tenure (CMT) arrangements may have resulted in the sus- tainable and equitable use of fisheries resources, in part because there was limited fishing pressure. Many continued to operate when resources declined and effort sub- stantially increased, but with varying degrees of success. However, it needs to be remembered that these CMT systems are often primarily mechanisms that govern exchange and social relations within and between traditional communities and groups, rather than explicitly protecting resources. While customary marine tenure may have been associated largely with traditional systems, there is increasing recognition that it also has a role to play, albeit in modified form, in modern management systems. For example, Kuemlangan (2004) noted that a “[a] cursory examination of PIC (Pacific Island Countries) Constitutions, fisheries legislation and general natural resource management practice indicate that the PICs have the necessary minimum legal basis for application of CMT, and are receptive to or already practise participatory approaches to fisheries management including those based on CMT.” Today, there is renewed interest in learning from these approaches and applying them to rights-based approaches at the community level. But, it is also recognized that com- munity-based approaches more generally are not a panacea for resource management (Pomeroy, 1994).
  • 34. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 16 4.2 Yield maximizing approaches As mentioned above, in the past, the focus of fisheries management and development tended to focus on ways of maximizing production. Speaking at the opening of the 1883 International Fisheries Exhibition in London, the biologist Thomas Huxley famously stated that “The world’s fish and fisheries are inexhaustible” (Link, 2010). It was only in the 1900s that people began to fully realize that the world’s fish were exhaustible. More recently, there have been concerns about maintaining stock size, retaining bio- diversity and ensuring ecosystem function – with significant tension between those approaches adopted to maximize productivity and those for achieving biological con- servation. For example, the Plan of Implementation of the 2002 World Summit on Sus- tainable Development targeted the restoration of fish stocks to maximum sustainable yield (MSY) levels by 2015. While MSY is a useful concept in a single species stock, it becomes less useful in a multi-species stock with inter-species interaction (Leal, 2010). In addition, limited governmental capacity may limit the ability to assess what MSY actually is. The World Bank-FAO report, The Sunken Billions: The Economic Justifica- tion for Fisheries Reform, suggested that MSY should be considered a minimum target (World Bank-FAO, 2009). The drive to maximize production from fisheries has been, in large part, behind the massive over-capitalization of fisheries and the perverse incentives that now are the norm. As a result, there have been many attempts to control fishing efforts at MSY. These have often involved a series of technical measures including direct gear and fishing effort restrictions, including limits on vessel numbers (e.g. by license), vessel types, engine power, vessel length and gear used. Gear restriction may include mesh size restrictions, hook size, net length and the use of excluder devices. Restrictions may also be on species, fish length or age, total weight taken, weights landed (and thus discards) and breeding state. Fishing activities may be limited by physical areas which may range from zones where no fishing occurs at any time of the year to lesser restrictions that allow certain gears by certain people at certain times. These might include inshore fishing areas for small-scale fishers. Such spatial restrictions, often called marine management areas (MMAs), are discussed in more detail below. In some fisheries, total allowable catches (TACs) of different species are designated and, in some cases, quotas are allocated within that. They may be allocated directly (free of cost or for a fee) or through an auction system. These different measures have come into favor and gone out of favor in different fisheries at different times. In Scott’s (2010) useful chronology of such changes, he identified a general movement from gear restrictions, through licenses, to quotas and to property rights with a move towards stronger qualities of rights including: greater exclusivity, greater permanence, greater transferability, greater divisibility and greater security. 4.3 Conservation of resources Approaches to conserve resources have adopted a number of measures to limit the ability of fishers to harvest resources. While technical measures (as outlined above)
  • 35. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 17 have been adopted, marine conservation areas, habitat and stock restoration, and pre- cautionary principles have been a key part of this approach (Hilborn, 2007). The precautionary approach uses foresight to avoid unacceptable or undesirable situ- ations, taking into account that changes in fisheries systems are only slowly revers- ible, difficult to control, not well understood, and subject to change in the environment and human values (FAO, 1996). As Hilborn (2003, 387) noted “[t]he precautionary approach is built around the concept that managers should not wait until they have unequivocal evidence that fishing effort needs to be reduced before acting, and it is intended to protect fisheries from overexploitation in the face of uncertainty.” Even where fisheries are being managed effectively, there is likely to be a need to ensure that forces from outside of the sector do not degrade habitats and stocks. These include land-based pollution, marine pollution, coastal development and climate change. Restoring habitats and stocks to their original condition and limiting external pressure are important components. Marine conservation areas are often referred to as Marine Protected Area (MPAs), including those which are no-take zones and thus have the benefit of protecting the species and individual fish that remain inside the protected area (see Box 3). FAO (2007) listed eight common reasons for establishing MPAs:  i) to protect a specific life history stage, ii) to control fishing mortality, iii) to handle the spillover effect of fish migrating across the boundaries of an MPA so they can be fished, iv) to serve as a source and/or sink for fish eggs and larvae to improve recruitment, v) to protect habitat, food web integrity and biodiversity, vi) to reduce by-catch, discarding and other negative impacts on harvested species, other species, endangered species and other species society wants to protect, vii) to reduce competition between user groups or to enhance opportunities for certain groups of users (by establishing rights), and viii) to serve as a potential hedge against uncer- tainty. However, MPAs take many forms around the world and the language used to describe them differs from place to place, which can lead to considerable confusion (Christie and White, 2006). The effectiveness of MPAs depends in part upon the size and ecological sufficiency of the enclosed area, its level of exclusion and its connectivity to other MPAs. While very large MPAs which are enforced no-take zones effectively eliminate fishing pressure, there still may be other pressures from climatic conditions, non-fisheries pollution or habitat destruction. A review of the experience of inter-coastal manage- ment (ICM) in the Philippines by White et al. (2006) determined that MPAs, as part of wider ICM processes, protect and enhance near-shore habitats and fisheries for BOX 3: Soufrière marine management area in St Lucia The Soufrière Marine Management Area in St Lucia, created in 1995, had a rapid impact on the combined biomass of five commercially important fish families in the adjacent fishing area. Mean total catch per trip per fisher increased by between 46% and 90% over a five-year period with stable fishing effort. Source: Roberts et al., 2001
  • 36. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 18 the benefit of coastal communities, and they attract marine tourism which contributes to the local economy. Key benefits include i) enhanced local biophysical quality of coastal habitats and improved fish catches inside and outside of MPAs, ii) enhanced revenues to communities and local governments derived from tourism within and outside of MPAs, iii) revenues from marine-based or eco-tourism enterprises to local communities, and iv) improved planning and implementation of ICM through 100 municipal and city govern- ments. However, benefits can be mixed, as shown in Box 4. In addition to conserving existing resources, there has been considerable interest in enhancing fish stocks. Bell et al. (2006) stated that the key challenges for capture fisheries are i) reducing fishing effort, ii) removing excess fishing capacity, and iii) building the institutional arrangements needed to restore spawning biomass to more produc- tive levels and reverse degradation of sup- porting habitats. They suggested two options from the cultured production of juveniles to enhance this process – restocking and stock enhancement – although they also recog- nized the difficulties of doing so. Examples of success include scallop stock enhance- ment in Hokkaido, Japan, and giant clam restocking in the Philippines. 4.4 Economic maximization The over-exploitation of fisheries resources is often associated with significant economic losses. When the World Bank and FAO (2009) calculated the current state of fisheries from an economic perspective, FAO reported that “economic losses in marine fisheries resulting from poor management, inefficiencies, and overfishing add up to a staggering US$50 billion per year ... Taken over the last three decades, these losses total over $US2 trillion, a figure roughly equivalent to the GDP of Italy.” The focus of economic approaches calls for the maximization of economic yield (MEY) and the reduction of these losses. MEY – the value of the largest positive difference between total revenues and total costs of fishing – generally requires less fishing effort than what is required to achieve maximum sustainable yield (MSY). Many fisheries managers hope that some of this economic return may be captured by wider society as a resource rent that will provide a return from giving fishers the opportu- nity to profit from the nation’s fishery. Economic approaches often include some of the technical measures discussed above and the use of rights which are outlined below. BOX 4: Impact of marine protected areas (MPAs) in Tanzania The impact on abundance of harvested fish around MPAs in Tanga and Mafia, Tanzania, was perceived to be positive, but impacts were perceived as negligible or negative in other MPA sites. Fishers’ focus group meetings in Tanga and Mafia sites corroborated that MPA efforts have improved the fisheries. The changes in Mafia were further verified by key informant marine experts who knew the condition of the fisheries in the early 1990s and at the time of the study. Finfish, octopus, endangered species such as marine turtles, and even whales and dolphins were returning. However, social and economic changes were less obvious, with only a small impact on household involvement in decision-making, negligible or negative effects on employment, and negligible impact on incomes. Source: Tobey and Torell, 2006
  • 37. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 19 Resource rents can be captured, for example, through charging for the right to fish, either directly on landed catch or by selling licenses for access or selling quota access. One approach to fisheries management which emphasizes the potential economic returns is referred to as wealth-based fisheries manage- ment (WBFM). WBFM calls for using the al- location of fishing rights to capture the wealth that is currently being dissipated through poor management practices (Cunningham et al., 2009). While this has occurred in, for example, Norway, Iceland and New Zealand, there are few examples in developing countries where small-scale, labor-intensive fisheries operate (see Box 5). A key problem is that this approach depends on the capacity of resource managers to assess how much fish catch is sustainable in a particular fishery and establish quotas based on that amount, which can be challenging in developing country fisheries that may lack such information and the capacity to collect it. 4.5 Rights-based approaches In recognition of the adverse effects of the often open-access nature of fisheries, fisheries authorities have been developing a series of approaches to fisheries manage- ment that confer specific rights to some groups of fishers but exclude others. This is an increasing trend in fisheries and other natural resources (Pearse, 1992). Rights-based management of fisheries, in its most basic form, refers to bundles of entitlements that confer both privileges and responsibilities. For example, since the 1980s, countries have established Exclusive Economic Zones (EEZs) through which they claim exclusive rights up to 200 nautical miles from baselines. Such rights-based approaches are evolving to address more complex issues, and discussions referring to “rights-based management” or “rights-based approaches” are now expanded to include human rights (Charles, 2008; FAO, 2010; Charles, 2011) to reach, for example, adequate livelihood and poverty-reduction criteria (Willmann, 2010). Rights are an emotive issue that is much misunderstood. A “right” can be thought of as an entitlement assured by custom, law or property, and defined by legal, social or ethical principles. Some rights have been described as universal, natural, permanent and inalienable while others are thought to be more culturally specific or limited to specific groups. Rights may be defined by international or national law or custom, and may be changed or removed by society. Rights generally involve two parties: those that hold the right and those that have responsibility to uphold the right. The effective- ness of the right is in large part dependent on each party fulfilling its role (Donnelly, 2003). Rights in fisheries have tended to refer to a legally defined ability to do or to own something, e.g. to catch a quota of fish, to access an area of water or to harvest a certain species. BOX 5: An economic approach in practice The Partnership for African Fisheries (PAF), operated under the auspices of the African Union, is currently piloting an approach to the economic rationalization of the fisheries of Africa through wealth-based fisheries management (WBFM). This will inform fisheries policy across the continent. Source: DFID, 2012
  • 38. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 20 Pomeroy (1994) noted that rights and rules, or incentives and sanctions are essential for the effective operation of any fisheries management system. Rights to harvest resources have taken a number of forms that include licenses, individual transferrable quotas (ITQs), and territorial use rights in fisheries (TURFs). In most cases, fisheries rights also have associated responsibilities that need to be adhered to, as reflected in the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries (Charles, 2011). Informal rights are being recognized more and more, and are being converted into formal rights in developing fisheries es- pecially in co-management systems. These informal property or use rights, which have tended to be based around community ownership of resources, are becoming more formally recognized. The draft International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small- Scale Fisheries (GSSF) currently being prepared by FAO (FAO, 2012b, 7) recognizes that “[r]ights and responsibilities should be bestowed on small-scale fishing communi- ties to restore, protect and manage local aquatic and coastal ecosystems on which they depend for their wellbeing and that they have used traditionally for their livelihoods.” For example, individual transferrable quotas (ITQs), used in a number of developed fisheries across the globe, receive much attention in the literature. They can be seen as part of a rights-based approach where the right to a certain part of a total allowable catch (TAC) is transferrable and tradable. They are based on a TAC being established for a fishery and the quotas within the TAC limits being allocated to individuals, vessels or groups. Key questions around the specific design of ITQs include i) method of allocation and charges for a accessing a quota, ii) length of time of ownership of the quota, iii) its transferability between users, iv) divisibility of quotas, v) the ability to assess the TAC and vi) enforcement. 4.6 Ecosystem-based management Ecosystem approaches to fisheries (EAFs) represent a move away from management systems that focus only on the sustainable harvest of target species or the manage- ment of fishers’ behaviors, to a system that also considers the major components of the ecosystem and the social and economic benefits that can be derived from them (FAO, 2012a). EAFs also follow the direction established by the 1993 Convention on Biological Diversity and can be seen as an attempt to reverse the divergence of two management goals that call for i) conserving the structure, diversity and function of ecosystems and ii) satisfying societal and human needs for food and economic benefits (Zhou et al., 2010). But it also recognizes the wider importance of ecosystems services and the long-term benefits of their continuation. FAO’s EAF, adopted by FAO’s Committee on Fisheries (COFI) in 2003 as the most ap- propriate management framework, was explicitly indicated as the target framework by the World Summit of Sustainable Development (WSSD, 2002). FAO (2008) suggested that ecosystem approaches to fisheries management should be implemented with the following features: • adopting participatory approaches at all levels of the planning and implementation steps • ensuring that all key components of the fishery system are considered (including those related to the ecological, social, economic and governance dimensions) and also take account of external drivers such as climate change
  • 39. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 21 • encouraging the use of the best available knowledge – both scientific and tradi- tional – in decision-making • promoting the adoption of adaptive management systems • building on existing institutions and practices. FAO promotes EAF as the most recent stage in a process of fisheries management which includes the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries and guidelines for EAF’s implementation developed in 2003. EAF is recognized as an important guiding principle in FAO’s Guidelines for Small-Scale Fisheries (FAO, 2012b). To date, the most extensive applications of the EAF have been in developed countries such as Norway, Australia and the EU. Although the concept of the EAF may seem relatively straightforward, its implementation may require the involvement of a large number of stakeholder groups, particularly if the implementation is across sectors. This implies a need to find improved ways of defining and sharing responsibilities. The importance of stakeholder participation in EAF has im- plications for the type of governance arrangements required to implement that approach (FAO, 2008). As regards existing fisheries management procedures, FAO recommends supporting current management systems, enabling them to evolve and adapt in order to become EAF compliant. In many ways, the ecosystem approach is designed to address the complexity of fisheries management, es- pecially with respect to small-scale fisheries (Mahon et al., 2008). In order to understand this complexity, Hall and Mainprize (2004) suggest the need for ecosystem performance measures and reference points for a diversity of metrics to provide an overall picture of the ecosystem. Integrated coastal management (ICM), which aims to bring together a wide diversity of sectors, interests and groups in a large area, is one management approach that comple- ments the wider approach of EAF. Likewise, marine protected areas (MPAs) can play an important role in EAF. The concept of ecosystem-based approaches is now being extended to address a much wider set of issues where fisheries man- agement concerns are embedded in the local economic, social and environmental situations and designed not only to improve existing resource use but to address future issues such as climate change. Conservation International (2011) describes its approach as ecosystem-based adaptation (EbA), “which capitalizes on the ability of natural systems to BOX 6: Ecosystem-based adaptation (EbA) in the Philippines In the Philippines, Conservation International (CI) is targeting the Verde Island Passage marine corridor, specifically its coastal ecosystem where 830,000 people live and depend on its marine resources for livelihoods including fishing, aquaculture and tourism. With increasing population, pressures such as overfishing, clearing of mangroves for aquaculture, development and logging will result in erosion and degradation of the natural coast. The vulnerability assessment for this region, completed in 2009, resulted in a series of recommendations. Based on this, CI is working with partners to implement two initiatives: to enhance coastal protection and strengthen fisheries resilience. Key actions include mangrove reforestation, training local communities and government in EbA coastal management techniques, application of best fishing practices and technologies, and income diversification strategies. Source: Conservation International, 2011
  • 40. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 22 assist in human adaptation to climate change.” CI defines EbA as “the use of biodiver- sity and ecosystem services as part of an overall adaptation strategy to help people to adapt to the adverse effects of climate change” (see Box 6). The interpretation of ecosystem approaches is also becoming increasingly sophisticat- ed – with more attention given to the interlinkages among different ecosystems, with more recognition of marine and coastal management in terms of “from the deep-sea to the ridgeline”, and with more recognition of the ways ecosystems interact with each other (Silvestri and Kershaw, eds., 2010). The added complexities of these “expanded” ecosystem approaches clearly has important implications for the decision-making processes, policies and institutional structures required to support them. 4.7 Co-management Co-management systems are becoming popular in many parts of the world and are demonstrating considerable levels of success (see Box 7). The greater involvement of fishers in the management decisions of fisheries not only builds on traditional systems of resource management in many parts of the world, it reflects both an increased awareness of the need to empower and engage fishers in the management process, and a recognition that it is potentially less expensive than trying to manage from the center (Alpízar, 2006). Berkes (2008) discussed the oppor- tunities and challenges of using indigenous and community conserved areas (ICCAs) for conservation practice, noting that they have a role to play in ensuring that conven- tional conservation approaches become more inclusive and pluralistic. In its simplest form, co-management can be described as fisheries management where roles and responsibilities are shared between the government and the users (Pomeroy, 1994; Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen, 1996). Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen (1996) dif- ferentiated this from community-based resource management (CBRM) because with co-management, government is also involved in the decision-making process concerning the management of the fishery. Abdullah et al. (1998, 106) found that “co-management is a middle course between pure state property and pure communal property regimes,” while Guttiérrez et al. (2011) referred to co- management as community-based co-man- agement where fishers and managers work together to improve the regulatory process. In many respects, co-management and com- munity-based management are separated by the degree of government involvement and community centricity (Alpízar, 2006). However, in the wider context of Exclusive Economic Zones (EEZ), markets, infrastruc- BOX 7: Co-management in inland water bodies in Bangladesh During a ten-year period, the Bangladesh Department of Fisheries, in partnership with the WorldFish Center and 11 NGOs, established community control over 116 water bodies. Over 130 poverty-based community-based organizations (CBOs) were involved in the management of these water bodies. In return for the right to operate these fisheries, the CBOs had to embrace the principles of sustainable fisheries management. Source: Dickson, www.worldfishcenter.org
  • 41. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 23 ture, safety and rescue, and the associated policy and legislative environment in which fisheries exists, it is difficult to conceive of any fishery which is not co-managed. Abdullah et al (1998, 106) noted that “[s]trictly speaking, pure communal property systems and community-based coastal resource management (CBCRM) are always embedded in state property systems and derive their strength from them.” Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen (1996) provide a useful classification within the broader scope of co-management as follows:3 • INSTRUCTIVE: where there is only minimal exchange of information between gov- ernment and users (e.g. co-management arrangements in inland fisheries in Ban- gladesh) • CONSULTATIVE: where mechanisms exist for government to consult with users but all decisions are made by the government (e.g. the fisheries committees es- tablished on Lake Malombe in Malawi and the bay management council in San Miguel Bay in the Philippines) • COOPERATIVE: where government and users cooperate as equal partners in deci- sion-making (e.g. customary rights areas in Fiji) • ADVISORY: where users advise government of decisions to be taken and govern- ment endorses these decisions • INFORMATIVE: where government has delegated authority to make decisions to user groups who are responsible for informing government of these decisions (e.g. the mechanized seine fishery in Inhassoro, Mozambique). While co-management covers a broad spectrum of relationships between government and users, others such as environmental advocacy groups and scientists may also feel they have a role to play in the process. The level of participation by non-state actors can often reflect the cultural or political preferences of the country concerned (Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen, 1996). Co-management, in addition to being regarded as a management approach on its own, is also key to other approaches, such as integrated area management, ecosystem- based management, protected area management and adaptive management (Evans et al., 2011a). The developing focus on co-management in fisheries is, in part, a response to the failure of other, more top-down forms of management. But, as Wamukota et al. (2012) noted, there has also been considerable debate about whether co-management has provided the expected benefits. There seems to be widespread agreement that co- management has a growing role to play in fisheries management globally, especially in small-scale tropical coastal fisheries. However, the evidence to support this still remains elusive, largely because of the complexity of the processes involved and the long-time frames often required to see clearly distinguishable impacts. Evans et al. (2011a, 1938), carried out a meta-analysis of 29 case studies in 90 sites, noting that “overall fisheries co-management delivers benefits to end-users through improve- ments in key process and outcome indicators. However, the dataset as a whole is con- stituted primarily of data from the Philippines. When we exclude this body of work, few generalizations can be made about the impact of fisheries co-management.” 3 The examples given were from a sample of 22 case studies on fisheries co-management.
  • 43. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 25 5 5. Impacts The success of different fisheries management systems can be measured in terms of their impact. This section discusses impacts, howtheymightbemeasuredandwhathasbeenachievedthrough fisheries management. Impact has two sides. One concerns the achievement of the objectives established in the management regime, the second defines the actual, objectively measurable impacts of the management regime on the resource, environment and people’s lives, i.e. the intended versus the actual. The impacts identified in the literature are often selective and may be biased towards social, ecological or economic perspectives (Bennett, 2005b) or even biased to demonstrate effectiveness selectively (Wamukota et al., 2012). Even when one of these biases is adopted, it may have bias within it, e.g. the type of sociological indicators selected may be those of the researcher rather than those of the people who are impacted. This needs to be kept in mind when assessing impact. In the Philippines, for instance, CBCRM programs are effective in engaging BOX 8: Assessing community perceptions of impact in Cambodia In Cambodia, the decision to introduce community-based fisheries management was a political one. The government had its perceptions of what it wanted to achieve in terms of improving people’s livelihoods but it also wanted to see what perceptions the communities had. It adopted a process of participatory impact assessment to evaluate policy effectiveness. Different stakeholders were asked to identify the impact on their livelihoods and to score them. Initially, the policy reforms generated improvements in poverty reduction, reduced fishing costs, improved income and improved food security, but these started to decline over time as they encouraged more people to join the fishery. They also created opportunities for small-scale processors and for small-scale farmers who were better able to access flooded land. Source: CFDO and IMM, 2004
  • 44. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 26 local communities but resource users are skeptical about the impact on their liveli- hoods (Maliao et al., 2009). Evans et al. (2011a) also noted that different studies tend to measure different indicators and include biases towards favorable places, or they focus on successful projects or projects that are currently being supported, which is likely to produce more favorable results. There can often be confusion around impact because of who decides the criteria used to assess it. Researchers or managers views of what should, could or has occurred may be very different from those of the community, and different stakeholder groups in the community may also have quite different perceptions from each other. Par- ticipatory approaches to policy reform impact assessment can often reveal interesting aspects of impact (see Box 8). According to Hanna (1996), there are three main means of assessing the effectiveness of co-management: • SUSTAINABILITY: in the form of stewardship (the maintenance of productivity and ecological characteristics) and resilience (the ability to withstand changes and shocks) • EFFICIENCY: the cost effectiveness of the arrangement (transaction costs or net returns) • EQUITY: this is divided into representation (of users), process clarity (transpar- ency and accountability), homogenous expectations (similarity of user expecta- tions) and distributive effects (equitable distribution of benefit flows). Wamukota et al. (2012) complemented this by indicating that co-management success can be measured through social dimensions, the condition of the resources and aspects of wider ecology. In regard to community-based fisheries management (CBFM), Kuemlangan (2004) noted the importance of balancing the livelihoods of fisheries with improving fish resource conservation or management. Weeratunge et al. (2013) pointed out that human wellbeing can be measured in a number of different ways but, in relation to fisheries, this is not a well-developed area of research. They also noted that fishers’ perceptions of wellbeing changes over time, which needs to be accommodated in any wellbeing analysis. Assessing the delivery of impact is often confused by a lack of clarity around the aims of the intervention. Many programs have confused policy objectives that interact, are internally inconsistent (Bellamy et al., 2001), are unrealistic or are incapable of objective measurement. Few seem to recognize trade-offs or a need to prioritize. In part, the ability to measure impact is time dependent, with some impacts taking many years to become apparent. In other situations, the theory of change itself may be changed over time to reflect changing political aims, and the focus of implementation may shift while the impacts being evaluated may remain unchanged (Bellamy et al., 2001). Co-management impacts seem to have been studied more than most. Sen and Nielsen (1996) noted that in most of the co-management cases they studied, the rationale for introducing co-management was that the fishery was reaching a point of over- exploitation or was already over-exploited, making it a form of crisis management.
  • 45. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 27 Although it was mostly not possible to assess the outcomes in terms of sustainability, equity and efficiency, in most cases representation was increased and process clarity was improved. Guttiérrez et al. (2011) noted that the advantages of co-management include an enhanced sense of ownership which encourages responsible fishing, greater sensitivity to local socio-economic and ecological restraints, improved man- agement through use of local knowledge, collective ownership by users in decision- making, increased compliance with regulations through peer pressure, and better monitoring, control and surveillance by fishers. However, what is rather disappointing is the general lack of strong evidence about the impact of fisheries on people’s livelihoods and sense of inclusion. Evans et al. (2011a) noted the scarcity of impact assessment data on fisheries co-management in developing countries. Hilborn (2007a, 272) also found that there has been “very little systematic attempt to evaluate the success and failures of individual fisheries.” Roe et al (2009, x) found that a “major deficiency of formal CBNRM projects is the absence or paucity of quantitative and/or qualitative data on the social, economic and environmental impacts,” and Hilborn (2007) also noted that there are no systematic evaluations of the ecological impact of fisheries. In reviewing the evidence for the success of fisheries management, Sutinen (2010, 97) concluded that: “Although there are several bright spots for some marine fishery resources (marginal improvements in stock status, growing use of rights-based man- agement, capacity reduction programs, to name a few), the evidence overall leads me to conclude that our marine resource management institutions have failed to conserve resources and improve the economic health of coastal communities.” Although there are few examples of really successful management in developing country coastal fisheries, much still can be learned from the existing operations of fisheries management that may inform a better way of doing things. These critical success factors are outlined in the next section.
  • 47. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 29 6 6. Critical factors that influence success This section of the report presents evidence from the literature, cross-referenced with key informants, as to factors that have been key in making fisheries management work. In spite of the paucity of evidence on the impact of fisheries management systems and approaches, there is some evidence about which factors influence success in particu- lar fisheries in particular locations at a particular time. This section starts with a brief introduction of some of the efforts undertaken by specialists in the fields of fisheries and natural resources management to encapsulate frameworks of success factors. It then looks at these factors in more detail under three headings: i) factors affecting policy and planning, ii) factors affecting technical imple- mentation and iii) factors affecting community engagement. The critical factors are those which fisheries experts and practitioners perceive to have influenced the extent to which a fisheries management approach has had direct influence over planned or perceived impact. As our concern here is to achieve an understanding of the balance between social and ecological impacts, the critical success factors are reviewed in terms of both social and ecological impacts. This analysis does not give a concrete solution to management problems but indicates the trends in thinking and practice towards more successful ways of implement- ing management. As Hilborn (2007, 300) noted, “there is no single prescription for moving currently unsustainable fisheries towards sustainability. The appropriate method will depend greatly on local circumstances.” Arthur (2005, 4) concluded in an 11-year study of fisheries management, funded by the UK government’s Depart- ment for International Development (DFID), “[w]hile a diversity of circumstances and needs suggests there is no single or ‘optimum’ co-management arrangement for any region, nation or local situation there are some features common to all and common lessons that can be drawn from the study of different arrangements.”
  • 48. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 30 In spite of these concerns for the specificity of success, some researchers have developed design principles or generalized criteria. Some are outlined below with the components discussed in more detail in later sections. 6.1 Some frameworks of success factors Ostrom (2009b) identified the following design principles for the management of com- mon-pool resources management that were sustained over a long period of time and absent from fsystems: • USER BOUNDARIES: clear and locally understood boundaries between legitimate users and nonusers are present • RESOURCE BOUNDARIES: clear boundaries that separate a specific common-pool resource from a larger socio-ecological system are present • CONGRUENCE WITH LOCAL CONDITIONS: appropriation and provision rules are congruent with local social and environmental conditions • APPROPRIATION AND PROVISION: appropriation rules are congruent with provision rules: the distribution of costs is proportional to the distribution of benefits • COLLECTIVE-CHOICE ARRANGEMENTS: most individuals affected by a resource regime are authorized to participate in making and modifying its rules • MONITORING USERS: individuals who are accountable to or are the users monitor the appropriation and provision levels of the users • MONITORING THE RESOURCE: individuals who are accountable to or are the users monitor the condition of the resource • GRADUATED SANCTIONS: sanctions for rule violations start very low but become stronger if a user repeatedly violates a rule • CONFLICT-RESOLUTION MECHANISMS: rapid, low-cost, local arenas exist for resolving conflicts among users or with officials • MINIMAL RECOGNITION OF RIGHTS: the rights of local users to make their own rules are recognized by the government • NESTED ENTERPRISES: when a common-pool resource is closely connected to a larger social-ecological system, governance activities are organized in multiple nested layers. BOX 9: Design principes for the Peruvian anchovy fishery A study of the Peruvian anchovy fisheries assessed the applicability of Ostrom’s eight “design principles” of long-lasting common pool resources management regimes. Ostrom (1990) confirmed these could serve as a valuable tool for analysis and understanding of large- scale common pool resource systems: 1. early defined boundaries defining who has rights to withdraw resources and the boundaries of the common resource 2. congruence between appropriation (restricting time, place, technology, etc.) and provision rules (requiring labor, material, and money) and local conditions 3. collective-choice arrangements 4. monitoring of conditions and behavior 5. graduated sanctions depending on the seriousness of an offense 6. conflict-resolution mechanisms 7. minimal recognition by government authorities of rights of appropriators to organize 8. nested enterprises with monitoring, enforcement and governance activities organized in multiple levels for CPRs that are part of larger systems. Source: Arias Schreiber and Halliday, 2013
  • 49. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 31 Refined versions of these have been tested in the field and demonstrated their value, as shown in Box 9. Similar sorts of criteria that support positive management experiences have been identified by other researchers. The following highlights the findings of Leal (2010), Berkes et al. (2001), Francis and Bryceson (2001) and Bennett (2005b). Community management of quotas Leal (2010) suggested that, to be effective, the communities require: • legally backed quota rights • sufficient common interest to make negotiations feasible • clear awareness among fishers that collective management will generate benefits for both fishers and non-fishers • an acceptable system for disposal of rights should the collective arrangement close • an effective system for deterring violations with sanctions • clear signals that such arrangements will not be overturned by higher levels of government. Fisheries management in San Salvador Berkes et al. (2001) determined that success was due to a number of factors including: • the resource stakeholders’ participation and sense of ownership in project planning and implementation • clarity of objectives • supportive leadership • the partnership between fishers and government • specification and legitimacy of user rights enforcement • capability building • tangible benefits such as redefined resource access, a shift to non-destructive fishing methods, improved enforcement, and observable biological, economic and social changes. Sustainable use of coastal and marine resources in Tanzania Francis and Bryceson (2001, 76) identified general lessons learned and key factors, including: • dialogue and linkage between traditional and scientific knowledge systems • mechanisms for interaction between scientists, managers and decision-makers • continued human and technical capacity building of research institutions • essentiality of addressing land and sea tenure and common property rights • genuine involvement and empowerment of local communities and civil society including community-based organizations (CBOs), and local non-governmental organizations (NGOs) • credible and equitable arrangements for benefit-sharing with communities • open availability of information for overall transparency and accountability • integration of socio-economic opportunities into conservation programs • recognition of and respect for local and traditional institutions • openness in collaboration between traditional and government institutions • strengthening of relevant institutions providing entry to decision-making • management agreements between institutions for cross-sectoral coordination
  • 50. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 32 • long-term and broad-based visions in policy thinking • democratic process of public involvement in policy-making and implementation. Measures which achieved their objectives Bennett (2005b) collated a number of drivers from a 1997 Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) study on measures which achieved their fisheries objectives. These were found to be: • use rights • co-management • compliance and enforcement • biology and luck • policy frameworks • pro-active industry • stakeholder participation • multi-sectoral approaches. Bennett noted that few if any of these factors are able to contribute to success on their own but need to be applied in association with others. As can be seen from these examples, the factors which support positive manage- ment experiences are likely to be numerous, and operating over several scales. For example, Wamukota et al. (2012) found that “[t]he full list of contextual conditions thought to influence the success of common-pool resource management is large (>30).” But having systematically reviewed 38 papers of 49 co-management projects related to reefs, they concluded that few studies presented results that covered the full range of social-ecological success criteria and that reporting selectivity was likely to have been high. Success factors appear to operate at different levels and here we have reviewed them at three levels: • factors affecting policy and planning • factors affecting technical implementation • factors affecting community engagement. However, we have noted that while this helps split the number of factors into opera- tional levels, some operate at multiple levels – and the linkages between these levels are as important as the levels themselves. 6.2 Factors affecting policy and planning Factors affecting policy and planning are broadly those that act globally, regionally and nationally. This includes relating fisheries management to the complexity of the management situation and conflicting aims, recognizing the importance of context, operating at different scales and levels, ensuring institutional coherence, ensuring ecosystem viability and adapting to external change. Embracing complexity and integration Fisheries management is, as mentioned above, a complex process. Efforts to simplify that process tend to result in simplistic solutions. Increasingly, there is a focus on embracing complexity and integrating management across sectors.
  • 51. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 33 Coastal areas are, by their nature, complex. They support a diversity of species, eco- systems and stakeholders in a dynamic environment where the land-water interface generates constant change. The very nature of social and ecological approaches to natural resources management means dealing with the complexity of bringing together factors that relate to the environment, society, the economy, politics and culture. This complexity can often mean that problems have no right or wrong answer (see Box 10). But as Link (2010) noted, the potential for fisheries management to become so complex that it becomes unmanageable should be avoided by getting the balance right. In the past, fisheries management tended to represent the issues involved in coastal fisheries management in a simplified form. The use of single species models from temperate waters, for example, has been trans- ferred to multi-species fisheries operating in ecologically diverse ecosystems. While this has generated much knowledge of the stocks, it also has many limitations (Link, 2010). Models based on fisheries with fewer larger vessels landing into fewer ports with good infrastructure and monitoring facilities do not always transfer well to fisheries with many small craft landing into dispersed sites with limited monitoring. A key factor of success is bringing these different elements together in ways that integrate them as a working whole. Acknowledging and dealing with the holistic nature of the coast is an important starting point for understanding how to bring other factors into a management approach. As Link (2010, 3335 of Kindle edition) noted, “without a place, process, or some such mechanism to sort out the social, economic, biological, ecological, and cultural tradeoffs, we will remain mired in the same difficul- ties we have faced for centuries.” Pomeroy (1994) noted that the delay in developing community-based management in fisheries, compared with other natural resource systems is due, in part, to the com- plexity of coastal and marine resource systems, the social and cultural structure of fishing communities, and the independent nature of fishers. Addressing the issue of scale in commons management, Berkes (2006) noted that it may be more useful to think in terms of managing complexity rather than simply trying to “scale up”. This involves thinking of management of the commons as the manage- ment of complex systems, and recognizing that communities are themselves complex systems embedded within a larger complex system of politics and economics. Ostrom (2009a, 421) identified a number of variables that need to be considered in analyzing socio-ecological systems. Shown in Box 11, these demonstrate how complex it can be to understand and to monitor such systems. Understanding the processes that lead to improvements in, or deterioration of, natural resources is limited because scientific disciplines use different concepts BOX 10: Wicked problems of fisheries management There is increasing study of the “wicked” nature of some of the problems that face fisheries and coastal governance. “Wicked” problems are those that are difficult to define and delineate from bigger problems and tend not to be resolved easily. Essentially they have no right or wrong answer that can be scientifically determined. This can place limits to how rational and effective fisheries and coastal governance can possibly be. Source: Jentoft and Chuenpagdee, 2009
  • 52. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 34 and languages to describe and explain complex social-ecological systems (Ostrom, 2009a). The current debate on fisheries and marine biodiversity has polarized to an extent around three key areas: i) economic rationalization, ii) marine conservation and iii) distributional/equity issues. Each of these areas has emerged from specific disciplines, each of which operates within a specific discourse, i.e. a shared way of ap- prehending the world which constructs meaning and relationships, creates and uses its own language, validates knowledge in its own way, helps to define common sense and legitimate knowledge, and builds assumptions, judgments and contentions that provide the basis for analysis and debate (Dryzek, 2005). Such discourses tend to separate, confuse and isolate parts of the debate from other parts, which then tend towards reductionism in the solutions they provide and to heightened disagreement between different discourses. Bromley (2009) noted that even within fisheries economics, confused concepts result in incoherent models of fisheries management. Compartmentalization of the fisheries/biodiversity debate around the three key areas mentioned above has often been characterized by oversimplified solutions to fisheries problems such as the use of individual transferrable quotas, marine protected areas and community-based management (Degnbol et al., 2006). This has been compound- ed by the evolution of these discourses away from each other (Belsky, 2000). Ostrom (2009a) noted that, without a common framework to organize findings, isolated knowledge does not cumulate. Armitage et al. (2012) found that there are thresholds where existing systems are no longer valid, e.g. where coastal fisheries have reached a level of resource decline that produces profound effects on the system as a whole. This suggests that systems, whatever form they take, should be sufficiently flexible and adaptable to embrace change and respond to it. One approach to this calls for utilizing multi-level arrange- ments where different levels of management or governance have different roles and responsibilities, and are linked through coordinating institutions (Ostrom, 2009b). The devolution of roles and responsibilities may be the necessary course of action, in part to address capacity issues within government, but such transfers also have the effect of redistributing power, which may be difficult for government to deal with (Mahon et al., 2008). The multi-species nature of fisheries, especially in high biodiversity areas such as coral reefs, can make management particularly difficult. The potential number of in- teractions of different species and ecosystems in any given fishery can be extremely high, which manifests itself in many different fisheries (Link, 2010). For instance, the multispecies nature of the fishery along India’s Andhra Pradesh coast constrains man- agement measures (Salagrama, 2005). Studies of coastal fisheries and other natural resource systems suggest that success depends upon matching rules to the local resource context and attributes (Ostrom, 2009a). In research on coastal resource management (CRM) in the Philippines, Fabinyi et al. (2010) demonstrated that various aspects of social complexity also have significant implications for the outcomes. By highlighting social complexity, they demonstrat- ed how the planning, implementation and impacts of CRM have different effects for
  • 53. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 35 BOX 11: Examples of variables in a framework for analysing social-ecological systems Social, economic and political settingss (S) S1 Economic development,. S2 Demogaphic trends. S3 Political stability. S4 Government resource polices. S5 Market incentives. S6 Media organization. Resource systems (RS) RS1 Sector (e.g., water, forests, pasture, fish) RS2 Clarity of system boundaries RS3 Size of resource system* RS4 Human-constructed facilities RS5 Productivity of system* RS6 Equilibrium properties RS7 Predictabaility of system dynamics* RS8 Storage characteristics RS9 Location Resource units (RU) RU1 Resource unit mobility* RU2 Growth or replacement rate RU3 Interaction among resource units RU4 Economic value RU5 Number of units RU6 Distincitve markings RU7 Spatial and temporal distribution I1 Harvesting levels of diverse users I2 Information sharing among users I3 Deliberation processes I4 Conflicts among users I5 Investment activites I6 Lobbying activites I7 Self-organizing activities I8 Netowrking activities Governance systems G51 Government organizations GS2 Nongovernment organizations GS3 Network structure GS4 Property-rights systmes GS5 Operational rules* GS6 Collective-choice rules* GS7 Constitutional rules GS8 Monitoring and sanctioning processes Users (U) U1 Number of users* U2 Socioeconomic attributes of users U3 History of use U4 Location U5 Leadership/entrepreneurship* U6 Norms/social capital* U7 Knowledge of SES/mental models* U8 Importance of resource * U9 Technology uses 01 Social performance measures (e.g., efficiency, equity, accountability, sustainability) 02 Ecological performance measures (e.g., overharvested, resilience, bio-diversity, sustainability) 03 Externalities to other SES Source: Ostrom, 2009a Interactions (1) outcomes (O) *Subset of variables found to be associated with self-organization. Related ecosystems (ECO) ECO1 Climate patterms. ECO2 Pollution patterns. ECO3 Flows into and out of focal SES.
  • 54. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 36 different groups of people. The complexity of the socio-cultural systems that make up the way people and ecosystems interact means moving away from simplistic gen- eralizations about the coast and embracing complexity (Mahon et al, 2008; Ostrom, 2009a; Campbell and Townsley, 2013). Understanding and using behavior patterns that emerge from complexity might suggest that management measures focus more on developing participation, building trust, gaining commitment to change, internaliz- ing the political economy, enhancing communication and fostering common interdis- ciplinary discourses rather than focusing on specific technical measures (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). There is also a growing realization that complex situations, such as those that charac- terize coastal fisheries, will often generate forms of feedback, learning processes and non-linear relationships that are not always predictable. These are becoming more difficult to predict due to external factors that affect the fishery – such as climate change, natural hazards, global fuel and food prices – becoming more common and in- fluencing fisheries and coastal livelihoods (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). However, attempts to break down these complex relationships at sectoral and sub-sectoral levels fail to recognize the interconnectedness of the social, economic and ecological systems in which fisheries operate (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). Ferrol-Schulte et al. (2013) called for a more holistic approach to understanding coastal livelihoods in order to manage coastal and marine social-ecological systems more effectively. There is increasing realization that fisheries are, in fact, complex social-ecological systems that are capable of adaptation as management systems alter conditions (McConney and Charles, 2008). Mahon et al. (2008, 110) proposed “an approach that emphasizes enabling self organization and adaptive capacity through empower- ment, learning, and response systems and promoting positive, equitable, transparent interaction among stakeholders” as a foundation for governing fishery systems. In reviewing a number of papers concerned with this complexity, Armitage et al. (2009, 95) determined that “[e]fforts to resolve multi-scale environment-society dilemmas require innovative governance approaches.” Some of these innovative approaches are starting to emerge, but there is still much to be done in this area. In the main, there has been a tendency to implement fisheries management processes in isolation from wider coastal activities and from the planning and management actions in other sectors (Copes and Charles, 2004). In the future, fisheries management will have to take into account a much wider set of social and economic variables and address inter-generational issues (Copes and Charles, 2004). This has started to emerge as a way forward in some areas. In the Philippines, there has been some success in integrating fisheries into a wider process of integrated coastal management. In fact, integrated coastal management (ICM) is now replacing the narrow focus of fisheries management and narrowly based habitat management and moving more towards ecosystem-based management which emphasizes the need for integration and collaboration (White et al., 2006). The potential of ICM to address coastal complexity through breaking down institutional barriers is gaining support and is starting to show positive effects (Christie and White, 2006). But the complexity of such approaches requires that they be developed over time through correspond- ingly complex systems of consultation and institution building.
  • 55. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 37 Addressing conflicting aims Fisheries management tries to address social, economic, environmental and political aims, but these often conflict with each other (Cochrane, 2002). Deciding how to trade-off between different aims is not an objective process but is ultimately a political one of negotiation. This section looks at these conflicting aims and discusses the im- portance of responding to them. A fishery is a complex system that links individual human endeavor, enterprise, risk, culture, the physical world, technology, the natural world, the political economy, and wider society’s beliefs, aspirations and values. Different people’s perceptions of reality and their ideals can influence the aims that are chosen for different interventions. For example, wilderness science uses two points on a spectrum when approaching man- agement: i) the pristine wilderness devoid of humans, and ii) humanized landscapes and manipulated ecosystems (Belsky, 2000). Different fisheries ecosystems lie within this spectrum but different aims place different fisheries at different points along it. Even within a given fishery, the aims of different people engaged in the sector are often confusing. These aims may be numerous, often conflicting or requiring trade- offs, and quite often are being under-achieved. In some situations, the conflicts are clearly defined as noted by Salagama (2005), who identified the need to balance man- agement efforts with providing livelihoods and foreign exchange earnings as one of the constraints to effective management in Andhra Pradesh, India. In other cases, the conflicts are more complex, as noted by Sugiyama et al. (2004, 49) who determined “[a] key factor to turn around the current trends (in fisheries in Asia and the Pacific) would be for States to resolve the competing policy imperatives of: • optimal and sustainable use of fish resources and their supporting ecosystems; • economic objectives, especially in relation to either small- or large-scale fisheries; • social objectives, including maximizing employment and improving livelihoods; • objectives related to equity, including access for only small-scale fisheries; and • any other objectives (for example trade liberalization, market access etc.) which may have impacts on this sub-sector.” At any one time, the stated aims of fisheries management may be maximization of production, conservation of resources and ecosystems, maximization of economic benefits to the nation, food and nutrition security, foreign exchange generation, em- ployment, poverty reduction, sustainable resource use or maximization of ecosystem service provision. There may also be many unstated aims, such as rent seeking by politicians or for powerful groups that might otherwise threaten political stability, or appeasement of some parts of the electorate, or trade-offs with other non-fisheries aims in other sectors. Historically the main aim of fisheries was to increase production to satisfy growing demand from an expanding population. Many saw the sea as full of fish, a resource that could never be depleted (Roberts, 2007; Link, 2010). But technology and fishing effort have proved that to be incorrect, and many fisheries are now over-exploited, biodiversity has changed and ecosystems are damaged. The desire to harvest fish must now be balanced by a need to do so sustainably. There is also recognition that fisheries can play a significant role in the livelihoods of people, especially the poor, by
  • 56. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 38 providing food, nutrition, employment and income. As such, the issue of equity in the benefits that flow from fisheries is also important. In addition to fisheries management having conflicting aims, there also seems to be a significant divide around how those aims might be achieved. Hilborn (2007b) noted that ecologists strongly support marine protected areas (MPAs) as a central part of the solution whereas fisheries specialists support stopping the “race to fish” through a change of incentives to encourage sustainability and stock building. These two ap- proaches need not be seen as two distinct ways of looking at the world. Claudet (2011) noted, for instance, that MPAs can have multiple objectives ranging from sustainable use and management of marine resources to socio-economic development. Likewise, Pomeroy (2003) recognized how co-management approaches can work well with MPAs. In trying to make sense of the complexities of fisheries management and to break them down into their component parts, Hilborn (2007c) cast light on the motives and intended outcomes of different groups of stakeholders involved in the management process. He concluded that there are broadly four categories of fisheries objectives: biological, economic, social and political, each with specific concerns: • BIOLOGICAL OBJECTIVES: concerned with maximizing production which translates in the traditional maximum sustainable yield (MSY) • ECONOMIC OBJECTIVES: concerned with resource rent maximization through ef- ficiency i.e. maximum economic yield (MEY) • SOCIAL OBJECTIVES: concerned with distributional issues of employment, income, maintenance of communities and food security – or maximum job yield (MJY) • POLITICAL OBJECTIVES: concerned primarily with the avoidance of conflict among the electorate and opposition from resource-users regarding management measures – or what he refers to as “minimum sustainable whinge” (MSW).4 This gives some idea of the complexity of objectives and even of the different ways that different groups have of looking at the fishery. It also gives some indication as to why there is so little agreement on targets for the achievement of management objec- tives – if the different groups are talking at cross-purposes about radically different priorities, they are unlikely to ever achieve a consensus on what is needed. Hilborn (2007c) suggested that the current fisheries crisis can be thought of largely as a conflict between these different objectives, and linked these possible policy objectives to different stakeholder groups in a way that clearly differentiates the groups from each other: • large-scale fishers may want a greater focus on economic optimization or maximum production (depending on the management regime in place) • small-scale fishers may prioritize stable, reliable yields • fisheries managers operate within a highly politicized context • politicians often react to policy by providing appeasement measures, such as subsidies, to reduce conflict • government scientists tend to err on the side of caution and avoid deciding where they stand in favor of collecting more data • environmental NGOs tend to focus on ecosystem and species health and the negative impacts of fishing, concerns which tend to conflict directly with those of production maximization and social inclusiveness. 4 MSW is a term first used by Pope, J.G. in 1983.
  • 57. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 39 In spite of the diversity of possible aims for fisheries management, Hilborn (2007b) found a seemingly broad agreement among the fisheries management community, the conservation world and even the resource users themselves that the future of fisheries lies with much less fishing, lower exploitation rates, larger fish stocks, reduced by-catch, increased concerns for ecosystems, less destructive fishing methods, more spatial management of fisheries and more areas protected from fishing. In reviews of schools of thought around fisheries management, he identified some areas of agreement, pointing out a broad consensus of the need to move towards lower ex- ploitation rates and to remove subsidies that increase fishing effort. Key elements of the consensus included dedicated access, as well as: “quotas and allocation, fishing cooperatives that internally allocate, territorial fishing rights for communities, groups or individuals, and individual allocation of catch quotas” (Hilborn 2007b, 297). The debate around the implementation of MPAs, as one form of fisheries manage- ment measure, illustrates the increasing recognition of the importance of negotia- tion in setting management objectives. Christie and White (2007, 1053) noted that “[u]nclear goals and inattention to social dynamics are almost certain to result in conflict that derails MPA implementation.” Gaining the support of communities in the use of MPAs and other management measures is vital if fisheries and conservation aims are to be achieved. Integrated coastal management, if planned properly and with a sufficiently holistic perspective can provide a useful framework for bringing aims together. As Christie and White (2006, 191) noted, the ICM process “tries to break down the barriers erected by traditional sectoral management of natural resources as well as the divide that exists among local government, national agencies, community groups, and NGOs.” Diversity in the aims for fisheries management is a fact and needs to be acknowledged and reconciled if we are to move forwards successfully. Berkes et al. (2001) discussed in some detail how conflicts between objectives can be resolved but ultimately this requires agreement on a prioritization process. Recognizing the importance of context The level and form of complexity of fisheries and their management is not constant but varies between places. The importance of local context and how it affects fisheries management comes out clearly from many references. Recognizing the importance of the local context in fisheries management and adjusting management measures to accommodate that is very important. The specific context in which fisheries management operates will have considerable influence on what works and what does not. In the wider context of wilderness manage- ment, it has been argued that there are no “right solutions” to management problems and that these should be examined in the context of particular places, peoples, issues and ecosystems (Belsky, 2000). Hilborn (2007b) acknowledged that different situations call for different solutions. The local biological, ecological, political economy and socio- economic aspects of a fishery often determine the success of management initiatives. What works in developed countries will not necessarily work in developing countries. Guttiérrez et al. (2011) noted that countries with high and very high human devel- opment indices (HDIs) were more successful at fisheries management than those
  • 58. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 40 with low to medium HDIs. Andrade and Rhodes (2012) found that although there is a positive correlation between gross domestic product (GDP) at purchasing power parity (PPP) per capita and compliance with regulations, this may well be due to other factors such as political will, corruption and social inequality. However they also found that population density was negatively correlated with compliance. Hilborn (2007b, 301) noted that “[i]n countries without strong central management structures, decentralization and locally controlled dedicated access appears to be the best way to make the transition to biological and economic sustainability.” In relation to community-based fisheries management (CBFM), Kuemlangan (2004) noted that above all, “the CBFM initiative or programme should be tailored in design and delivery to the individual country circumstances.” Bell et al. (2006) determined that the success of stock enhancement of scallops in Japan could not be replicated in New Zealand, which may have been due to the existence or not of the other factors mentioned here. While in many parts of the world there is a move towards greater engagement of com- munities in resource management, this is not always the case. In Costa Rica, when Alpízar (2006) compared the current level of government involvement in marine pro- tection and fisheries management with that of the community, he concluded that, at that stage of development, the greater role should remain with government. Francis and Bryceson (2001) noted weaknesses in both government and traditional institu- tions in coastal management in Tanzania that needed support, while Baticados et al. (1998) found that even within the Philippines, fisheries cooperatives on the mainland had significant differences in their capacities compared with those on the islands. This pattern of dependence on specific circumstances also seems to affect specific management measures. On the subject of individual transferrable quotas (ITQs), Robinson (2010, 53) noted “the first best, ITQs, is barely politically feasible anywhere. Even in the best possible circumstances, in rich, well-functioning democracies where the stakes are high, ITQs are highly controversial … If ITQs are not politically feasible in Norway, what chance have they of being adopted in Ghana or Sierra Leone? Very little would be my guess.” Rudd et al. (2003, 66) reported that complexity of tropical coastal fisheries “makes economically efficient policy tools such as individual transferable quotas impossible to implement …” This is likely due to a number of factors, such as the quality of the institutions in place in terms of their governance arrangements and management capacity, the adherence to the rule of law, the political economy, the financial and staff resources available, the number of vessels and the number of operating sites. Operating at multiple scales Fisheries management cannot be addressed in isolation from other factors that affect the fishery. Fisheries are, by the fluid and interconnected nature of the sea, part of a bigger whole which creates the social and ecological context in which fisheries management must operate. Attempts to externalize these wider influences from the fisheries management equation have tended to lead to rather simplistic and often failed management approaches.
  • 59. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 41 These factors that influence fisheries also operate at multiple levels. In particular, fisheries fit inside a wider set of ecological processes that influence, and are influ- enced by, the fisheries. There are different scales and levels at which fisheries need to be considered (Jentoft and McCay, 1995; Raakjaer Nielsen and Vedsmand, 1995). In this case, “levels” refers to where decisions should be made and “scale” refers to the fisheries resource system and the management tasks to be undertaken (Sen and Raakjaer Nielsen, 1996). It is clear that when the ecological system is large, some decisions have to be made at the national or international levels, such as those that deal with transboundary issues or are designed to reflect wider national development policies. Likewise, the economic conditions that allow fisheries to function at the local level are also influenced by the wider national and regional economy (see Box 12). Under- standing the need to work at these different scales and to identify the appropriate level for particular roles is important to understand- ing what works in fisheries and how it works. Legislation is generally a national role, trade may be controlled by an international body and the development of specific site regula- tions may be much more local. In some cases, roles are shared – policy and planning may be jointly developed, and monitoring and evalua- tion may be participatory. The movements of water, pollution, fish and predators across large areas, between locations and across adjacent or connected ecosystems can affect ecosystem function. Likewise, water circulation patterns, climate change effects and industrial fisheries can all affect small-scale fisheries over large areas and time frames. Where fisheries cover large geographical areas and different fish stocks, there may be need for higher level management functions than in the case of the management of a small area of reef. Arthur (2005) noted the importance of getting management of fisheries at the right scale for the size of the fishery concerned. At the larger scales, there would appear to be greater room for generalizing the factors that create positive social, ecological and economic benefits. Berkes et al. (2000) start to address the generalizability issues in co-management at higher scales. However, the most appropriate scale to manage from an ecological perspective does not neces- sarily correspond to the most appropriate scale from social or economic perspectives (Roe et al., 2009). This is likely to be particularly true in coastal fisheries where the fluid and interconnected nature of the sea invites a much wider perspective, such as a large marine ecosystem, whereas communities of resource users may be more isolated and different from each other. The value of managing at multiple levels has become increasingly apparent. Armitage et al. (2012) noted that devolution of power to lower levels – closer to the level of resource users – works best when formal policy and regulatory support from the BOX 12: Linkages across scales of management In Cambodia, the community management of fisheries is embedded in a wider process that links fisheries, through the provincial levels, into national development objectives through a Strategic Planning Framework for Fisheries 2010- 2019. This Framework allows for decision-making to be devolved to different levels to incorporate local needs and aspirations while also ensuring coherence of objectives at national levels. Source: Fisheries Administration, 2010
  • 60. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 42 state are provided. However, such devolution can generate the risk of elite capture of decision-making processes. Wilson et al. (2006) also noted that complex scale issues are now resulting in combina- tions of institutions working at different scales to form cross-scale networks that can address greater complexity. While the more traditional view of fisheries management has been a more “command and control” approach, these have not tended to create the conservation outcomes that are desired because of the complexity and multi-scale reality of the management issues (Armitage et al., 2012). In response, multi-level gov- ernance arrangements involving state and non-state actors are emerging. Multi-levels approaches are often needed to confer economies of scale on knowledge generation, ensure coherence across policy areas, allocate rights fairly, and link national and local priorities. This is particularly so where the effects of management in a fishery will affect adjacent fisheries – either along the coast or further out to sea. Even in fisheries research, the value of shared functions is being recognized across the research cycle (Campbell and Salagrama, 2001), which has shown traditional ecological knowledge to be very useful, especially when combined with more formal knowledge. The interconnectedness of the marine environment suggests the need for taking a broader perspective that links fisheries to the wider ecology and human world. This reflects a similar change which is developing in terrestrial systems (Berkström et al., 2012), such as the “tropical seascape” approach in the marine sphere. This approach works with a mosaic of interlinked patches that provides a multitude of ecosystem services and represents a level of management intervention which is receiving increased interest. However, the knowledge of the inter-linkages and connectivity within such systems is limited (Berkström et al., 2012). In comparing a number of approaches to large areas for marine management (LAMM), Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010) addressed marine management at multiple scales from the larger scale of multiple nations down, in some cases, to the local scale with stated aims that covered both marine conservation and sustainable development. These approaches included Large Marine Ecosystems (LMEs), Seascapes, Marine Ecoregions, Regional Seas and Integrated Coastal Zone Management (ICM). Large Marine Ecosystems that cross national boundaries address marine ecosystems at this larger scale – especially in relation to fisheries. The term (LME) is now used to define marine management areas by agencies such as the Global Environment Facility (GEF), the International Union for the Conservation of Nature (IUCN) and the World Bank. The World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF) and The Nature Conservancy (TNC) use the term “Marine Ecoregions” and Conservation International (CI) is working with “Seascapes” (see Box 13) in the Coral Triangle Initiative (Indonesia, Malaysia, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Solomon Islands, Timor-Leste). The United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) has developed a “Regional Seas Approach” which includes action plans for protecting the environment and delivering sustainable de- velopment. Some form of wider ecosystem approach is an important component of many fisheries management programs, and integrated coastal management is used in a number of countries but particularly widely in the Philippines. Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, (2010, iv) determined that “Large Marine Ecosystems, Marine Ecoregions and to some extent Seascapes are all ecosystem-based in their
  • 61. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 43 geography and are reasonable starting units, around which to build a programme of marine conservation or restoration and sustainable use.” In addition, they suggested that for all of these approaches, context is very important. They (2010, iv) noted that all three approaches “have attained important results, yet we are concerned that the aim of effective governance across sectors and at all levels, from local to regional, is poorly articulated and inadequately addressed, especially in the case of the Large Marine Ecosystems.” They also noted that “most Regional Seas Programmes are well established and have an increasingly significant role in coastal and marine resource management and conservation in their respective regions.” In relation to ICM they wrote (2010, iv) that “we consider that the other approaches studied here have much to learn from the ICM process, as they strive to overcome some of the barriers to EBM in developing countries, such as: ineffective governance, sometimes under- mined by corruption; local stakeholders lacking rights over resources, power in decision-making and the means to develop alternative livelihoods; rapid social and BOX 13: The Conservation International (CI) seascape approach Seascapes are large, multiple-use marine areas, defined scientifically and strategically, in which government authorities, private organizations and other stakeholders cooperate to conserve the diversity and abundance of marine life, with the ultimate goal of promoting human well-being. In each seascape, CI is building coalitions with governments, corporations and civil society organizations to attain nine essential elements. 1. Enabling legal framework. Seascapes generate an enabling framework of laws, conventions, regulations and policies that facilitate marine conservation at local, national and regional scales. 2. Ecosystem-based management including MPAs. Seascapes advance large-scale management of marine ecosystems and species through the use of multidisciplinary scientific information to inform effective planning, implementation, monitoring and evaluation. 3. Adequate institution and capacity. Seascapes build adequate institutional frameworks and capacity, including personnel, infrastructure, and equipment, to make marine governance structures (governmental, commercial and civil) work effectively and efficiently. 4. Private sector engagement. Seascapes promote convergence between conservation and development by linking the viability and profitability of major economic activities with sustainable management of the ecosystem. 5. Social and political support. Seascapes increase the social and political viability of marine conservation as an integral part of sustainable development, and they build broad support at all scales, from stakeholders in local marine managed areas to national leaders. 6. Maintenance and restoration of critical habitats and ecosystems. Seascapes maintain or restore critical habitats and ecosystems so that ecological processes and ecosystem services are sustained. 7. Threatened species recovery. Seascapes reverse declining population trends for threatened marine species. 8. Human well-being benefits. Seascapes improve the social, economic, and cultural well-being of human communities dependent on marine and coastal resources and ecosystems. 9. Sustainable financing and market mechanisms. Seascapes strive to be financially sustainable with funding portfolios that are stable, diverse, and large enough to implement all priority marine conservation activities. Source: Conservation International http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/initiatives/seascapes/pages/seascapes.aspx
  • 62. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 44 political change preventing sustained commitment to EBM; scarcity of strong civil society organisations to champion and support EBM.” Since that review, some of the other approaches, such has the Conservation International Seascape (see Box 13) and The Nature Conservancy approaches have reportedly placed greater emphasis on governance issues and context-specific approaches. Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010, 22) also noted that given the different nature – and, in some aspects, complementary roles – of the five LAMM approaches, “it is not surprising that their application has in many cases overlapped. In some places the outcomes, funding and sustainability achieved may be fruits not of individual programs but of two or more complementary, interacting approaches. An additional question to ask, then, is whether the application of multiple approaches in the same area, or overlapping areas, is synergistic or merely inefficiency caused by institutions adhering to their own methodologies instead of building on what is already in place.” Integrated coastal management is seen by many as an effective, comprehensive and holistic way of bringing different sectors and levels together. The Philippines has probably had the most extensive ICM experience (White et al., 2006). ICM’s effective- ness is likely to be, in part, a result of its ability to incorporate other tools at the local level, e.g. MPAs. Christie and White (2006, 184) noted that “[t]o be effective on a wide scale MPAs should be embedded within larger planning frameworks such as inte- grated coastal management (ICM) or ecosystem-based management (EBM).” These wider frameworks are designed to balance economic development with resource man- agement processes in cross-sectoral ways. Ecosystem approaches to fisheries also place an emphasis on operating at different scales. Charles and Saunders (2006) noted that from the perspective of EAF, “it is important for fisheries management to take into account the impacts of fishing on the ecosystem, and conversely, the impacts of the ecosystem and of other human uses of that ecosystem, on fisheries.” The ecological aspects of fisheries need also be consid- ered in wider development approaches where multiple use economic development is occurring. It is important to understand that context and to adjust fisheries manage- ment accordingly. Clearly, there is a need for fisheries managers to look outside of their normal environ- ment and seek solutions and linkages with other sectors (Mahon et al., 2008). This need for integration of social, economic, environmental and political concerns and issues is starting to take on a new form as integrated ecosystem-based approaches, which have considerable potential to integrate sustainable resource-use management, conservation and development into a single paradigm. The value of addressing this at higher levels of spatial planning is becoming more generally recognized. The Coordi- nating Body on the Seas of East Asia (COBSEA) (2011) noted that coastal and marine spatial planning (CMSP) “is emerging as a tool of choice around the world, particu- larly in heavily used marine areas. CMSP offers countries an operational framework to maintain the value of their marine biodiversity while at the same time allowing sustainable use of the economic potential of their oceans. CMSP is an approach that can make key components of ecosystem-based management of coastal and marine areas a reality.”
  • 63. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 45 Ensuring institutional coherence As discussed above, many fisheries are faced with multiple aims that are often conflict- ing, and few mechanisms exist to facilitate trade-offs and choices. This can potentially lead to a lack of policy coherence which confuses what fisheries management is trying to achieve. Even when there is some clarity of aim, it may not be possible to predict how implementation of policies will pan out. Overfishing can be seen as a rational response to irrational policies (Dengbol, 2009). Policy processes, legislative frameworks and governance structures often reflect situations that no longer exist. As noted by Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, (2010, 4) “[a]ccess rights, laws and institutional structures in some countries are outdated and do not reflect social and political realities, so that governance structures have inherent conflicts.” The historic evolution of the fishery and the forces at play within the political economy influence the way political decisions are made and the way fisheries managers at the national level have interpreted national policy. Much of the past emphasis of fisheries has been on productivity increases and many government departments are still staffed by people with skills that reflect this focus, in agencies structured around productivity using top-down approaches. Salas and Gaertner (2004, 154) recognized this, noting: “… fishers develop and implement strategies and tactics in response to the constraints they encounter and their intended objectives given their particular human, social, cultural and economic contexts. Managers in contrast, have generally made simplistic assumptions about fishers’ nature and attitudes when defining management policies.” There is also a need to ensure that institutional structures and processes are enshrined in law to avoid failure in political coherence when political parties or indi- viduals change. Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010, 4) noted that frequent changes in political leadership can “make it difficult to secure the sustained policy commitment over decades that EBM requires; individual and institutional champions of EBM can counterbalance this problem but they are few and civil society organisations in many countries are weak.” Informal discussions with key informants during the course of the current review also emphasized the importance of this aspect in terms of ensuring coherence between management efforts at the local level and the prevailing policy and legislative framework within which they are nested, and in terms of the need to evolve approaches that take account of changing political priorities over the course of long-term management initiatives. Ensuring the viability and sustainability of ecosystem function Marine ecosystems are important not just for the food and income that they generate but also for the many other ecosystem services they provide. These ecosystem services generate benefits for local communities and wider society. A key part of any fisheries management program must be to ensure the healthy condition of the resources and ecosystems being fished. Without this, the harvests are likely to be reduced and/or unsustainable. As discussed above, greater emphasis is being placed on the larger scales involved in fisheries management and beginning to address some of these larger ecological issues through approaches such as LMEs, Seascapes, Marine Ecoregions, Regional Seas and ICM.
  • 64. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 46 Even with smaller areas of sea, there are wider ecological considerations that need to be included in fisheries management. According to Bennett (2005b), several studies have found that much of the success of the management system put in place is due to the biology of the underlying resource species being managed. Some species and ecosys- tems respond to fishing pressure better than others. Sharks, for instance, often have to reach a greater age to breed than many small pelagics (e.g. Peruvian anchovy) and are thus more easily affected by overfishing. Coral reefs seem to be very susceptible to sea water temperature increases and, where local fisheries are under pressure from over- exploitation, a decline in habitat can enhance the negative effects of fishing pressure. A University of Washington study of some 230 fish stocks emphasized the impact of environmental conditions on potential fish harvest (see Box 14). Addressing the wider ecosystem needs will often require combining several ap- proaches to management. The concept of marine protected areas (MPAs), one of the main measures discussed in the literature to ensure the viability and sustainabil- ity of ecosystem function, is used widely across fisheries with mixed results. Many consider MPAs a central tool in marine ecosystem-based management of tropical inshore fisheries (Rudd et al., 2003) and there is now substantial evidence to indicate that, within MPAs, species tend to live longer and grow bigger, and that biomass increases, especially among sedentary and benthic species (Roberts et al., 2001; Gell and Roberts, 2002; Rudd et al., 2003). These larger, more abundant fish may be benefi- cial for tourism. Protected areas can also play an important role in stock enhancement and restocking programs to allow adequate growth and spawning (Bell et al., 2006). Roberts et al. (2005) argue that no-take MPAs can also protect against over-generous fishing quotas, which are often set based on poor information about the fisheries stocks available or on a political reluctance to upset fishers. MPAs are part of a larger group of marine management areas which might include no-take zones, buffer zones or limited access zones – all of which have a role to play in fisheries management depending on the local context. Some spill-over effects from MPAs – where protected species migrate into the unprotect- ed area – are also reported. The effect of this will depend on a number of factors such as the time taken to reach a point where density- dependent movement is achieved (Rudd et al., 2003) – which will vary among species, depending upon their behavior and natural ranges (Tupper and Rudd, 2003). This time needs to be taken into account in order to consider the extent to which excluded fishers will be affected by lost fishing opportunities before beneficial spill-over effects are seen. At the time of their study, Rudd et al. (2003) recognized that it was generally unknown if the benefits of greater catches from spillover were sufficient to offset lost catches from the MPA. Pitcher et al. (2000) showed that boundary porosity had a strong influence BOX 14: The drivers of fish abundance It is often assumed that the potential harvest of fish is dependent upon their abundance, but a recent study suggests that we may have to rethink some assumptions. The University of Washington-led study suggested that harvestable amount was only closely linked to abundance in 18% of 230 fish stocks assessed. For the other 82% of stocks, potential harvest was primarily controlled by irregular shifts in environmental conditions or was random and not controlled by either abundance or shifts in environmental regimes. Source: University of Washington http://www.washington. edu/news/2013/01/14/potential-harvest-of-most-fish- stocks-largely-unrelated-to-abundance/
  • 65. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 47 on the success of marine reserves. One obstacle to MPAs as an effective fisheries management tool is that, while the fish that stay within the MPA are afforded pro- tection, those outside are subjected to greater harvesting pressure unless effort is reduced. While the exploitation of resources inside protected areas on a sustainable basis is reported to improve the living conditions of people who depend upon the protected resources (Andrade and Rhodes, 2012), there can also be negative effects. McConney and Charles (2008) noted that MPAs can lead to conflicts over resources, but the extent to which such issues arise tends to be influenced by design and gov- ernance arrangements. MPAs have a role to play in fisheries management systems, particularly when com- munities are directly involved in their design and management. Community-based MPAs are designed to meet both small-scale fisheries management and conservation needs. In addition, when run by interested and informed people through collective action, they have proved an effective approach (Christie and White, 2006). In recogni- tion of the role of communities in environmental protection, in 2003, the African Heads of State amended the African Convention on Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources to promote the establishment of community-based protected areas (Tobey and Torell, 2006). MPAs, as part of a wider ICM approach, are having some success in some parts of the world (White et al., 2006). For example, the Philippines has estab- lished more than 1,100 MPAs, of which at least 20 percent are reportedly achieving their management targets (Lowry et al., 2009) (See Box 15). Adaptating to external pressure and changes Fisheries are always changing and often in ways that cannot be predicted (see Box 14). Climate change is having considerable effects on fisheries, and fuel and food prices are changing rapidly. Even with the best will in the world, plans will need to be adjusted and changed over time. Being able to adapt to these external pressures will be an important function of future fisheries management. The coast is in a constant state of flux and is subject to major upheavals from time to time. Coastal and marine social-ecological systems are characterized by their high degree of risk and uncertainty (Ferrol- Schulte et al., 2013). Fishers, fish farmers and their communities around the world tend to be vulnerable to natural disasters because of their locations, the characteris- tics of their livelihood activities, and their overall high levels of exposure to natural hazards, livelihood shocks and climate change impacts. As exposure and vulner- ability to these hazards is increasing (FAO, 2012a), the ability to predict, prepare for, cope with and adapt to change will be critical to any fisheries management situation. BOX 15: Community-based coastal resource management – success or failure? There have been a number of assessments of the effectiveness of community-based coastal resource management (CBCRM) programs in the Philippines where MPAs play a major role. Approximately 91% of the over 600 MPAs in the Philippines are managed under the CBCRM framework. In 1997, 19% of the 47 completed CBCRM programs survived after external funding was withdrawn. In 1999, 10% of the 439 MPAs in existence were well enforced. In 2004, 156 MPAs were evaluated and 44.2% were found to be successful. This suggests that success increases over time. Worldwide the estimates of successful MPAs vary from 10–30%. Source: Maliao et al., 2009
  • 66. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 48 Climate change Climate change is now well recognized as having potential effects on fisheries that are widespread and significant (Cochrane et al., 2009). Climate change is already affecting the distribution and movement of fish stocks. It is also affecting coral reefs through sea temperature rise, and increasing coastal inundation. Extreme weather events, such as tidal surges and storms, are also on the increase. These not only affect the social, economic and cultural aspects of fishers’ lives directly, they also affect fishing com- munities located on coastal margins. Loss of life from such events is more common in developing countries. From 1970 to 2008, more than 95 percent of deaths from natural disasters were in developing countries (IPCC, 2011). The poor are often affected most in these situations, as they inhabit the higher risk environments (Blaikie et al., 1994). Food and fuel prices Global food and fuel prices change the costs and benefits of fisheries, as well as the tourism trade, which can be a significant market for many small-scale fishers, such as those in the Caribbean. In addition, global terrorism and economic decline affect markets and especially tourism which, in turn, directly affect fish sales and alternative employment opportunities. Population and development Increasing coastal populations and coastal development have a significant effect on coastal habitats and pollution. While coastal tourism brings opportunities to coastal communities, it also increases stress on water and land use. Inland infrastructure, such as dams and factories, is also beginning to affect water quality and flows into coastal areas. While it is unlikely that all forecasts will be consistently accurate in the fisheries management process, McConney and Charles (2008) noted the importance of learning to live with uncertainty, rather than seeking more sophisticated fisheries models. Box 16 provides an example of how coastal management is evolving to address uncertainty. Allen and Gunderson (2011) suggested that there are specific circumstances where adaptive management can be effective – especially when the situation is controllable but uncertain (see Box 17). Adaptive co-management can be defined as an approach based on collaboration among agencies, researchers and local stewards where natural resource management is seen as a process of controlled experiments that need to be monitored and improved upon (Moberg and Galaz, 2005). There is growing support for adaptive management processes that foster resilience and flexibility (Mahon et al., 2008; Allen and Gunderson, 2011; Evans et al., 2011b). Alpízar (2006) noted that co-management and community-based management ap- proaches have the potential to respond to change and dynamic conditions more quickly than central programs because they are closer to where these changes are being ex- perienced. Berkes et al. (2000) pointed out that traditional management systems have certain elements in common with adaptive management strategies, such as: i) man- agement rules are locally crafted and socially enforced by users, ii) resource use tends to be flexible and change with circumstances, iii) accumulated knowledge allows ap-
  • 67. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 49 propriate responses from ecological feedback, iv) a diversity of resources is used for livelihoods thus keeping options open, and v) qualitative approaches are used, rather than working towards quantitative yield targets. They also discussed how traditional ecological knowledge “can be viewed as a ‘library of information’ on how to cope with dynamic change in complex systems” (Berkes et al., 2000, 1259). They also pointed out that adaptive management and traditional practices emphasize process and accommo- date change as part of that process, and that by “responding to and managing feedbacks from ecosystems, instead of blocking them out, adaptive management seeks to avoid eco- logical thresholds at scales that threaten the existence of social and economic activities, as do some traditional management systems” (Berkes et al., 2000, 1260). In relation specifi- cally to MPAs, Christie and White (2006, 211) said that “[i]t is apparent that a well-managed MPA requires an adaptive management approach.” The external changes not only affect people, they also affect the environment. Increas- ingly climate change is seen to be affecting abundance and distribution of coastal species. One argument for MPAs in fisheries is that the levels of uncertainty associated with change require a risk buffer that MPAs can provide for the wider marine ecosystem. The BOX 16: Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region INTEGRATING EMERGING ISSUES AND MODERN MANAGEMENT APPROACHES The  Spatial  Planning  in  the  Coastal Zone  Disaster  Prevention  and  Sustainable Development  Project was developed by the Coordinating Body on the Seas of East Asia (COBSEA) Secretariat as a post- tsunami project during 2006. Its overall goals are to reduce and prevent the impacts of natural disasters, climate change and sea level rise, and to promote sustainable development of the coastal areas in COBSEA member countries through the application of spatial planning for integrated coastal zone management (ICZM) and ecosystem-based management (EBM). In achieving the overall goal, the specific objectives are to: • develop the regional policy, resource and guidance document, Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region: Integrating Emerging Issues and Modern Management Approaches • strengthen national capacities in sustainable coastal spatial planning through the application of the adaptation of the document into national needs and capacities for the COBSEA countries for spatial planning and disaster risk reduction • enhance the capacity of countries to integrate the consideration of new concepts such as climate change, ecosystem based management, disaster risk reduction and integrated land-sea planning into their existing national spatial planning procedures and systems. Source: COBSEA, 2011 BOX 17: Management approaches for different situations Source: Allen and Gunderson 2011, adapted from Peterson et al., 2003 Controllable LowHigh Uncertainty Uncontrollable Controllability Adaptive managment Maximum sustainable yield Scenario planning Build Resilience
  • 68. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 50 fact that MPAs may have a role to play in building ecological resilience (Rudd et al., 2003) has never been as important as now when, in many parts of the world, climate change is an uncertain process. When looking at how community-based systems for commons management can be used to scale-up approaches, Berke (2006) noted that “it may be more illuminating to approach the debate by suggesting that commons management in many cases should be understood as the management of complex adaptive systems …”, and that such systems are affected by a multitude of outside forces which affect them. However, adaptive management approaches are not without problems. Allen and Gunderson (2011) identified a number of conditions that can negatively affect the success of adaptive management when: • stakeholders are not fully engaged in the process • ecosystems are very complex • unforeseen events occur – such as natural disasters which are on the increase in many areas where climate change is expected to be significant • managers are too prescriptive about how they respond to change • the desire to learn overtakes the desire to act • learning does not feed back to policy • hard decisions are avoided • leadership is absent, dogmatic, non-inclusive or biased in a particular direction • planning takes the place of action. There will always be uncertainty in the management of fisheries which are complex social-ecological systems, and this will lead to unpredictability. In addition Ferrol- Schulte et al. (2013) noted that, in poverty stricken areas, the necessary funds and know-how to manage resources adaptively is often lacking. A sustainable livelihoods approach can be a useful tool to address the complexities of social-ecological systems in coastal areas and assist adaptive planning. Adaptive management takes learning as a necessary starting point in the struggle to confront and respond to this uncertainty, according to Armitage et al. (2009). They noted that adaptive management is not a governance panacea and will not be suitable in all cases, and that tools are still being developed. They also identified ten key condi- tions for successful adaptive co-management: • a well-defined resource system • small-scale resource-use contexts • clear and identifiable set of social entities with shared interests • reasonably clear property rights to resources of concern • access to an adaptable portfolio of management measures • commitment to support a long-term institution-building process • provision training, capacity building and resources for local-, regional- and nation- al-level stakeholders • key leaders or individuals prepared to champion the process • openness of participants to share and draw upon a plurality of knowledge systems and sources • national and regional policy environment explicitly supportive of collaborative management efforts.
  • 69. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 51 However, as Gondo (2008) noted, adaptive co-management systems and tools are still at an early stage of development and should be treated with caution. Gondo also pointed out that a key part of adaptive co-management is the need for continuous experimenta- tion and experience in dealing with the associated problems. This is not new for fisheries managers, who have experimented with management measures over decades. 6.3 Factors affecting technical implementation While the above factors tend to apply to a larger design scale, there are others that are more concerned with technical issues. Although these classifications are not set in stone, these technical issues can include the allocations of rights, the need to change structures and processes incrementally in order to accommodate the local pace of change, ensuring that the right things are done with the right institution and that decisions occur at the right level, acknowledging the importance of the local political situation and factoring it into management decisions, recognizing the importance of balancing costs and benefits of management, and addressing the importance of local and global markets. Establishing legal group rights and responsibilities Across the range of fisheries management approaches and themes discussed above, rights are playing a more and more central role in what is done. There is a growing move towards greater and more sophisticated approaches to rights that combine fisheries and human rights. This is a first step towards connecting fisheries to the wider well-being of coastal communities (Charles, 2011). While fisheries rights can take many forms, there seems to be growing support for community-based rights in small-scale fisheries. Recognition of this linkage between community-based systems and welfare of communities is gaining momentum (e.g. Copes and Charles, 2004) but lacks supporting data, particularly on the multiplier effects across communities. The need for controls in fisheries and the recognition of the finite and exhaustible nature of fish has encouraged a stronger focus on rights around fishing. This has been closely linked to two key problems associated with common property resources, namely that: i) exclusion or control of access is difficult and ii) each fisher’s activity subtracts from the potential gains of other users (Berke, 2006). There is now wide- spread acceptance among fisheries academics and managers that some form of rights in fisheries is essential to the success of fisheries management. According to FAO (2012a), such approaches do have potential to rationalize and improve returns in small-scale fisheries and increase resources rents at the national level. However, they need to be implemented in ways that provide for rent distribution methods that include the poor and vulnerable. Huppert (2005, 201) noted that “(t)he controversies over fishing rights take three forms: disagreements over the meaning and intent of fishing rights, disputes over the distribution of rights and associated economic gain, and concern for disruptions imposed on people who are dependent on the ‘old order’.” The initial allocation of rights can be particularly difficult and controversial (Pearse, 1992). Anderson and Libecap (2010) suggested that, in the allocation of rights, the allocation along the lines
  • 70. 52 of first-possession, or “grandfathering” can make both economic sense (they are more knowledgeable about the resource and thus often lower cost) and institutional sense (by suggesting that historic engagement is likely to ensure rights of access). They said that in community-based fisheries where the participants are often poor but well informed about the resources, “grandfathering” is likely to generate local support for management measures. Overall, the practical experience of using individual transferrable quotas (ITQs), one of the most commonly promoted forms of individual fishing right, is seen as encourag- ing as a rights-based approach. Yet, in 2008, ITQs were found in less than 2 percent of the world’s fisheries (Costello et al., 2008). According to Leal (2010), they had generated considerable benefits in the form of higher income for fishers, improved product quality for consumers, reduced fleet excesses, and largely maintained harvest with TACs. But these benefits have largely been associated with developed countries. ITQs are also beginning to be used in those developing countries where there is a transition to more reliable legal institutions with stronger governance, e.g. in the anchovy fishery of Peru and Chile (Leal, 2010). While transferable quotas in developed countries have focused mainly on giving quotas to vessels or owners, in developing countries there is increasing interest in rights to quotas being provided to communities or specific community groups or as- sociations For example, in the Philippines, collective action and participation would be increased if fishers cooperatives were given exclusive rights which restrict access and, in turn, provide greater incentives for improved resource management in the long-term (Baticados, 2004). The balance between small-scale and industrial fisheries needs to be examined with a view to the appropriate allocation of property rights (Stobutzki et al., 2006). In many developing fisheries, legally-backed exclusive fishing rights granted to nearby communities or fishing cooperatives are likely to be a more practical form of rights (Leal, 2010) (see Box 18). Associations of fishers are more and more taking on the role of government in fisheries management, which according to Scott (2010) heralds a new fishers’ culture. This is supported to an extent by the fact that studies over the last 30 years have documented the capability of com- munities to self-organize and self-regulate to resolve problems of the commons (Berke, 2006). Territorial use rights in fisheries (TURFs), in practice in many parts of the world, have been a means of traditional fisheries access rights and, according to Hilborn (2007a): “the most direct incentive to facilitate compliance is the granting of territorial fishing rights to individuals or communities. This provides a BOX 18: Local management of lobster stocks The red lobster (Panuliris interuptus) found on the west coast of Baja California, Mexico, is harvested by fishers’ cooperatives under concessions established in the 1930s. Nine cooperatives work together in a federation to manage the stock. As an indication of success, in 2004, after extensive scientific review, the Marine Stewardship Council (MSC) certified that the fishery satisfied the MSC’s criteria for sustainable fishing. Source: Leal, 2010
  • 71. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 53 strong incentive to exclude non-members … .” In much of the Pacific, small-scale fisheries have been based on TURFs from which neighboring communities have been largely excluded. During expert consultations as part of this review, several respondents referred to the success of introducing TURFS in the Chilean loco (abalone) fishery, through which rights to fisheries in different areas are allocated to local cooperatives. Increasingly fishing rights are being placed in the wider framework of human rights (FAO, 2010) (See Box 19). Incrementally changing to allow for capacity, reflection and negotiated response Adopting new approaches and tools for fisheries management – including those that address wider social, economic, ecological and political concerns and are inte- grated vertically across scale and horizontally across sectors – requires new skills and knowledge, and also new attitudes from those involved, such as managers and community members. In addition, getting the speed of change right is very important to the successful management of change. In many situations, change has been intro- duced at a pace that managers and community members find difficult to understand and respond to. The increased focus on the need to integrate fisheries management into wider economic systems is reflected in a move towards more integrated, multi-sector and BOX 19: Rights in small-scale fisheries At its 26th session in March 2009, the FAO Committee on Fisheries (COFI) reviewed the outcome of the Global Conference on Small-Scale Fisheries – Securing sustainable small-scale fisheries: Bringing together responsible fisheries and social development. Held in Bangkok, Thailand, 13-17 October 2008, the Conference was attended by more than 280 participants from 65 countries. It was preceded by a preparatory workshop with more than 100 participants from fishworkers’ organizations and CSOs. The Conference re-enforced the claim that small-scale fisheries have yet to fully realize their potential to significantly contribute to sustainable development and the attaining of the UN millennium development goals (MDGs). In spite of their economic, social and nutritional benefits and societal and cultural values, small-scale fishing communities often face precarious and vulnerable living and working conditions. Various factors contribute to these conditions, including insecure rights to land and fishery resources, inadequate or absent health and educational services and social safety nets, vulnerability to natural disasters and climate change, and exclusion from wider development processes due to weak organizational structures and representation and participation in decision-making. The 2008 Conference identified several critical ways forward in securing sustainable small-scale fisheries that integrate social, cultural and economic development, address resource access and use-rights issues guided by human rights principles, and recognize the rights of indigenous peoples. The Conference also reaffirmed that human rights are critical to achieving sustainable development. Source: Willmann, 2010
  • 72. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 54 ecosystem-based management (White et al., 2006). The increased use of integrated coastal management (ICM) as an approach to wider ecological management systems in coastal areas has necessitated adapting institutional and organizational structure to accommodate the different roles and responsibilities. This has meant building skills and qualifications across different ministries and departments to ensure a commonal- ity of purpose, methods and language, a difficult process that should not be underesti- mated, as shown by ICM experience in the Philippines (see Box 20). During discussions for this review, experts highlighted the challenge of finding the means of communicating ideas about complex management issues that are ac- cessible to those who are unfamiliar with the terminology and concepts. Several re- spondents referred to experiences with foreign experts in ecosystem-based manage- ment approaches who had attempted to explain extremely complex ideas to local or national counterparts using language that was largely inaccessible to them, rather than breaking the concepts down into more “digestible” elements and building under- standing incrementally. Christie and White (2006) recommended the incremental development and the adoption of ICM and other comprehensive frameworks such as EBM, building on past practice to match human and fiscal capacities. Although calls have been made for larger scale interventions to maximize ecological function, they were sometimes done without sufficiently careful analysis. For example, the Large Marine Ecosystem (LME) approach moved ahead with little empirically grounded understanding of what it entailed (Christie and White, 2006). Incentives are often needed for local gov- ernment to move in the direction of change in support of ICM. For example, when the Philippines adopted a coastal resources man- agement (CRM) certification process which was often provided with external financial support, it encouraged national-level agencies to start redefining their roles as providing technical assistance to local government rather than taking the lead on such initiatives (White et al., 2006). There is also recognition in the Philippines that networks of MPAs in a wider ICM process require development of network governance (Lowry et al., 2009). In some areas of the world, MPA and other man- agement networks have been established to support joint learning and lesson sharing. The Philippines has social and information networks that assist in improved manage- ment of MPAs. Christie and White (2006) BOX 20: Lessons from ICM in the Philippines A review of experiences in coastal management in the Philippines provided the following lessons. • ICM provides the framework for local government to implement sustainable coastal development. • Participation at all levels and allowing interagency cooperation and cross-sectoral integration is a prerequisite for ICM. • An integrated planning process is essential. • Comprehensive information systems that evolve with planning processes are needed. • Institutionalizing ICM into local government is important for integrating into regular development plans. • Baseline information is necessary for ICM planning. • Community-based management requires on-going support and mentoring from government, civil society and the private sector. • Sustainability of ICM cannot be determined without time and field testing. Source: modified from White et al., 2006
  • 73. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 55 identified five effective processes derived from networking efforts that led to good practice and scaling-up of governance: i) consensus building on common issues, ii) information sharing and identification of core groups, iii) institutionalizing mecha- nisms for administration, iv) sustainable financing and v) adaptive management. For instance, at the international level, the Local Marine Management Area Network (LMMA) is an example of a learning network, in place across Southeast Asia and the Pacific where members exchange information and experiences. Institutional fit and subsidiarity Ensuring the institutional “fit” of a set of management/governance issues is increas- ingly recognized as important (Armitage et al., 2012). This might include the suit- ability of different institutional arrangements to address specific problems. Some researchers, such as Folke et al. (1998) have determined that resource boundaries rarely fit institutional boundaries. Similarly, Berkes (2006) noted “integrated systems of human-in-nature are more likely to work if there is a fit between the level and boundary of the ecosystem and the institution designed to manage it.” For example, tuna in the Pacific migrate between nations, in and out of EEZs and through inshore fishing areas. Even though many communities have successfully addressed many of the issues associated with common property fisheries, they are still subject to many external pressures that require solutions that respond to scale (Berkes, 2006). In many parts of the world, traditional customary marine tenure (CMT) was the norm and, in some places, particularly in the Pacific, CMT still plays an important role. However, as fisheries capacity has developed and concerns over the resource have increased, the management process in many places has become more central- ized and developed. Some see this move from community-based fisheries manage- ment systems to centrally controlled government systems as leading to replacement of common-property regimes with open-access (Pomeroy, 1994). However, in many cases, traditional community-based institutions, in their original form, are no longer appropriate for the management of more mechanized fisheries which extend beyond traditional grounds, involve many more people and feed into more easily accessible and larger markets. Kuemlangan (2004), who looked at the institutional fit between community-based fisheries management and the legal systems in a number of countries in the Pacific, found that recognition of customary marine tenure may provide an opportunity for adopting more community-based systems. This raised the important question of the legal requirements needed to establish co-management in countries with less history of such approaches. In Cambodia, a process of consultation around the by-law on fisheries co-management took four years. Although customary marine tenure has worked in the past, Kuemlangan (2004) also noted that those past structures and processes are not necessarily ideal for the future. Rather, it is better to see customary marine tenure as a dynamic process that can inform and influence future processes. In noting the importance of the legal and jurisdictional context in which MPAs operate to long-term management, Christie and White (2006) also identified the following principles for effective legal and jurisdictional norms related to MPA experience.
  • 74. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 56 Nested institutional and legal (national to local) systems, if balanced and supportive of local initiatives, support MPA implementation. MPA management requires both upward (from local to national agency) and downward (from national to local agency) coordination and accountability. • Embedding MPA management within larger management systems designed to address larger sectoral and development processes will help address external impacts on MPAs. • Transparency, fairness and broad understanding of the law and enforcement support compliance and reduce conflict. • Clear identification of the role and responsibilities for formal and informal MPA management bodies is necessary. • The jurisdictional mandate should fit the institutional capacity of a management body. If necessary, there should be ongoing attention to the development of insti- tutional capacity. A consistent national mandate for MPA implementation with adequate resources for implementation can provide a supportive environment (Christie and White, 2006, 197). This theme, regarding the way in which the legal and institutional context meshes with management efforts on the ground, emerged repeatedly during expert inter- views. It often took the form of constraints encountered by local-level fisheries man- agement initiatives in situations where existing legislation on fisheries and manage- ment contradicted rules and regulations being evolved at the local level. Often, the fact that legislative functions are entirely held at the national level meant that local administrations could not be as responsive as they wished in approving and sanc- tioning new forms of management being generated at the ground level. The issue of subsidiarity and the devolution of decision-making responsibility to the lowest appro- priate level in order to support adaptive management in the field therefore seemed to be particularly important. Institutional fit also has cost implications (Abdullah et al., 1998). Christie and White (2006) noted that MPA planning and monitoring can be expensive, and centralized government MPA agencies must compete with other more pressing budget needs such as health, economic development and education. But they also pointed out that centralized control of management is necessary and effective in some situations, as in the case of MPAs in Brunei. In some cases, it may be appropriate to consider the private sector as the agency for engaging in management as, for example, was shown in Chumbe Island, Tanzania (Cristie and White, 2006). In such situations, it is important to balance the incentives of society’s goals with those of the private sector. Across a number of environmental concerns, there is a growing emergence of hybrid forms of governance that combine state, markets and civil society (Armitage et al., 2012). Costa Rica has split its resource management function between two government or- ganizations, one concerned with conservation and the other with resource use. This agency interaction is not uncommon, as fisheries departments do not always agree with the policies of environment agencies (Alpízar, 2006).
  • 75. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 57 Also, in dealing with the effect of climate change on fisheries, the more traditional insti- tutional arrangements within government no longer fit the problems to be addressed. Instead, this calls for incentives to be in place that will encourage different agencies and ministries to collaborate and share information and experience, e.g. in cross-sectoral functions such as climate change response, disaster risk reduction and ICM. Other external considerations, such as fuel and food prices, fisheries-tourism interac- tions, coastal development and livelihood diversification might require changes in the types of institutional arrangements needed to implement change. Likewise, the move from a production focus in many fisheries to a poverty reduction or food security focus may require skills and experience that fisheries departments do not have and may necessitate evolving new partnerships with other agencies such as NGOs. Having the right institutional arrangements at the community level and within government is also crucial. In some situations, localization of governance might be seen as decentraliza- tion of function to district-level fisheries offices rather than to community organiza- tions (Rudd et al., 2003). Less traditional forms of rights, such as ITQs, faced implementation issues in develop- ing countries, in part because of the lack of appropriate legal, institutional and gov- ernance arrangements required to achieve an appropriate institutional fit. Bennett (2005b) noted that property rights have to be equitable in their allocation but also, the wider stakeholder group, i.e. society, must see them as fair. Another often overlooked aspect of institutional fit is the way that external funding can distort fisheries management processes. Project support can provide a hothouse effect which ensures a greater chance of a fisheries management initiative succeed- ing. However, reporting on the success of such projects during implementation may generate a more favorable assessment than would be the case several years after the project has finished. Likewise, donor willingness to compartmentalize the policy process and fund some aspects of fisheries management but not others can distort those policies, resulting in long-term adverse effects. Aid effectiveness processes have been established to address some of these distortions.5 The situation has shown con- siderable progress in the fisheries sector in Cambodia, which now has much greater policy coherence and has reduced the transaction costs of policy, planning and policy implementation (see Box 21). The engagement of any external implementer or funder, e.g. NGO, consultancy or intergovernmental agency, in the process of fisheries management can distort the factors that support sustainability of positive change. The ecoregional approach adopted by The Nature Conservancy and World-Wide Forum for Nature, works with national and local partners and with NGOs that are committed to the kind of long-term (15–20 year) intervention needed. However, the long-term engagement of an external NGO can impede the emergence of sustainable governance (Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, 2010). Such powerful organizations can influence policy implementation in much the same way as that described for donors above, and aid effectiveness proce- dures need apply equally to them. 5 For example see OECD: www.oecd.org/dac/effectiveness
  • 76. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 58 Incorporating politics and political choices Fisheries management is, in part at least, about the distribution of rights to access resources and the distribution of the benefits from those rights. These are largely political decisions and can be subject to both the choices of political parties and the personal choices of politicians. These two choices manifest themselves either as overt policies or covert forces behind the scenes. Political decisions can be some of the most important influences on fisheries, and the political economy needs to be included fully in the management process for it to stand a chance of being successful. The political forces that influence fisheries management effectiveness have been touched on a number of times in this synthesis. In management more generally, the political aspect of environmental protection has been downplayed (Belsky, 2000) or even externalized in the resource management equation. Economic rationalization approaches to fisheries management tend to focus on the state capture of resource rents for the wider application to national economic development – a political decision which prioritizes economic impacts over other impacts. Welfare approaches tend to focus more on the distributive aspects of resource rents to fuel local development and secure livelihoods. Politics, power and corruption often influence how wealth is redis- tributed in both cases, e.g. through the political economy of national governments and through patronage at a local level. A renewed focus on rent capture by the state is sometimes seen as a means of “introduc- ing some logic into the policy process” (Cunningham et al., 2009). This might suggest a level of rational thinking in economics that does not exist in politics. However, policy is driven by politics, and political processes may have their own logic which may not prioritize purely economic incentives. Wider political issues may concern re-election, feeding the population now, short-term foreign exchange generation, trading fisheries sustainability for politically more important gains, or enhancing personal wealth and/ or patronage through non-transparent means. These may well represent logical uses BOX 21: A sector wide approach in Cambodia The fisheries sector in Cambodia is planned around a 10-year Strategic Planning Framework (SPF) that links to national development policy. The SPF was developed through a participatory planning process that links all subsectors together and links those to provincial plans. A “basket funding” mechanism is in place, which allows donors to fund the sector according to the SPF, rather than their own donor-generated projects. It also has a common monitoring and evaluation system, which uses participatory approaches to gain fishers’ perspectives on policy implementation and feeds these back into policy. Cross-sectoral and donor harmonization issues are addressed through a technical working group process and a strategy for harmonization and alignment encourages donor procedures to harmonize with each other and then align to those of government. There also has been a progressive process of decentralization of function and resources on the basis of subsidiarity. The government-developed Cambodian Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries (CamCode) provides a framework for government, development partners, civil society and private sector to work to a common set of principles and guidance. Source: FiA, internal documents
  • 77. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 59 of fisheries resources if they achieve wider development aims. Externalizing the political economy in discussions of policy is likely to lead to unforeseen outcomes. Robinson (2010) found that most fisheries reform has occurred in well-functioning democracies where competition is for public goods rather than private goods, e.g. to achieve larger departmental budgets rather than personal financial gains. The extent to which the rule of law and other legal and governance institutions function effectively will play a major role in the form of fisheries management and who will benefit from it. If, for instance, government officials allow foreign fishing vessels or unlicensed domestic fishers to operate, then sustainability can be easily under- mined (Hilborn, 2007b). There are many documented cases in the Philippines where CBCRM initiatives have collapsed because of local politics (Maliao et al., 2009). Roe et al. (2009), after reviewing a number of community-based natural resource manage- ment initiatives across Africa, noted that conflicts between local groups and powerful elites remain widespread and are often intensifying. According to Rudd et al. (2003), a breakdown in MPA management on Sumilon Island in the Philippines was caused in part by local politicians engaging in opportunism. Vested interests can also be an incentive for greater or lesser involvement of the state – if conflict over resources plays out beyond local levels, then greater involvement by government may be needed (Wilson et al., 2006). In some situations, the government may be provided with inadequate resources to implement management of fisheries on their own, and it may need the involvement of the community to assist (Wilson et al., 2006). In fisheries management, the generation of knowledge itself is not an apolitical process. By its very nature, what scientists say has a political element because some of the evidence goes on to inform policy and some does not (Belsky, 2000). In discussing the political economy approach to fisheries, Robinson (2010, 54) noted that the political economy approach “leads to a very different way of thinking about policy than the one current in international institutions. It suggests that too much attention is being paid to the first-best solution to this problem and not enough to finding politically feasible ways of mitigating the tragedy of the commons.” The key challenge here, and one widely recognized by respondents during the expert interviews, is that these issues relating to politics and power relations in society are too often regarded as “externalities” which cannot be influenced or addressed by in- terventions focused on fisheries management. However, the critical role that these factors play in influencing fisheries management outcomes is equally recognized. This is in part attributable to the nature of projects working on fisheries manage- ment, which do not necessarily have the skills, mandate, resources or time required to engage at the political level. However, it is also due to a general paucity of appropri- ate tools for analyzing and addressing the political economy surrounding fisheries management and understanding how it can be influenced, or adapted to, during the course of interventions. Sustainably and equitably addressing costs and benefits According to recent analyses of fisheries management, fisheries in some parts of the world cost more than they generate. To generate benefits for society or for fishers, the fisheries management and development process needs to generate surpluses. This, in turn, means understanding the costs and benefits of the management process.
  • 78. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 60 At present, most of the world’s fisheries are heavily subsidized (World Bank-FAO, 2009). In 1992, FAO estimated the global fiscal deficit of fisheries at US$50 billion [FAO, 1993]. Thus, the reference to wealth capture involved in some fisheries man- agement approaches must seem very attractive to politicians who are faced with small budgets, low returns from the sector and ever increasing demands on financial resources. According to Cunningham et al. (2009), under free- and open-access condi- tions, fisheries exploitation levels will reach equilibrium only when all resource rent has been dissipated. While the removal of the free and open access could be seen as the solution to this problem, such arrangements also incur costs. For tropical inshore fisheries, transaction costs may make up a large proportion of the total fisheries management cost, but there are limited data to assess this (Rudd et al., 2003). Abdullah et al. (1998, 108) separate transaction costs into: 1) informa- tion costs, 2) collective decision-making costs, 3) collective operational coast, 4) dis- tributional costs, 5) resource maintenance costs and 6) monitoring, enforcement and compliance costs. They suggest that the cost difference between centrally run man- agement and co-management systems is that cost 1 and 2 are low under a centralized systems whereas 3, 4, 5 and 6 are high, while in a co-management system the cost structure is reversed. Copes and Charles (2004) recognized that socio-economic data are limited for different management systems, but also noted that community-based systems can be less expensive to manage than more individually focused approaches such as ITQs, because of the self-regulation aspects of community based systems. Co-management represents a shift in the financial burden from the central govern- ment to the community, which the community may not be able or willing to support, especially where the benefits of better management may not arrive for many years. MPAs, as part of a program of fisheries management, do appear to have some cost ad- vantages. Cullis-Suzuki and Pauly (2010) roughly estimated the global costs of MPAs to be only 3 percent of fishing subsidies. But this needs to be balanced by considering the number of MPAs that are actually operating effectively. The work done under the DFID-funded Fisheries Management Science Programme (FMSP) showed that, while participation in fisheries management by fishers is ben- eficial, it also comes at a cost. Arthur (2005, 13) noted that, in order for the benefits of co-management to outweigh these costs, “it is vital from the outset that efforts are to develop trust and mutual respect, including respect for different knowledge types. This requires a commitment, throughout the management process, to transparency, accountability and empowerment as well as to explanation, developing skills, and increasing organisational flexibility.” Analyses of marine management areas across Belize, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Panama, Colombia and Brazil found considerable variabil- ity in costs among locations but all sites had significant expenditure on enforcement (Samonte et al., 2010). If fishers are not committed to the rules, there is a particular danger that enforce- ment costs can exceed the benefits to society that the fishery is capable of generat- ing. There may be strong arguments for increased economic rent capture to cover at least some of the costs to society of fisheries management, but given the institutional weaknesses in many developing countries, this seems unlikely to be very effective (Robinson, 2010). Many see co-management as the implementation of the principle of
  • 79. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 61 subsidiarity, and that management is better done, at least in part, at lower levels. This perhaps suggests that there is a case for greater resource rent going to local authori- ties to assist with that management process and to facilitate the wider development role of fisheries locally. Taxation of fisheries might be one way to do this but, in reality, these taxes are rarely applied in developing countries. In part, this is because governments do not have the information to set such taxes at appropriate levels, or do not have the political power to do so, or both (Anderson and Libecap, 2010). This is not to say that more rational economic measures in fisheries would not be beneficial. For instance, fishers generally do not pay for the right to fish or for the ecological costs of stock depletion (Sutinen, 2010) and, in some situations, revenue generation from the fishery, espe- cially if locally collected, might be beneficial for wider development. In most developed country fisheries, a trend towards the concentration of investment and fishing effort into fewer, larger vessels has helped the management process. However, a side effect has been the decline of employment opportunities. In the UK between 1938 and 2008, employment in capture fisheries fell from 48,000 people to 12,761, a loss of 73 percent of the workforce (Campbell and Cattermoul, 2009), a trend also seen in Norway, which lost 90 percent of its capture fisheries employment in a similar period (Béné et al., 2010). While this may be acceptable in developed countries, where greater employment opportunities exist, it is less so in developing countries. Fur- thermore, the transaction costs of governments collecting this rent, enforcing property rights and delivering replacement development services to rural communities while avoiding political interference are likely to be high, especially where the rule of law is poorly adhered to. Legal rules, organizations and processes are central to the success of any effort to reform fisheries management (Thompson, 2010) and their existence and rigorous application in many developing countries is limited. Anderson and Libecap (2010) also noted that rents created by rights-based approaches and transferred to gov- ernment will be competed for in a potentially rent-dissipating political process. The extent to which fisheries are seen to generate economic benefits is in part dependent on how costs and benefits are measured. As Béné (2011) noted, “reducing the value of fisheries to their rent … misrepresents the real contribution that these small-scale fisheries play for the livelihoods and food security of millions of people in Africa.” In the case of small-scale fisheries in developing countries, what is perceived as the dissipation of rents through a failure to accurately capture and measure them can actually represent, at least in part, the distribution of benefits from small-scale fisheries within local communities through employment and trade. This contribution is often not recorded in GDP figures, and so the economic role of small-scale fisheries is often ignored (Hall and Andrew, 2011). In this sense, community-based fisheries can play a significant role as a social policy instrument (Campbell et al., 2006). In many countries, coastal fishing communities represent growth hubs where income from fisheries fuels a large local economy, but these multiplier effects are often poorly understood (Allison, 2011) and are all too often externalized from fisheries economic calculations. Small-scale coastal fisheries have generated, and continue to generate, employment for large numbers of people (Béné, 2011) on a full-time, part- time, seasonal and safety net basis which often forms a very significant part of their
  • 80. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 62 livelihood strategies linked into other sectors (Whittingham et al., 2003, Béné, 2011). For many people, having a particular sectoral focus for food, income and employment puts too much risk in one area, while a diversified portfolio of livelihood activities is safer and may keep them out of poverty (Allison and Ellis, 2001). However attractive the capture of resource rent by the state may seem, it is difficult to find many examples where fisheries resource rent from small-scale fisheries in developing counties has been captured by the government and subsequently applied to local community development with the same multiplier effect as the fishery itself. This role of generating rural employment and providing a safety net, which fisheries often play in developing countries, is very important politically, especially when the government does not have the funds to fill the gap that other approaches to fisheries management might create. Alban et al. (2011) provided some useful insights into addressing cost benefit analysis of MPAs but recognized the problems involved in doing so effectively, for example the difficulty of measuring non-market values such as marine biodiversity and the lack of data on the effects of MPAs on wider fisheries. In addition, transaction costs are likely to be high when using MPAs for tropical inshore fisheries (Rudd et al., 2003). After reviewing a number of protected areas and associated approaches to management, DeFries et al. (2007) determined that identifying “small loss-big gain” opportunities – where big gains for management are achieved at low cost to human use – presents a key management challenge. While the costs and benefits of different management systems will vary greatly, there are doubtless ways in which these costs can be rationalized through the application of good practice. One facet of costs and benefits noted in both the literature and in- terviews is that positive change in fisheries management requires adequate financial support for a long period of time to be effective. Ultimately this should be self-sustain- ing. Even in conservation-related management measures where fishers are excluded, there may be problems in financing the operations. Andrade and Rhodes (2012) noted that the successful establishment and maintenance of protected areas requires political and financial commitment in the long-term. Conservation International, in its Seascapes approach, recognizes the importance of sustainable financing and market mechanisms (Bensted-Smith and Kirkman, 2010). The expert discussions, held as part of the review, highlighted the need for new and innovative sources of financing for fisheries and marine ecosystem management. The timeframes involved in establishing effective management processes and mechanisms are generally long and tend to stretch beyond the normal period of donor funding and project cycles, generally exceeding the mandates of politicians and administrators whose support and engagement is so important in bringing about change. Clearly, over these long timeframes, the priorities of donors, supporting agencies and politi- cians will often change, and the destination of available funding will often shift as these priorities evolve. For example, donors or government may prioritize setting up MPAs as a key management intervention for 2–3 years in response to wider political agendas, but this may subsequently be replaced by a desire to focus on climate change issues or community resilience for the next funding cycle.
  • 81. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 63 This can make it extremely challenging to ensure the flow of resources required to support a long-term intervention to develop fisheries management. Those involved in implementing and supporting such processes on the ground often speak of the need for managers to be “entrepreneurial” in knitting together different sources of short- term funding in order to create a coherent program on the ground, and in molding the way in which they present their work in order to respond to changing priorities. Alternative and innovative mechanisms for ensuring a more consistent and long-term flow of resources into the sector are therefore attracting increasing interest in fisheries management, just as they are already playing an increasingly important role in sup- porting marine conservation efforts in general. A variety of models for generating the resources to support transition to more sustainable management approaches have been proposed. • The Financial Institution for the Recovery of Marine Ecosystems (FIRME), currently being developed as part of the WWF Smart Fishing Initiative, proposes establishing a fund that can provide resources for the upfront costs of develop- ing and implementing management schemes on a loan basis, secured against the value of future fish stocks based on credible sustainable fisheries management plans. Initial potential financing for this fund has been identified to come from the redirection of subsidies currently directed at the fisheries sector (which are themselves partly responsible for existing management issues). Funding would also come from socially responsible investment from private finance, with a po- tentially important role for more traditional grant funds from governments and philanthropic institutions to leverage more sustainable investment sources and support higher risk initiatives (WWF, 2012). • The development of markets for seafood products produced with ecologically and socially responsible methods has attracted much attention in recent years, particu- larly in developed countries. This provides, at least potentially, a means of generat- ing revenue for producers and agencies through premium pricing that can be used to cover the additional costs of management and to cushion the social and economic impacts of changes in management. The costs associated with labeling schemes, which are considerable, particularly for small-scale producers, have generally been covered to date by grant funds from supporting organizations (MRAG, 2010). • Trust funds for marine conservation have become popular over the last two decades as a means of providing longer-term financing that is not dependent on funding for specific projects or programs. These trust funds can take several forms, including endowments, which provide a permanent capital fund which generates investment from interest and investment earnings; sinking funds, which may also invest the capital provided and therefore have a limited life span; or revolving funds, where the capital provided is maintained through user fees, fines or earmarked taxes, such as the Belize Protected Areas Trust Fund which is maintained by a $4.00 fee for park visitors. Trust funds often tend to operate as sources of small grants and can provide effective long-term flows of resources into either fisheries management or marine conservation more generally, although they can suffer from relatively high administrative costs and are dependent on the performance of their investments (Spergel and Moye, 2004).
  • 82. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 64 • Debt-for-nature swaps have also attracted attention, particularly from bilateral donors who agree to cancel part of a country’s debt in return for guarantees on in- vestment in nature conservation. The Philippines 2002 Debt-for-Nature swap with the United States government provided funds for small grants for conservation over a 10-year period, some of which was spent on marine conservation activities (Spergel and Moye, 2004). • Earmarked taxes, fees and levies have been widely used in fisheries to ensure a sustainable flow of funding into fisheries management. Issues have been raised on occasions regarding the specific “earmarking” of funds from these sources, as opposed to their inclusion in the overall national budget. However, countries such as New Zealand, which has a Fisheries Services Levy and also charges a Conservation Services Levy on specific fisheries that have high levels of by-catch or ecosystem impacts, and Namibia, which has a Fish Catch Levy, have effective systems in place that ensure a flow of funds to fisheries research and fisheries management. Worldwide, these levies are found in many different forms, ranging from taxes on tourists, hotel guests and airport users, protected area entrance fees, excise taxes, lottery revenues and pollution fines (Spergel and Moye, 2004). • Payments for ecosystem services (PES) also provide a potential source of financing for fisheries and marine ecosystem management. Although better developed for terrestrial ecosystems, where initial valuation and monitoring is easier, a market for the protection of marine ecosystem services is developing, particularly for coastal habitats and coral reefs. The valuation of the ecosystem services involved in marine habitats is particularly challenging, and the effective- ness of these mechanisms is particularly dependent on good governance and strong capacity to ensure compliance. The most widespread applications have been in more developed nations where the rule of law is strong and monitoring mechanisms are better developed (Forest Trends et al., 2008). To date, the application of such mechanisms to fisheries is less developed, although fisheries has also benefitted from existing tools and their application. However, the majority of these tools have tended to be applied in more developed countries as they almost all depend on the availability of data (for example on the values of ecosys- tems), high levels of monitoring (for example to ensure compliance in the protection of ecosystem services) and the availability of the resources and capacities required to set them up and ensure their proper functioning. Getting market measures right Market measures to support the sustainable harvesting of fish are becoming more popular in developed countries as a means to enhance the management process. Thus far, they have had limited effects in developing countries, but there is increasing pressure for these measures. Markets have had profound effects on fisheries in many countries in recent years. Fish is now a significant source of foreign exchange for many countries, which has raised its profile among politicians. There is also a growing realization among consumers
  • 83. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 65 that fisheries are having profound effects on the environment. Sustainable fisheries labels are becoming an increasingly important marketing device, especially in developed country supermarkets. The extent to which this has influenced small-scale fisheries in de- veloping countries is limited, but the number of cases is growing (see Box 22). An analysis of the Marine Stewardship Council (MSC), undertaken by Gulbrand- sen (2009), found that the MSC has contrib- uted to more open management processes in certified fisheries but that environmental benefits from the scheme may take longer to be seen. In a report on fish certifica- tion and eco-labeling, the OECD and FAO (2009) highlighted that sustainability is difficult to market. It is becoming clear that despite consumers’ stated interests in the environmental impacts of their purchasing decisions, their actual buying behavior, especially in relation to food, is more likely to be determined by other factors. The current global financial crisis has seen consumer confidence fall and their behavior increasingly influenced by price. The industry therefore cannot, at the moment, rely on consumers being prepared to pay a price premium for sustainable fish and seafood. Part of the debate at the 2009 OECD and FAO Round Table on Eco-labeling and Certi- fication in the Fisheries Sector focused on the role that eco-labeling has played in man- agement and fishers’ behavior. According to the meeting report, at that time, there was little concrete evidence of the impact of eco-labeling and certification on improve- ments in fisheries management and sustainability. It speculated that eco-labeling had achieved more as a marketing tool than as a conservation one, although the report did go on to say that increasing evidence indicated that eco-labeling and certification might lead to better management through the purchasing behavior of the fish retail industry rather than through the direct demands of the public. While market demand can influence the way fisheries are managed, there is a need to ensure that the poorer fishing communities are not excluded from these benefits through the cost of certification. It is also necessary to ensure that the increased revenues that certification may bring do not act as an incentive for increased movement into the fishery. The need for a better understanding of how market mechanisms such as eco-labeling and certification work across international market chains was highlighted during expert interviews. The experts noted that the expected premiums to producers from such schemes did not always seem to materialize or were insufficient to cover the con- siderable costs involved in compliance with such mechanisms. UK retailers’ concern over the use of trawler by-catch in fish feed for prawns in Thailand was cited as a specific BOX 22: Certification helps community fishery in Vietnam Ben Tre province in Vietnam worked with government officials to implement management measures in its clam fishery through allocating fishing rights to local cooperatives. This improved management of the clams and attracted the attention of WWF which provided partial funding toward paying for the full Marine Stewardship Council (MSC) assessment of the fishery. In 2009, the fishery received full certification that it was sustainable and well-managed. In total, the MSC certification cost $120,000. Source: MRAG, 2010
  • 84. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 66 example of a situation in which realistic alternatives for feed producers were not always readily available and, when they were, would be likely to incur costs that they were not confident would be recouped through existing certification arrangements. 6.4 Factors affecting community engagement A number of factors relate specifically to the community and the individual fishers themselves. These relate in part to the extent to which fisheries depend upon the coastal fisheries resources for their livelihoods, and what alternatives they have to engage in. Bringing about change in behavior requires understanding where fishers are coming from – what drives them – and from that understanding, building their commitment to change. This requires participation in all levels of decision-making, not just for fishers but for all relevant groups in the community. This participation includes making use of local knowledge systems and people’s ability to analyze and advise on change processes. Understanding dependency The extent to which communities or households depend upon fisheries as a key part of their livelihood strategies will be a significant driver of impact within any fisheries management system. Livelihood dependency on fisheries can take many forms and is often a complex mixture of these. Coastal ecosystems and their associated fisheries resources provide a wide array of ecosystem services (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005), and poor coastal people have quite specific and diverse patterns of dependency on these services (Campbell and Townsley, 2013). Whittingham et al. (2003) describe the forms that de- pendency can take. Some people, households and communities are highly dependent on fisheries resources for all or most of their needs. These needs may take the form of food, income, employment, a resource for reciprocal relations and to demonstrate power, cultural values, protection from the sea (e.g. coral reefs for coastal protection), building materials (e.g. reefs and mangroves), and areas for recreation and social engagement. Some people may depend upon the marine resources at times when land-based activities are less productive. Other people may depend upon the fishery at certain vital times of the seasonal calendar and, while they only spend a small pro- portion of their time involved in fisheries, this may be key to their survival. Yet other people may use fisheries as a safety net to fall back on when times are very hard. This is most prevalent where government social protection programs are not very strong (Bennett, 2005b). Cinner et al. (2010) have shown that poorer households have a greater reliance on fishing for primary subsistence or for income. It is assumed, to an extent, that if other opportunities exist, fishers will leave the fishery and take up those opportunities. This was found to be the case in Cambodia where many of the fishers did not have a long cultural history of fishing (IMM et al., 2003) but not the case in Kenya where fishers have a longer tradition of fishing (Cinner et al., 2010). More indirect forms of dependency also occur when people depend upon fish for pro- cessing and trade, and this can be a very significant part of household income. In
  • 85. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 67 many communities, the income generated through fish sales and wages in the fishery provides a diverse array of local industries that survive because of the fishery (IMM et al., 2005). The management system adopted for fisheries and marine ecosystems must be very aware of the dependency of different stakeholders and how manage- ment arrangements will affect each group. Balancing exclusion, livelihoods alternatives and the local economy All too often, fisheries management is seen as separate from the economic activities that surround it. But the local economy is one of the main drivers of over-exploitation of resources – if fisheries is seen as a business that is more beneficial than other local activities, more people will try to enter the fishery. This is particularly important for the poor who often have limited means to invest in equipment or land and lack the skills to enter other industries. Thus, if people are to be successfully excluded from the fishery, they need to have access to alternative options for their labor and capital that provide as good, or better, returns than fishing. This is often seen as an area of de- velopment that stands outside of fisheries management but, in reality, it is crucial to it. As coastal populations increase and where fisheries’ entry barriers are porous, more people will join the fishery on a full-time, part-time, seasonal or safety-net basis. A key part of fisheries management must ultimately be the decision to allow some people to fish and others to be excluded. If this is to be done equitably, then the different ways in which fishers depend on and use the coastal environment and its ecosystem services will need to be accommodated in the management system. In describing the underpinning rational for the need for closer links of fisheries in the wider economy, Charles and Herrera (1994, 1315) noted “…fisheries of developing regions typically face a trio of key problems: over-exploited stocks, an over-extended fleet and a lack of alternative employment outside of the fishery. In addressing these, the late economist Ian Smith (1981) expressed well a fundamental but oft-neglected reality: to be just, feasible and effective, policies cannot be restricted to resolving one of two of these problems alone.” Charles and Herrera (1994) also discussed the points that Smith made regarding the consequences of not taking all three elements into account, namely: i) inhumane impacts on the fishers, ii) political infeasibility due to community reaction, or iii) failure due to fishers’ non-compliance. Ultimately some people will need to seek alternatives, or at least reduce their depen- dency through a more diversified livelihood portfolio, for some or all of the year. This requires an understanding of how fisheries and the wider economy interact. Graham et al. (2006) noted that “[m]uch has been written about economic development in countries, in regions, and in communities, but little about the connection between community-based fisheries management and economic development.” This is a sig- nificant limitation, given how dependent those in the fisheries are on the wider local and national economy. This economy generates markets for capital and labour that affect investment in fisheries. Community-based fisheries management can be greatly influenced by the economic viability of the surrounding community. Limited diversity of livelihood opportunities are both a factor driving people into fisheries and a barrier to their leaving. As a consequence, in coastal communities where there are few alternatives, more people will join the fishery or will need to
  • 86. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 68 migrate away from their communities. Kuperan and Jahan (2010), for instance, iden- tified a lack of alternatives as a major obstacle to fisheries management in coastal Bangladesh, where population pressure and non-compliance to fisheries regulations is accelerating over-fishing, noting that “the resource can be better managed and the compliance level can be improved if the fisherfolk have other means of generating income to manage their losses for the regulatory measures” (Kuperan and Jahan, 2010, 112). In many coastal fisheries where fishing is seen as the occupation of last resort, this will be very difficult to achieve. As Tobey and Torell (2006, 853) noted, regarding the poor “[w]ithout other income generating options in the near future, the loss of nearshore marine fisheries could lead to a downward spiral of food security, income and vulnerability of rural coastal households.” Providing opportunities for the poor to move out of fisheries permanently, or at least reduce their level of dependency, is also fraught with difficulties, given their multiple deprivations: low income opportunities, weak market power, poor access to land-based resources, weak political access and low inclusion in public services such as health and education. Even under rights-based fisheries, Swan and Gréboval (2005) noted that regulating access and dealing with displaced fishermen are particularly important problems that must be overcome. This emphasized the need to view fisheries within the wider local and national economies. However, for many people involved in fisheries, the household will already support a portfolio of livelihood activities reflecting, e.g. levels of wealth, skill, seasonal op- portunities and available alternative or additional livelihood options (Allison and Ellis, 2001; IMM et al., 2005; Walmsley et al., 2006; Cinner et al., 2010). These will often be linked into the wider aspects of the local economy, and fisheries manage- ment should, ideally, be seen as part of the wider process of community develop- ment (Jentoft, 2000). Understanding fisheries from a livelihoods perspective can be a useful way of understanding dependency and the linkages to the wider community (Ferrol-Schulte et al., 2013). Livelihoods approaches encourage a focus on the con- tribution of fisheries to wider local economic development, with the opportunities in the wider economy providing livelihood alternatives for fishers which might lower the pressure on stocks and improve the livelihoods of those involved. Closer inte- gration of the fisheries economy with the wider local economic development should also assist in shifting the safety net/buffering role that fisheries provide for rural labor (Béné, 2003). Co-management processes in the Philippines have started to move beyond fisheries management issues and started to address wider development, eco-tourism, alterna- tives to fishing and livelihood enhancement (Wilson et al., 2006). This has also been recognized by ICM programs, which cover a much wider part of the economy and need to include a diversity of livelihood opportunities (White et al., 2006). In Tanzania, there are also efforts to promote livelihood diversity (see Box 23), and in South Asia, efforts to develop a systematic approach to sustainable livelihood enhancement and diversification (SLED) have proved successful (Cattermoul et al., 2008).
  • 87. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 69 From studies in Costa Rica on the diversifica- tion of livelihood opportunities for fisheries households, Charles and Herrera (1994) de- termined that the role of livelihood opportu- nities for fisher households may be enhanced by taking a more integrated approach to management which addresses value addition within the sector and by addressing both micro-level (community) and macro-level (industry) changes to alternative livelihood options. The sequencing of the introduction of liveli- hood alternatives is very important (Catter- moul et al., 2008). If restrictions on entry to the fisheries are introduced as part of a fisheries management process before adequate and acceptable alternatives are developed, then fishers are likely to invest in means to circumvent management measures. It is important to develop livelihood opportunities early in the management process. Ideally, these should not be the sorts of opportunities that are only services that rely solely on the income generated by fisheries. This is likely to create a localized “resource curse” situation. The “resource curse” reflects the poor potential of natural resource dependence to generate the economy-wide innovation needed to sustain growth (Collier, 2007; Barbier, 2007). This happens because a large amount of human, physical and financial capital often gets directed at the development of those resources at the expense of the rest of the economy (local or national). The spillover effects of natural resource exploitation tend to be less than those of manufacturing and service sectors, which reduces the diversi- fication effect in the wider economy. This may be particularly pronounced in smaller economies where development resources are few anyway. Small-scale fisheries have the potential to be a “growth pole” in many coastal communities but, all too often, they tend to generate economic activity that perpetuates over-exploitation and dependency on the fishery. In reality, small-scale fisheries are a valuable resource that can lead to economic diversification if used properly. While livelihood diversification is not always a successful approach to shifting pressure from fisheries resources (Tobey and Torell, 2006), there are examples where a par- ticipatory approach which facilitates the selection of livelihood opportunities by the communities themselves, rather than imposed from outside, can work (Cattermoul et al., 2008). Micro-finance is very important to stimulate or facilitate livelihood alterna- tives (Tobey and Torell, 2006), as are wider mechanisms of support such as technical training, market information and development of entrepreneurship skills (Salagrama and Koriya, 2008). Building capacity Fishers and their wider communities have an important role to play in fisheries man- agement, but first they need the skills to understand the management process and the knowledge required of their roles and responsibilities. Good leadership can play an BOX 23: Livelihood diversification In Tanzania, MPAs have used the generation of diversified livelihood options as a way of reducing pressure on resources. Some 19% of male-headed and 16% of female-headed households surveyed have been involved in these activities. Diversified income-generating activities included: agriculture, improved fishing techniques and marketing, apiculture, tree nurseries, rabbit fish cage culture, oyster farming, seaweed farming, and handicrafts such as weaving, . Source: Tobey and Torell, 2006
  • 88. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 70 important part in this but can also distort the outcomes. Building community capacity to participate, engage, share and cooperate can be equally as important. Good leadership of communities and groups seems to be an important ingredient of sound management as does good community cohesion. With an analysis of 130 co- managed fisheries across 44 countries, Guttiérrez et al. (2011) identified strong lead- ership as the most important attribute contributing to success, followed by individual or community quotas, social cohesion and protected areas. However, White et al. (2006) noted the importance of building durable institutions that will be self-sustaining after leadership change. Processes such as ICM are seen as valuable governance mechanisms that can help this and can enhance the local govern- ment leadership role. In his discussion of co-management on the Mekong River in Laos, Baird (1999) mentioned that when solidarity increases through co-management, there may also be other spin-offs such as community development. A counter to good leadership can be dominant elites who look after themselves and their immediate supporters and colleagues. Patronage systems can be seen as powerful allies in management where a village chief or local elite is able to ensure compliance to management by a particular group. Participation in co-management does not always mean community empowerment and, even when the community is more empowered, it does not necessarily mean that such empowerment is even. Local elites may have a vested interest in moving the co-management process in certain directions or in presenting personal choices as those of the wider community. Such patronage is likely to exclude some key stakeholder groups, especially the poorest and most marginalized. This can be particularly damaging when managers or scientists assume a certain degree of homogeneity within communities and that the leader represents different groups fairly. This is particularly so where the effects and impacts of MPAs are being measured, and the exclusion of fishers is likely to have very different effects on different groups of people. Women excluded from gleaning local reefs on foot, for instance, are likely to suffer much more from a local exclusion zone that men with boats who are able to travel further afield. Women may lose not only local access rights but the ability to fish anywhere and the opportunity for social engagement with other women in the community where gleaning is a col- laborative activity. But paradoxically, local elites are essential to providing the leadership and legitimacy of co-management structures and processes (Wilson et al., 2006). NGOs can have a role in reducing the adverse effects of these elites through building rights com- mittees and other transparency mechanisms.6 Civil society more generally has a par- ticular role to play in fisheries management where communities are poorly organized (Jentoft, 2000). The power of such organization can be seen in Box 24. 6 The Hunger Safety Net Programme (HSNP) outlines rights committees in pastoralist communities in Kenya http://www.hsnp.or.ke/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=142%3Arights&catid=34%3Aarticle s&Itemid=1
  • 89. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 71 Rudd et al. (2003) noted that social capital in communities is very important for influenc- ing decision-makers, for building solidarity within communities and for forming bridges among communities. This is important for developing learning networks and sharing ideas. According to Armitage et al. (2009), successful adaptive management calls for clear and identifiable sets of social entities with shared interests. The extent of the community’s ability to organize itself to work within a co-manage- ment arrangement is a significant issue affecting the potential impact of such ar- rangements. Abdullah et al. (1998) found that it can take 3–5 years to develop effective in- stitutions. Wilson et al. (2006) found that many co-management initiatives give the role of building capacity to NGOs operating in the areas. They provided examples in Philip- pines, Cambodia, Laos, Thailand and Bangladesh where capacity was strengthened by NGOs. During expert discussions, participants also highlighted leadership issues as being important at levels above the community, as initiatives for fisheries management or conservation of marine areas have often tended to be highly dependent on specific individuals with the commitment and charisma to encourage wider support for such initiatives, whether in local government, the NGO sector or at higher policy-making levels. They saw this dependence on specific leaders as representing vulnerability, because such individual “champions” are subject to generational change or regular transfer to other locations or fields of work, especially given the long timeframes often involved in fisheries management development. Work in Indonesia within the Coral Triangle Initiative is looking at how more systemic incentives can be created – within schools, higher education and government depart- ments – to encourage people to commit to and engage in marine management issues. The goal is to generate a wider group of leaders of change across generations and institutions who can provide more sustainable leadership for change processes in the long-term. Engaging with fishers’ motives and preferences A key part of working in partnership with fishers in the management process is un- derstanding their motives and preferences. Without this, management assumptions can be well off mark. In addition to understanding dependency of different groups, it is important to un- derstand what drives fishers to do what they do and how they will react to change. BOX 24: Post-cyclone cooperation On India’s Orissa coast, many migrant fishers had coalesced into communities but lacked cohesion and organization. After the Orissa cyclone in 2000, the NGOs providing support insisted that the community organize itself and form groups through which support could be provided. Although it had little previous experience of working in groups, the community discovered the benefits of mutual support and cooperation very quickly. Residents reported that this alone had transformed the way they function as a community and influenced all aspects of their lives. Source: IMM, 2001
  • 90. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 72 Hilborn (1985, cited in Salas and Gaertner, 2004) suggested that the collapse of many fisheries is due to misunderstanding fishers’ behavior rather than a lack of knowledge of fisheries resources. Understanding what motivates fishers is an important part of deciding how to manage a fishery according to Hilborn (2007a), who also noted (2007a, 286) that “… fishermen respond to regulation in ways that often surprised managers, and managers must understand the motivation and incentives for fishermen to under- stand how they respond.” Thecontextinwhichfishersconvertpolicymeasuresintoactionsissubjecttoanumber of influencing factors that can change the course of those actions. These include what their priorities are, their cultural norms and expectations, their perceptions of risk, their relationship with managers and politicians, conflict and cohesion with commu- nities, and beliefs around the sustainability of the resource. In addition, these may differ from those of managers. Salas and Gaertner (2004, 154) recognized this when they said: “…fishers develop and implement strategies and tactics in response to the constraints they encounter and their intended objectives given their particular human, social, cultural and economic contexts. Managers in contrast, have generally made simplistic assumptions about fishers’ nature and attitudes when defining management policies.” This can be very important in a management context. As Hilborn (2007a, 290) noted: “[f]isheries management works much better when there is good coopera- tion between managers, scientists and the fishing fleets …” This cooperation depends on people understanding where each is coming from. Understanding and responding to the motives of fishers is not straightforward. In an attempt to counter the potential effects of a change in community attitudes about MPAs, the Philippine government introduced the National Integrated Protected Areas Systems (NIPAS) to replace community-based management with national government direction. It did so because it feared the community might choose to turn its back on conservation objectives and exploit the MPA for economic benefit. This has report- edly generated much resentment within the communities and reduced effectiveness of the MPA (Hind et al., 2010). In many fishing communities, there is a tendency for boys and girls to follow in their parents’ footsteps and join the sector. In some more traditional communities, fishing may be seen as a right or an obligation as a career. This can influence people’s in- clination to leave the fishery or not join the sector. This is not true in all situations, especially where fishers are part-time or seasonal operators. Where viable alterna- tives offer better benefits, those people will generally take them up. However, many fisheries people have few other skills and knowledge, which may make leaving much more difficult for them. Fishers are apt to view resources in terms of their time preferences or the way they discount future benefits in current prices. People who have high discount rates favor current gains much more than the same gain in the future. Time preference influences the behavior of fishers, as well as those people making policy and those implementing it. For politicians the time horizons are generally short – 2 to 6 years (Sutinen, 2010) – because of the time between elections. The time preference for donor agencies can be even shorter, leading to substantial distortions of policy as their funding priori-
  • 91. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 73 ties fluctuate in a given sector or policy area. Longer-term considerations are often less important to them than short-term gains. This can become a significant problem because when major institutional reform is needed for fisheries management change, it may take many years. After reviewing the legal requirements for community- based fisheries management in the Pacific, Kuemlangan (2004, 32) noted that “[a]ny external programme for assistance (for CBFM) should be for a longer term duration than normal technical assistance or development projects.” This is not only required to address community-level institution building but also to build government under- standing of the benefits of CBFM and to facilitate the necessary policy and legislative changes. Fishers also often focus on the short-term. In open access fisheries, where fishers have no secure claim over future outcomes from the fishery, they are encouraged to reap the benefits quickly before others do. There are also uncertainties about future fisheries policy, markets and fish stocks. Poor people also sometimes have shorter time horizons because they discount benefits at higher rates suggesting a lesser com- mitment to environmental management (Holden et al., 1998). In Tanzania, Tobey and Torell (2006) found that poverty may be a limiting factor to conservation efforts, in that poverty often forces people to engage in destructive practices. If the time preferences of managers and fishers are very different, then giving fishers or local communities the rights to harvest fish resources may not always generate the expected results. For example, rights do not necessarily confer a commitment to sustainability. As Bromley (2009, 282) noted, “if the ‘time preference’ of a private owner is such that income now trumps income in the future, then private owners will be quite intent on liquidating (destroying) a renewable natural resource in order to spend the proceeds or invest them elsewhere.” Investing current catches in your child’s education may seem like a good investment even if it destroys future stocks. It is also worth noting that the motivations and preferences of fishers are dynamic and constantly changing in response to their surrounding social and economic envi- ronment. Experience in India indicated how a combination of people’s perceptions of the increasing competition for fisheries resources, exposure to outside ideas (in this case during the post-tsunami relief efforts after 2004), improved communications and access to education had led, over the course of a generation, to a significant change in the attitudes of many fishers in South India regarding the future of fisheries and their desire for their children to enter the fishery in the future (Townsley et al., 2011). Understanding these different motives is important for ensuring that fisheries man- agement systems accommodate them and work with them. Addressing commitment, compliance, conflict and enforcement The enforcement of regulations represents a large part of the cost of any management process. This can be very high where fishers must be forced to comply with regula- tions rather than where they have a commitment to those regulations. Moving from compliance to commitment can be an important step in increasing management’s ef- fectiveness and reducing its cost.
  • 92. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 74 Rights imply an entitlement which is generally supported in law. With those rights are responsibilities which often require the sustainable use of the resources. Enforcement involves both protecting those rights and ensuring that rights holders adhere to their responsibilities. In traditional fisheries, the enforcement of rights and responsibilities were often controlled by traditional authorities. The importance of these institutions should not be underestimated. As Jentoft (2000) noted, if the community disintegrates socially or morally, it becomes a threat to fish stocks. In many developing countries that have introduced more formal and centralized licensing systems, the enforcement of regulations has become more difficult with many vessels operating from many small landing sites. In many small-scale developing fisheries, the government lacks the funds to implement effective enforcement (Arthur, 2005). Non-compliance to fisheries regulations undermines the effectiveness of manage- ment measures and is a major problem in most fisheries. In their review of compli- ance in the coastal fisheries in Bangladesh, Kuperan and Jahan (2010) recommended examining the level and causes of non-compliance and exploring policies for encour- aging or securing compliance because, at that moment, the chances of detection and conviction in fisheries rule breaking in coastal Bangladesh were reported to be virtually nil. One solution to the compliance issue, suggested by Kuperan and Jahan (2010), called for moving towards co-management in fisheries where the additional transparency of the approach would support greater compliance. Unless there is commitment to the operation of management measures, there are likely to be difficulties in getting compliance. For example, Christie and White (2007) found that MPAs were one of the preferred coral reef fisheries management measures – covering (at the time) 18.7 percent of the world’s reef. Yet less than 0.01 percent of coral reefs were within no-take zones, with no poaching and at low risk. This suggested considerable lack of adherence to the rules. Rules not only need the legal framework to enforce them and the political will to implement enforcement but also legitimacy in the eyes of the fishers. Furthermore, legitimacy should also be in the eyes of wider society, but these forms of legitimacy can sometimes conflict (Jentoft, 2000). The use of graduated sanctions is seen as important in resource management systems (Ostrom, 2009b), particularly in relation to rights, as well as very important to the success of fisheries management. However, all too often, this is missing, especially in countries where the rule of law is not well established. According to Christie and White (2006), lack of clear tenure rules can undermine MPAs, and fair and effective law enforcement, knowledge of the law, and consistency between national and local laws and institutional goals are important to MPA effectiveness. In-migration and conflicts outside of the community often require the government to intervene to resolve disputes (Wilson et al., 2006). Where communities are more homogeneous, co-management seems to work better. Francis and Bryceson (2001, 94) noted that “[c]onflicts of interest can be resolved or avoided by fair processes respecting coastal communities’ systems of land/sea tenure and common property rights.” Andrade and Rhodes (2012) implemented a meta-analysis of 55 published studies to understand the key factors that lead to community compliance with protected area
  • 93. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 75 (PA) regulations. These included: • establishing cooperative relationship among all stakeholders • building relationships on voluntary compliance rather than draconian enforce- ment • promoting enforcement through participatory decision-making • setting rules that are clear and easy to understand • setting internal and external boundaries that are well defined and recognized by resource used and officials • ensuring well trained, equipped and motivated personnel • determining penalties and applying and enforcing them consistently. Fisheries management works best if there is good cooperation among the fishers, managers and scientists (Hilborn, 2007a), which enables the beginning of a shift from mere compliance with regulation to a sense of commitment to making the fishery work. As Bennett (2005b) noted, when fishers believe a stock needs sup- porting, they will agree to limit effort. A key part of the move towards effective man- agement must be a move from fishers’ coerced compliance to management regula- tion towards one where fishers are committed to the success of the management measures. Otherwise, there will be need to spend large amounts of funds and effort to ensure compliance, which is unlikely to be achieved in developing countries that have financial constraints. Understanding what incentivizes fishers is central to that process (Hilborn, 2007a). Ensuring participation and inclusion A part of generating compliance and commitment is building support for the manage- ment process, which requires involving fishers and their communities in the decision- making process. This means bringing in a much wider group than just the fishers because, in most communities, the whole local economy is closely linked to fishing and decisions are likely to have far reaching effects. The quality of that participation is also very important. Extractive participation – meaning the community is mined for its knowledge and consent – is likely to be less effective than where participation is more collegial (Campbell and Salagrama, 2001). Participation of fishers in management decisions and processes that affect their lives and livelihoods is important for several reasons. It generates buy-in and support for the process, it empowers communities, it incorporates local knowledge and ex- perience, and it can reduce costs. Recognizing that communities are not made up of people who all have the same needs and wants is key to effective participation (Bennett, undated). Andrade and Rhodes (2012) found that compliance is driven primarily by local in- volvement in the protected areas’ decision-making processes. This is because those decisions are likely to impact upon the livelihoods of people in adjacent communi- ties. Many protected areas around the world have been developed using exclusion- ary top-down methods and, as such, failed to consider other important issues such as social, cultural and political concerns. Opponents of no-take MPAs consider that such measures have failed largely because they have been imposed on fishermen, and they argue for the assignation of property rights to fish stocks and co-management
  • 94. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 76 through the greater involvement of fishermen in decision-making processes (Jones, 2007). The effects of exclusion of fishers from MPAs will have effects and impacts that are determined in part by the size of the enclosed area relative to the non-enclosed. MPAs that force the same number of fishers to catch from a smaller area are in danger of increasing over-exploitation in the areas outside the MPA at a much faster rate. Respect for participation and inclusion is seen across the literature. Allison (2011, 11) found that “[o]nly meaningful engagement with and deliberation amongst stake- holders can yield goals that will be seen as legitimate.” Similarly, Hall and Mainprize (2004) said that while it may not be possible to get complete agreement on the aims and potential outcomes of fisheries management, it is important that the views of all be heard. Aswani and Weiant (2004) noted that when local communities are excluded from protected area management systems, and their needs and aspirations are ignored, it becomes very difficult to enforce conservation policies. Andrade and Rhodes (2012) also noted that while the cost of patrolling big protected areas can be reduced by in- volvement of local people in patrolling and management, such stewardship will only take place if local communities feel included in the decision-making process. While biodiversity conservation may be achieved in the short-term, marginalizing participa- tion in decision-making, not engaging in capacity building, not enhancing governance processes or enforcing regulations fairly is likely to lead to biodiversity loss in the long-term. In addition there seems to be a growing recognition that stakeholder par- ticipation needs to be sought throughout the monitoring and adaptive management process, not just in initial planning, given the limited knowledge of how ecosystems function (Arkema et al., 2006). In relation to community-based natural resources management (CBNRM) in general, Roe et al. (2009) pointed out that, to be successful, it must prioritize local interests, agency and capacity. Bell et al. (2006) noted that in China, if the state took over stock enhancement programs, they tended to fail because it was difficult to see who should pay for the benefits, while those operated by local fishermen worked much better. The role of women in decision-making around fisheries management should not be forgotten (Bennett, 2005a). While women may play a smaller role than men in fish harvesting in most countries, their role in fish processing and trade is vital. Fisheries management measures can influence how much fish is landed, what sort of fish is landed, where it is landed, when it is landed and the condition in which it is landed. A recent study of women fish traders in Cambodia found that changes in the market for fish had changed significantly over an eight-year period, demonstrating the dynamic nature of the fish trade process (Asian Fisheries Society, 2013). Such changes can be driven by the fishery itself or by outside forces, but they can radically change the interface between fisheries management and fisheries trade. All of these characteristics affect fish processors and traders, but can be dealt with quite differently by men and women, the poor and the wealthy, those who are able to travel and those who are restricted to the village for religious or family reasons (see Box 25). Alpízar (2006) noted that the quality of participation is very important. This begs the question: who will be involved, how are they selected and what role will they take?
  • 95. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 77 The degrees of participation of small-scale fishers in fisheries research were reviewed by Campbell and Salagrama (2001) who noted the important and valuable role that fishers can play in research but also the limitation of such practice. Charles et al. (2009, 178) noted that participatory research and community-based management “have consid- erable, yet often unrealized, potential in coastal fisheries of the world. They are, to a great extent, two sides of the same coin. In thinking about participatory research, we envision the building of a co-learning environment that is empowering for all participants…” DFID’s Fisheries Management Science Programme identified the role that fishers can play in stock assessment work and how feedback from that process improved management decision-mak- ing (Howard and Arthur, 2005). Jentoft (2000) recognized the relationship between community and fisheries management as fundamental. Fishers are often born in and live in communities, and are enmeshed in the social and cultural structures and processes. If the management systems exclude the community, there is a danger that the fishers will act in their own interests only and ignore those of wider society. This role of the community will be important both in the design and implementation of fisheries man- agement plans. However, Van Tuyen et al. (2010) noted that the livelihoods of coastal people in Vietnam are often in a state of flux (as they are in most places) adding to the complexity of planning and management in fisheries. They suggested that there is “growing recognition among authorities of the value of engaging local fishers and fish farmers in participatory process to resolve complex livelihood challenges, and the development of local management bodies (newly formed Fishing Associations) as a basis for emerging co-management of aquatic resources” (Van Tuyen et al., 2010, 327). However, as Belsky (2000) noted, we should be careful not to replace a more top-down theory of conservation with another where we assume that rural communities are “ecological noble communities” or make them central to every conservation effort. This is reiterated by Alpízar (2006) who pointed out that communities are heteroge- neous and multidimensional, so conflicts, divisions and inequalities are likely to exist, and decisions are not always going to be environmentally benign. Belsky (2000) also found that not all communities have the necessary skills, governance and social struc- tures to enable management to occur, that a focus on community management takes the focus off the role of multi-nationals, international treaties and institutions, and that those in control of conservation policy often do not have a strong understanding of how communities work. In relation to reef decline, Whittingham et al. (2003, 52) noted that “… participation is not a panacea to ensure that interventions succeed in preventing reef decline and assuring sustainable reef benefits for poor stakeholders.” Other key elements include: i) when participation occurs in the management process, BOX 25: Factors influencing fish processors in India Increased capitalization of the India coastal fisheries has had a generally positive effect on the fishers although future catches are more vulnerable to overexploitation. However, increased landings into fewer ports has adversely affected many of the small-scale processors and traders. Centralization of landings has affected access to landed fish processing practices (especially the increased use of ice) and fish market opportunities. These have had knock-on effects on fishers’ household incomes. Source: IMM and ICM, 2003
  • 96. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 78 ii) how it is sustained, iii) the equitability of the participation process, iv) the extent to which the poorer and other marginalized groups are included and v) how systems of patronage are included. People also need to be included in understanding the need for change. In relation to ICM in the Philippines, White et al. (2006, 299) noted that “[p]roviding effective feedback on biological and socioeconomic information and quantitative indicators on fisheries and habitats as a result of effective management contributes to the under- standing of why ICM is needed.” An important element of inclusion often omitted from fisheries management discus- sions is that of poverty. Where do the poor fit into fisheries management systems? Walmsley et al. (2006) expressed that fisheries is often poorly addressed in national poverty reduction strategies. In addition, because of their often marginalized positions, the poor are often excluded from fisheries management systems. Linking different knowledge management systems A key element of participation and building commitment is recognizing the value of local ecological knowledge and the experience-based knowledge of local fishers. All too often, fishers are regarded as ignorant and their traditional knowledge as inferior to that generated by more formal knowledge systems, which has often proved incorrect. There is a growing awareness of the value of these informal knowledge systems in fisheries management. Knowledge management can be thought of as being composed of three components: i) generating knowledge, ii) sharing knowledge and iii) using knowledge. Even though knowledge is often considered that which is generated through formal science, fisher societies have both traditional knowledge that is transferred between generations with its roots in history, and experience-based knowledge which comes from working in the sector. Many fishers have profoundly detailed knowledge of their environment, the species of fish they target, changes in the waters they fish and its navigation, the seasons which influence their fishing and the techniques which preserve fish (see, for instance, von Brandt, 1972; Johannes, 1981; and Worsley, 1997 cited in Campbell and Salagrama, 2001). Customary marine tenure systems are often underpinned by the existence, value and application of traditional ecological knowledge to management (see: Christy, 1982; Ruddle and Johannes, 1985; Scudder and Connelly, 1985; Cordell, 1989; and Johannes, 1981 cited in Campbell and Salagrama, 2001). Berkes et al. (2000) discussed the importance of traditional ecological knowledge and acknowledged the similarity between such knowledge-based systems and adaptive management. Francis and Bryceson (2001, 94) researching the situation in the coast of Tanzania noted that “[b]oth traditional and scientific knowledge systems of coastal ecology and ecosystem management exist, but there are many gaps and there is a need for much improved dialogue and mutual respect between these knowledge systems.”
  • 97. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 79 In all aspects of knowledge management, a more collaborative approach is emerging as a key mechanism for shared understanding and decision-making in governance and policy processes more generally. The greater use of indigenous knowledge in fisheries management is a case in point. In fisheries research, participatory approach- es to knowledge generation through all stages of the research cycle are becoming more prevalent (Campbell and Salagrama, 2001). Wilson et al. (2006) expressed that experience-based knowledge of fishers can be very useful for fisheries management. In the UK, the government’s recent (2010–2013) process for the identification of marine conservation areas involved a very significant consultation and engagement with a wide array of stakeholders including fishers, sports divers, boat operators and conservation specialists. This was supported by marine scientists and policy makers. The extent and relevance of indigenous knowledge to fisheries is clearly demonstrat- ed in Johannes’ (1981) work among island communities in the Pacific. The expert discussions generally found consensus that local knowledge and experi- ence offer a crucial contribution to the knowledge base required for effective fisheries management. However there was less clarity regarding how this could be married with scientific knowledge. Some respondents, for example, were skeptical regarding the reliability of purely community-based mechanisms for monitoring and evaluat- ing the impacts of management, particularly on the ecosystem and its functioning. Inputs by trained scientists were seen as indispensable in some fields. Others felt strongly that a large proportion of key information-gathering roles could be taken on by resource users themselves, and that this could represent an important cost-saving mechanism while also contributing to building local commitment and engagement in the whole process. However, even when new knowledge is shared, it often is not used to inform policy and policy implementation. The work done through the Global Environment Facility (GEF) on its Large Marine Ecosystem projects, for instance, has generated a large amount of information about the biophysical, socio-economic, fisheries and gover- nance aspects of marine management. However GEF is reported to have been less enthusiastic about funding improved practice, new management actions and pro- tection of priority sites, according to Bensted-Smith and Kirkman (2010), who also noted that “[o]verall, the LME approach is a powerful generator of information and financial resources and promotes transboundary cooperation but we suggest that, in a developing country context, GEF and LME proponents should redirect emphasis and resources from natural sciences to effective, sustainable governance” (2010, iii). Mutual respect for, and trust in, different knowledge systems can take several decades to develop (Armitage et al., 2012). Without trust, the incentive to commit to management regimes based upon shared knowledge can be lost (Campbell and Cat- termoul, 2009). The incorporation of local knowledge into policy-making processes is becoming more common in fisheries management, as is sharing more formal sources of knowledge within communities in ways that can be understood and used.
  • 99. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 81 7 7. Discussion, conclusions and ways forward 7.1 Discussion A large body of literature, both peer reviewed and institutional reports, covers the area of small-scale fisheries management. This synthesis reviews a small proportion of those to provide an understanding of the existing knowledge field. The emphasis of the study has been on “reviewing reviews” of experiences in the field, as much of the literature stands one step removed from the field itself. As a consequence, the synthesis represents the findings and opinions of thought leaders in the field who have assessed the evidence, cross referenced by discussion with some 20 key infor- mants across the field. There was widespread agreement that the fisheries sector is very important to global food and nutrition, to livelihoods, to foreign exchange earnings, to local community development and as a safety net for the poor. It was also agreed that fisheries are in a fairly poor state with most over-capitalized and many over-exploited. But there was also a sense of optimism that this could be turned around and that there were already signs of hope that this was being achieved. A number of major themes in fisheries management that hold center stage in the discussions tend to focus on the degree of emphasis placed on different aims. Yield maximization, conservation, economic maximization and social policy are all entry points into fisheries management that color the focus of the management efforts. In- creasingly, however, there is recognition of the need to balance these different themes and to look at fisheries management much more holistically. This holistic approach brings recognition of the complex nature of fisheries manage- ment that is changing in the face of globalized markets and climate change. It is that complexity which needs to be embraced through much more integrated approaches to management that work across different scales and levels. This requires horizontal integration into the wider economy at local, national and global levels, and vertical
  • 100. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 82 integration to link the local fisheries situation to wider concerns of migratory stocks, cross-boundary effects, water pollution, IUU fishing and global markets. There is also recognition that there is no “silver bullet”, no universal answer for all the problems of fisheries. Each situation is ecologically, socially, economically, cul- turally and politically different. Local context is very important, particularly as more holistic approaches are adopted. The aims and objectives of different stakeholders and the local context will differ, making the definition of revitalized fisheries different in different locations. However, there does appear to be considerable support for the idea that a number of factors influence success in a number of locations around the globe. There is also a growing consensus of the need to use a combination of these factors to set a general trend of improvement in motion. An important element in this consensus is that the process by which fisheries man- agement is developed and implemented is more important than the specific measures through which it is implemented. In part, this is dictated by the fact that the timeframes involved in bringing about change in the way fisheries and marine ecosystems are managed are long, which means that the process by which stakeholders, institutions and decision-making mechanisms are engaged over time needs careful attention. Col- laborative approaches seem to play an important role in such processes, but the exact roles played by government, the community, community representatives, NGOs and the private sector will tend to vary according to context and the stage of development of the process itself. The way the management process develops will also depend very much on the broader context of governance, subsidiarity, institutional capacity and fit, rights to resources, the legal framework, inclusiveness and scale, and it will be influ- enced strongly by the prevailing political economy in different locations. Ensuring the long-term viability of the resource and the wider ecosystem was generally accepted as a key element, but one which needs to be balanced by other concerns around the ability of stakeholders, particularly the poor, to respond to change and around how benefits from protected ecosystem services might be distributed. It was also clear that adaptation to change is likely to play a larger part in fisheries man- agement in the future – climate change is introducing uncertainty that needs to be incorporated into the planning process. There was considerable support for the use of more adaptive approaches to respond to change and to build greater resilience in com- munities. Given both the level of change in the management process and the change in the fishery itself, it was felt that fisheries management needs to be introduced in- crementally, as this approach allows adaptation in policy, policy implementation and community structures and processes. However, creating the capacity at all levels – within policy mechanisms, communities and agencies – to work in an adaptive fashion is itself a challenge for which they require support and assistance. This suggests that introducing and establishing major shifts in the management process will not occur quickly in most situations. A long-term commitment by funders to this change process will be necessary, requiring more sustainable funding mecha- nisms to be identified and put in place without further adding to the subsidies to the sector. Improved market chains have a role to play in improving the benefit flows to fishers, but will require sequencing.
  • 101. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 83 There was also widespread recognition that greater inclusion of fishers and their communities in the decision-making process is key. This builds on recognition of the importance of rights and responsibilities at all levels, and goes beyond the inclusion of fisher’s representatives in the form of local elites. It recognizes that fishers are a disparate group of people who depend upon fisheries in quite different ways. It also recognizes that other members of coastal communities are affected by how fisheries management is conducted. Women in their roles as fish processors and traders are greatly influenced by management decisions. Children are affected by future em- ployment opportunities. The wider society is affected by the benefits that flow from fisheries into the local economy. Ultimately, fisheries management decisions will involve some people being included in the right to fish and some being excluded. Those excluded may be current fishers or future generations who may wish to join the fishery. Those who are excluded will need alternative livelihood options, otherwise they are likely to become impoverished or will try to circumvent entry regulations. Fisheries are generally closely linked to the local economy in which they operate, and ensuring that they become a vital part of local economic development is essential. Getting the balance right between exclusion, alternative livelihoods and linkages with the local economy will be very important to the sustainable and equitable development of small-scale fisheries. Embedding fisheries management into the wider context of the local economy is essential if the livelihoods of the poor are to be enhanced. It will also be important to get the sequencing of decisions around controls over entry, market chain development and livelihood alternatives right. Introducing im- provements in market chains before the rights to fish are established will encourage movement into the fishery. Restricting entry to the fishery before alternative invest- ment and labor opportunities are established can push the poor into a state of despera- tion. There was considerable concern about getting the motives of fishers in line with those of managers and recognizing the importance of different time frames for management decisions. Given differences between people, there would likely be conflicts and viola- tions of regulation that would need good enforcement, sound leadership, community cohesion and a greater sense of commitment to the management process. This again requires support for capacity building at the community level and building a sense of trust among the different players. A shared recognition of the value of formal and informal knowledge systems would provide a basis for starting to build that trust. 7.2 Conclusions It is clear from this work that there is no simple universal cure for the problems that face small-scale coastal fisheries. These fisheries are complex, confused and difficult to deal with, as well as locally specific. However, this does not mean that fisheries cannot achieve a much more balanced equitable and sustainable trajectory into the future. The 20 factors identified in this synthesis could help achieve this – when combined into a process for change. There are doubtless others that would emerge from a more comprehensive study.
  • 102. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 84 There is much that needs to be done to celebrate the areas of success that have been achieved so far but also to recognize that widespread success will take a considerable number of years, substantial financial support and a commitment to building capacity at all levels. Lessons can be learned from outside of small-scale coastal fisheries, such as those that have emerged from inland fisheries, such as Bangladesh and Cambodia where co-management systems are well developed. There also have been lessons from other resource management systems such as forestry, livestock and game which have parallels with fisheries. An approach to fisheries management which seeks examples and solutions beyond fisheries is likely to generate more useful approaches. Efforts to distill these different factors into principles for management began with the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries. The specific needs of small-scale fisheries that go beyond the Code have been progressively recognized and FAO is currently producing a draft International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small- Scale Fisheries to address many of the emerging issues associated with fisheries man- agement. These Guidelines are intended to enhance the contribution of small-scale fisheries to poverty alleviation, food security and economic growth. An important development in fisheries management is the greater interest in operating at higher scales as well as the community levels. Regional recognition of, and support for, good practice creates normative pressure for others to adopt. Learning networks around fisheries and marine ecosystem management are important in supporting the exchange of positive experience. While the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries has not been universally applied, it has become a standard against which practice is measured. The proposed Guidelines have the potential to go much further but will need time, commitment and financial support to achieve this potential. 7.3 Ways forward There is much that can be done to bring the successful experiences of different fisheries together into a more coherent and consistent process – a process supported by tools and mechanisms and learning materials that will facilitate a more incremen- tal but more coordinated approach to management change. This would need to be done on an iterative basis where experience and learning is shared through networks and exchanges, particularly in the face of climate change where so much remains unknown. The evolving FAO International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-Scale Fisheries provides a framework for moving more equitable and sustainable fisheries forward. This is still being developed and needs to be piloted to enable the different tools and mechanisms for implementation to be developed. In addition, as this report has shown, there are knowledge gaps in the process that should be given consideration for future work, investment or development in the sector, such as: how to combine these success factors into an effective process; to what extent will they complement or conflict with one another; how can the appro-
  • 103. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 85 priateness of different elements in the fisheries management process for different locations be assessed and understood; what form would adaptive planning take to address fisheries management in a rapidly changing marine environment; how can we generate revenues from small-scale coastal fisheries that will fund local man- agement initiatives, create alternative investment and livelihood opportunities, and stimulate the wider local economy; how do we get the sequencing of interventions right for different stakeholder groups; and how do we ensure long-term funding for the process?
  • 104. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 86 References Abdullah, N.M.R & Pomeroy, R.S. (1998) Transaction Costs and Fisheries Co-Man- agement. Marine Resource Economics, 13: 103-114. Acheson et al. (1998 cited in Berkes et al., 2000, Acheson, J. M., Wilson J. A. & Steneck R. S. 1998) Managing chaotic fisheries. Pages 390-413 in F Berkes & C. Folke, eds. Linking social and ecological systems: management practices and social mechanisms for building resilience. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Alban, F., Boncoeur, J. & Roncin N. (2011) Socio-Economy – Assessing the Impact of Marine protected Areas on Society’s well-being: An economic perspective. In J. Claudet, ed. Marine Protected Areas: A Multidisciplinary Approach. Cambridge University Press. Allen, C.R. & Gunderson, L.H. (2011) Pathology and failure in the design and imple- mentation of adaptive management. Journal of Environmental Management, 92: 1379-1384. Allison E. (2011) Aquaculture, Fisheries, Poverty and Food Security. WorldFish Center, Working Paper 2011-65. Penang. Allison, E. H. & Ellis, F. (2001) The Livelihoods Approach and Management of Small- scale Fisheries. Marine Policy 2001, 25: 377-88. Alongi, D.M. (2002) Present state and future of the world’s mangrove forests. Envi- ronmental Conservation, 29(3): 331-349. Alpízar, M.A.Q. (2006) Participation and fisheries management in Costa Rica: From theory to practice. Marine Policy, 30: 641-650. Anderson T.L. & Libecap G.D. (2010) The Allocation and Dissipation of Resource Rents: Implications for Fishery Reform. In D. Leal, ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Department, the World Bank. Andrade, G.S.M & Rhodes, J.R. (2012) Protected Areas and Local Communities: An Inevitable Partnership toward Successful Conservation Strategies? Ecology and Society, 17(4): 14. Arias Schreiber, M. & Halliday, A. (2013). Uncommon among the commons? Dis- entangling the sustainability of the Peruvian anchovy fishery. Ecology and Society, 18(2): 12 (available at http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-05319-180212). Arkema, K.K., Abramson, S.C. & Dewsbury, B.M. (2006) Marine ecosystem-based management: From characterization to implementation. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 4: 525-532. Armitage, D.R., Plummer, R., Berkes, F., Arthur, R.I., Charles, A.T., Davidson-Hunt, I.J. et al. (2009) Adaptive co-management for social-ecological complexity. Frontiers in Ecology and Environment, 7(2): 95-102.
  • 105. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 87 Armitage, D., de Loe, R. & Plummer, R. (2012) Environmental governance and its implications for conservation practice. Conservation Letters, 5(4): 245-255. Arthur, R.I. (2005) Co-management: a synthesis of the lessons learned from the DFID Fisheries Management Science Programme. MRAG Ltd. London (available at: http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/pdf/outputs/R8470d.pdf). Asian Fisheries Society (2013) Gender and Change In the Spotlight: Report on the 4th Global Symposium on Gender in Aquaculture and Fisheries. 1-3 May 2013, Yeosu, Korea. Aswani, S. & Weiant, P. (2004) Scientific evaluation in women’s participatory manage- ment: Monitoring marine invertebrate refugia in the Solomon Islands. Human Organization, 63(3): 301-319. Baird, I.G. (1999) Towards Sustainable Co-Management of Mekong River Inland aquatic resources, including fisheries. In Proceedings of the international workshop on fisheries co-management, Penang, Malaysia, 23-29 August, 1999. Barbier E. (2007) Natural Resources and Economic Development. Cambridge Univer- sity Press. Baticados. D.B (2004) Fishing cooperatives’ participation in managing nearshore resources: the case in Capiz, central Philippines. Fisheries Research, 67: 81-91. Bellamy, J.A., Walker, D.H., McDonald, G.T. & Syme, G.J. (2001) A systems approach to the evaluation of natural resource management initiatives. Journal of Environ- mental Management, 63(4): 407-423. Belsky, J.M. (2000) Changing human relationships with nature: Making and remaking wilderness science. In D.N. Cole, S.F.McCool, W. Freimund. & J. Oloughlin, eds. Wilderness Science in a Time of Change Conference, Vol 1: Changing Perspectives and Future Directions. 1999 May 23–27, Missoula, MT. Proceedings RMRS-P- 15-VOL-1. Ogden, Utah: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Research Station. Bene, C., Hersoug, B. & Allison, E.H. (2010) Not by Rent Alone: Analysing the Pro-Poor Functions of Small-Scale Fisheries in Developing Countries. Develop- ment Policy Review, 28(3): 325-358. Bene, C. & Neiland, A.E. (2003) Fisheries development issues and their impacts on the livelihoods of fishing communities in West-Africa: An overview. Journal of Food Agriculture and Environment, 1(1): 123-134. Bennett, E. (2005a) Gender, Fisheries and Development. Marine Policy 29, 451-459. Bennett, E. (2005b) Success in Fisheries Management: A review of the literature. In S. Cunningham & T. Bostock, eds. Successful Fisheries Management: Issues, case studies and perspectives. SIFAR/World Bank Study. Eburon Academic Publishers, The Hague. Bennett (undated). The Challenges of Managing Small Scale Fisheries in West Africa. In The Management of Conflict in Tropical Fisheries (R7334) Final Technical Report.
  • 106. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 88 Bensted-Smith, R. & Kirkman, H. (2010) Comparison of Approaches to Management of Large Marine Areas. 144 pp. Publ. Fauna & Flora International, Cambridge, UK, and Conservation International, Washington, DC. Berkes, F., Mahon, R., McConney, P., Pollnac, R. & Pomeroy, R. (2001) Managing Small-scale Fisheries: Alternative directions and methods. IDRC. Berkes, F. (2006) From Community-Based Resource Management to Complex Systems: The Scale Issue and Marine Commons. Ecology and Society, 11(1): 45. Berkes, F. (2008) Community conserved areas: policy issues in historic and contem- porary context. Conservation Letters, 2: 19-24. Berkes, F., Colding, J. & Folke, C. (2000) Rediscovery of traditional ecological knowledge as adaptive management. Ecological Applications, 10(5): 1251-1262. Berkstrom, C., Gullstrom, M., Lingborg, R., Mwandya, A.W., Yahya, S.A.S., Kautsky, N. & Nystrom, M. (2012) Exploring ‘knowns’ and ‘unknowns’ in tropical seascape connectivity with insights from East African coral reefs. Estuarine Coastal and Shelf Science, 107: 1-21. Blaikie, P., Cannon, T., Davis, I. & Wisner, B. (1994) At Risk: Natural Hazards, People’s Vulnerability and Disasters. Routledge. Bromley, D.W. (2009) Abdicating Responsibility: The Deceits of Fisheries Policy. Fisheries, 34(6): 280-302. Bryant, D., Burke, L., McManus, J. & Spalding, M. (1998) Reefs at Risk: A map-based indicator of threats to the World’s Coral Reefs. A joint report by WRI, ICLARM, WCMC & UNEP published by WRI. Burke, L., Reytar, K., Spalding, M. & Perry, A. (2011) Reefs at Risk Revisited, 130. World Resources Institute: Washington, DC. Campbell, J. (1996) Participatory and Integrated Policy: A field guide for policy formu- lation in small-scale fisheries. IMM Ltd, UK. Campbell, J, & Beardmore, J.A. (2001) Poverty and aquatic biodiversity. In: J. Saunders. ed. Living off biodiversity: exploring livelihoods and biodiversity issues in natural resources management. International Institute for Environment and De- velopment, London, 191–229. Campbell, J. & Cattermoul, B. (2009) The Socio-economic Impacts of Fisheries Man- agement and Policy Designed to Achieve Biodiversity Conservation. Report for the Tubney Charitable Trust, Reading, UK (available at http://www.tubney.org. uk/The%20Socio-economic%20Impacts%20of%20Fisheries%20Management%20 and%20Policy.pdf). Campbell, J. & Salagrama, V. (2001) New Approaches to Participation in Fisheries Research. FAO Fisheries Circular no. 965, FIPL/C965. FAO, Rome. Campbell, J. & Townsley, P. (2013) Biodiversity and Poverty in Coastal Environments, in Biodiversity Conservation and Poverty Alleviation: Exploring the Evidence for a Link. Roe, D., Elliott, J., Sandbrook, C. & Walpole, M., eds. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd, Chichester, UK.
  • 107. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 89 Campbell, J., Whittingham, E. & Townsley, P. (2006) Responding to Coastal Poverty: Should We be Doing Things Differently or Doing Different Things? In Hoanh, C.T., Tuong, T.P., Gowing, J.W. & Hardy, B., eds. Environment and Livelihoods in Tropical Coastal Zones. CAB International, London. Cattermoul, B., Townsley, P. & Campbell, J. (2008) Sustainable Livelihoods En- hancement and Diversification (SLED): A Manual for Practitioners. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland and Colombo, Sri Lanka; CORDIO, Kalmar, Sweden; & ICRAN, Cambridge, UK (available at http://www.imm.uk.com/PS/Main. aspx?projectid=22cbb689-4e26-41f2-9077-48ee89ef4de3). CFDO & IMM (2004) PRIAC Policy Reform Impact Assessment Cambodia: Impacts of the fisheries policy reforms in Kampong Cham, Pursat & Takeo Provinces. First Round Assessment Report. Department of Fisheries, Cambodia (available at http://www.imm.uk.com/PS/Main.aspx?projectid=7c00d7a5-81d2-4821-a1e9- 5be6dc302b48). Charles, A.T. & Herrera, A. (1994) Development and Diversification: Sustainability Strategies for a Costa Rican Fishing Cooperative. In M. Antona, J. Catanzano & J.G. Sutinen, eds. Proceedings of the 6th Conference of the International Institute of Fisheries Economics. Paris, IIFET/ORSTROM. pp. 1315-1354. Charles, A. (2011) Human Rights and Fishery Rights in Small-scale Fisheries Man- agement. In Pomeroy, R.S. & Andrew, N.L., eds. Small-Scale Fisheries Manage- ment: Frameworks and Approaches for the Developing World. CAB International, Oxfordshire. Charles, A. (2008) The Rights Form of Rights. Samudra Report No 51 OR Charles, A. (2008) Robust Management, Risk and the Ecosystem Approach to Fisheries. ICES CM 2008/O:05 Theme Session: Governmental quality and risk manage- ment. Christie, P. & White, A.T. (2007) Best practices for improved governance of coral reef marine protected areas. Coral reefs, 26: 1047-1056. Christie P. & White A.T. (2006) Best Practice in Governance and Enforcement of Marine Protected Areas: An overview. Paper produced for the FAO Expert Workshop on Marine Protected Areas and Fisheries Management: Review of issues and considerations, 12-14 June, 2006. Christy F. (1982) Territorial Use Rights in Marine Fisheries: Definitions and Condi- tions. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper 227, Rome. Cinner, J.E., McClanahan, T.R. & Wamukota, A. (2010) Differences in livelihoods, socioeconomic characteristics, and knowledge about the sea between fishers and non-fishers living near and far from marine parks on the Kenyan coast. Marine Policy, 34(1): 22-28. Claudet, J. (2011) Introduction. In Claudet, ed. Marine Protected Areas: A Multidisci- plinary Approach. Cambridge University Press. COBSEA (2011) Spatial Planning in the Coastal Zone of the East Asian Seas Region: Integrating Emerging Issues and Modern Management Approaches.
  • 108. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 90 Cochrane, K.L. (2002) Fisheries Management. In Cochrane, K.L.,ed. A fishery manager’s guidebook. Management measures and their application. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper. No. 424, 231 p. FAO, Rome. Cochrane, K., De Young, C., Soto, D. & Bahari,,T., eds. (2009) Climatic Change Impli- cations for Fisheries and Aquaculture: Overview of current scientific knowledge. FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Technical Paper. No. 530. FAO, Rome. Collier, P. (2007) Growth Strategies for Africa. A paper presented at the Spence Com- mission on Economic Growth. Centre for the Study of African Economies, De- partment of Economics, Oxford University. CI (Conservation International) (2011) Ecosystem-based adaptation for terrestrial, marine and coastal regions, fact sheet (available athttp://www.conservation.org/ Documents/CI_IKI_Ecosystem-based_Adaptation_Factsheet.pdf ). Copes, P. & Charles, A.T. (2004) Socioeconomics of Individual Transferable Quotas and Community-Based Fishery Management. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review, 33(2): 171-181. Costello, C.J., Gaines, S.D. & Lynham, J. (2008) Can Catch Shares prevent fisheries collapse? Science, 321:1678-80. Costello, C., Kinlan, B. P., Lester S.E. & Gaines S.D. (2012) “The Economic Value of Rebuilding Fisheries”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 55, OECD Publishing. Cunningham, S., Neiland, A.E., Arbuckle, M. & and Bostock, T. (2009) Wealth-based Fisheries Management: Using Fisheries Wealth to Orchestrate Sound Fisheries Policy in Practice. Marine Resource Economics, 24: 271-287. DeFries, R., Hansen, A., Turner, B.L., Reid, R. & Liu, J. (2007) Land Use Change Around Protected Areas: Management To Balance Human Needs and Ecological Function. Ecological Applications, 17(4): 1031-1038. Degnbol, P., Gislason, H., Hanna, S., Jentoft, S., Nielsen, J.R., Sverdrup-Jensen, S. & Wilson, D.C. (2006) Painting the floor with a hammer: Technical fixes in fisheries management. Marine Policy, 30(5): 534-543. Degnbol, P. (2009) Coastal Management for Sustainability (speech), Common Fisheries Policy Conference, London (available at http://ec.europa.eu/fisheries/ reform/docs/tom_appleby_en.pdf). DFID (2012) Annual review of International Partnership for African Fisheries Gov- ernance and Trade, synthesis draft (available at http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/pdf/ outputs/EoD/EoD_Consultancy_Summary_Oct2012_PAF_Review.pdf) Dickson M.W. (undated) The CBFM-2 project: proving the case for community based and co-management of fisheries in Bangladesh. Conference Paper no 1 (available at http://www.worldfishcenter.org/resource_centre/WF_765.pdf). Donnelly J. (2003) Universal Human Rights in Theory and Practice. Cornell Univer- sity Press. Ithaca, NY, USA.
  • 109. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 91 Dryzek, J.S. (2005) The Politics of the Earth: Environmental Discourses. Oxford Uni- versity Press, UK. Evans, L., Cherrett, N. & Pemsl, D. (2011a) Assessing the impact of fisheries co- management interventions in developing countries: A meta analysis. Journal of Environmental Management, 92: 1938-1949. Evans, L.S., Brown, K. & Allison, E.H. (2011b) Factors Influencing Adaptive Marine Governance in a Developing Country Context: a Case Study of Southern Kenya. Ecology and Society, 16(2): 21. Fabinyi, M., Knudsen, M. & Segi, S. (2010) Social Complexity, Ethnography and Coastal Resource Management in the Philippines. Coastal Management, 38(6): 617-632. FAO (2008) Fisheries and Aquaculture Report No. 884 FIMF/R884 (En). Workshop held in Rome, 26–29 February 2008. FAO, Rome. FAO (1993) Marine Fisheries and the Law of the Sea: A decade of change. FAO fisheries circular no. 853: FAO, Rome. FAO (1996) FAO Technical Guidelines for Responsible Fisheries – Precautionary Approach to Capture Fisheries and Species Introductions. FAO, Rome. FAO (2007) Marine Protected Areas as a Tool for Fisheries Management. MPAs, fisheries management and the ecosystem approach. FI Project Websites. In: FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Department [online]. Rome (available at http://www. fao.org/fishery/topic/16200/en). FAO (2008) FAO Newsroom. US$50 billion lost by marine fishing each year (available at http://www.fao.org/newsroom/en/news/2008/1000931/). FAO (2010) Report of the APFIC/FAO Regional Consultative Workshop: Securing sustainable small-scale fisheries: Bringing together responsible fisheries and social development, Bangkok, Thailand, 6-8 October 2010. FAO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific. RAP Publication 2010/19. 56 pp. FAO (2012a) The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture, 2012. FAO, Rome. FAO (2012b) International Guidelines for Securing Sustainable Small-Scale Fisheries. Zero Draft. FAO, Rome. Ferrol-Schulte, D., Wolff, M., Ferse, S. & Glaser, M. (2013) Sustainable Livelihoods Approach in tropical coastal and marine social-ecological systems: A review. Marine Policy, 42: 253-258. Fisheries Administration (2010) Fishing for the Future: Strategic Planning Framework for Fisheries 2010–2019. Fisheries Administration, Phnom Penh, Cambodia. Folke, C., Pritchard, L., Berkes, F., Colding, J. & Svedin, U. (1998) The problem of fit between ecosystems and institutions. International Human Dimensions Programme on Global Environmental Change, Bonn, Germany. Forest Trends, The Katoomba Group & UNEP (2008) Payments for Ecosystem Services. Getting Started: A Primer. Forest Trends/The Katoomba Group / UNEP, Nairobi. 74pp.
  • 110. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 92 Francis, J. & Bryceson, I. (2001) Tanzanian coastal and marine resources: some examples illustrating questions of sustainable use. Cited in Ahmed, J., Bergstrøm, C., Bryceson, I., Child, B., Francis, J., Khan, P., Ousmane, B.G., Price, T.L., Senaratna, S., Tareen, N. & van Dam, C., eds. In Lessons learned – Case Studies in Sustainable Use. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland, in pp 76–102. Gell, F.R. & Roberts, C.M. (2002) The Fishery Effects on Marine Reserves and Fishery Closures. WWF-US, Washington, DC. Gondo, T. (2008) Adaptive co-management of natural resources: A solution or part of the problem? Journal of Human Ecology, 33(2): 119-131. Graham, J., Charles, A. & Bull, A. (2006) Community Fisheries Management Handbook. Gorsebrook Research Institute, Saint Mary’s University. Greiber, Thomas, ed. (2009) Payments for Ecosystem Services. Legal and Institution- al Frameworks. IUCN, Gland, Switzerland. xvi + 296 pp. Gulbrandsen, L. (2009) The Emergence and Effectiveness of the Marine Stewardship Council. Marine Policy, 33: 654–660. Gutierrez, N.L., Hilborn, R. & Defeo, O. (2011) Leadership, social capital and incen- tives promote successful fisheries. Nature, 470: 386-389. Hall, S.J. & Andrew, N.L. (2011) Recent developments in fisheries science and their prospects for improving fisheries contributions to food security. In Foresight Project on Global Food and Farming Futures. Foresight, Government Office for Science, London. Hall, S.J. & Mainprize, B. (2004) Toward ecosystem-based fisheries management. Fish and Fisheries, 5: 1-20. Hanna, S.S. (1995) User participation and fishery management performance within the Pacific Fishery Management Council. Ocean & Coastal Management, 28(1-3): 23-44. Hilborn, R. (1985) Fleet dynamics and individual variation: why some people catch more than others. Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Science, 42, 2–13, cited in Salas & Gaertner (2004) Hiborn, R., Branch, T.A., Ernst, B., Magnusson, A., Minte-Vera, C.V., Scheuerell, M.D. & Valero, J.L. (2003) State of the World’s Fisheries. Annual Review of Environ- ment and Resources, 28: 359-99. Hilborn, R. (2007a) Managing fisheries is managing people: what has been learned? Fish and Fisheries, 8: 285-296. Hilborn, R. (2007b) Moving to Sustainability by Learning from Successful Fisheries. Ambio, 36(4): 296-303. Hilborn, R. (2007c) Defining success in fisheries and conflicts in objectives. Marine Policy, 31(2): 153–158. Hind, E.J., Hiponia, M.C. & Gray, T.S. (2010) From community-based to central- ised national management – A wrong turning for the governance of the marine protected area in Apo Island, Philippines? Marine Policy, 34(1): 54-62.
  • 111. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 93 Holden, S.T., Shiferaw, B. & Wik, M. (1998) Poverty, market imperfections and time preferences: Of relevance for environmental policy? Environment and Develop- ment Economics, 3: 105-130. Howard, C. & Arthur, R.I. (2005) Lessons for co-management: experiences from the FMSP programme. MRAG Ltd, London, 12pp. Huppert, D.D. (2005) An Overview of Fishing Rights. Reviews in Fish Biology and Fisheries, 15(3): 201-215. IMM (2001) Learning Lessons from the Cyclone: A study of DFID’s Support for the Post-Cyclone Livelihoods Rehabilitation in Orissa, India (available at: http://www. imm.uk.com/PS/Main.aspx?projectid=671dac8e-85c7-4965-bc89-c53b2dd20da9). IMM & ICM (2003) Major Trends in the Utilisation of Fish in India: Poverty-Policy Consideration. Output of the India Fish Utilisation and Poverty Project, RNRRS, DFID, London (available at http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/Search/SearchResults.aspx?s earch=advancedsearch&SearchType=3&Projects=false&Documents=true&Doc umentsOnly=true&ProjectID=2480). IMM, CFDO & CBNRM LI. (2005) Understanding the Factors that Support or Inhibit Livelihood Diversification in Coastal Cambodia. An output from DFID-funded research in Cambodia. IMM Ltd, Exeter, UK. (available at http://www.imm. uk.com/PS/Main.aspx?projectid=dd1e357e-9594-43c1-8266-c7be839098fa). IPCC (2011) IPCC special report on managing the risks of extreme events and disasters to advance climate change adaptation: fact sheet (available at www.ipcc. ch/news_and_ events/docs/srex/SREX_fact_sheet.pdf). Accessed 19 March 2012. Jentoft, S. & McCay, B. (1995) User participation in fisheries management: Lessons drawn from international experiences. Marine Policy, 19(3): 227-246. Jentoft, S. (2000) The Community: a missing link in fisheries management. Marine Policy, 24, 53-59. Jentoft, S. & Chuenpagdee, R. (2009) Fisheries and Coastal Governance as a Wicked Problem. Marine Policy, 33(4): 553-560. Johannes, R. E. (1981) Words of the Lagoon: Fishing and Marine Lore in the Palau District of Micronesia. University of California Press, Berkeley, USA. Jones, P.J.S. (2007) Point of View – Arguments for conventional fisheries management and against no-take marine protected areas: only half of the story? Reviews in Fish Biology and Fisheries, 17(1), 31-43. doi: 10.1007/s11160-006-9016-8. Kuemlangan, B. (2004) Creating legal space for community-based fisheries and customary marine tenure in the Pacific: issues and opportunities. FishCode Review, No. 7(En). 2004. 65p., FAO, Rome. Kuperan, V.K. & Jahan, K.M. (2010) Noncompliance a major threat in fisheries management – Experiences from the artisanal coastal fisheries of Bangladesh. Journal of International Studies, 6: 97-113.
  • 112. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 94 Leal, D.R. (2010) Lessons for Fisheries Reform and Development Assistance. D. Leal, ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Wash- ington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Department, the World Bank. Lennox, M. (2012) Monies for Marine Conservation: a White Paper Examining New Funding Sources for Oceans and Coasts. The Nature Conservancy, 56 pp (available at http://www.marineplanning.org/pdf/Monies_for_Marine_Conser- vation.pdf. Link, J.S. (2010) Ecosystem-Based Fisheries Management: Confronting trade-offs. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Lowry, G.K., White, A.T. & Christie, P. (2009) Scaling Up to Networks of Marine Protected Areas in the Philippines: Biophysical, Legal, Institutional, and Social Considerations. Coastal Management, 37(3-4): 274-290. Mahon, R., McConney, P. & Roy, R.N. (2008) Governing fisheries as complex adaptive systems. Marine Policy, 32: 104-112. Maliao, R.J., Pomeroy, R.S. & Turingan, R.G. (2009) Performance of community- based coastal resource management (CBCRM) programs in the Philippines: A meta-analysis. Marine Policy, 33(5): 818-825. Manta Consulting (2011) Financing Fisheries Change: Learning from Case Studies. 120pp. Manta Consulting, Inc. MARES (undated) Marine and Coastal Ecosystem Service Payments & Markets. Powerpoint presentation, 17 pp. (available at http://redlac.org/winnie%20lau%20 -%20marine%20and%20coastal%20ecosystem%20service%20payments%20and%20 markets%202.pdf). McConney, P. & Charles, A. (2008) Managing Small-Scale Fisheries: Moving Towards People-Centred Perspectives. In Grafton, R.Q., Hilborn, R., Squires, D., Maree, T. & Williams, M. (eds.) Handbook of Marine Fisheries Conservation and Manage- ment. Oxford University Press, UK. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MA) (2005) Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: A Framework for Assessment. Island Press, Washington, DC. Moberg, F. & Galaz, V. (2005) Resilience: Going from Conventional to Adaptive Fresh- water Management for Human and Ecosystem Compatibility. Swedish Water House Policy Brief Nr. 3. SIWI, 2005. MRAG, IDS & University of Sterling (2013) Fisheries and Aquaculture and their Potential Roles in Development: an assessment of the current evidence. Report produced for DFID, London. MRAG (2009) Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated Fishing. Policy Brief No. 8. MRAG, London. MRAG (2010) Towards sustainable fisheries management: international examples of innovation. MRAG Ltd, London: 93 pages (available at http://www.pcfisu.org/ wp-content/uploads/2010/12/MRAG-report_best-practice-examples1.pdf).
  • 113. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 95 OECD & FAO (2009) Round Table on Eco-labeling and Certification in the Fisheries Sector. Proceedings of a round table workshop 22-23 April 2009 The Hague, The Netherlands (available at http://www.globefish.org/upl/Papers/Final%20 Report%20Roundtable_720.pdf). Ostrom, E. (2009a) A General Framework for Analyzing Sustainability of Social-Eco- logical Systems. Science, 325: 419-422. Ostrom, E. (2009b) Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems. Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, USA, and Center for the Study of Institutional Diversity, Arizona State University, Tempe, Arizona, USA. Pearse, P.H. (1992) From Open Access to Private Property – Recent Innovations in Fishing Rights as Instruments of Fisheries Policy. Ocean Development and Inter- national Law, 23(1): 71-83. Pitcher, T.J., Watson, R., Haggan, N., Guenette, S., Kennish, R., Sumaila, R., Cook. D., Wilson. K. & Leung, A. (2000) Marine reserves and the restoration of fisheries and marine ecosystems in the South China Sea. Bull. Mar. Sci. 66(3):543-566. Pomeroy, R.S. (1994) Community management and common property of coastal fisheries in Asia and the Pacific: Concepts, methods and experiences – Intro- duction. In Pomeroy, R.S. (ed.) Community Management and Common Property of Coastal Fisheries in Asia and the Pacific: Concepts, Methods and Experiences. ICLARM Conf. Proc. 45, 189 p. Pope, J.G. (1983). Fisheries resource management theory and practice. In Taylor, J.L., Baird, G.G., eds. New Zealand finfish fisheries: the resources and their man- agement. Auckland New Zealand: Trade Publications Limited, 1983. p. 56–62. Raakjaer Nielsen, J. & Vedsmand, T. (1995) Fisheries Co-Management: An Alternative Strategy in Fisheries – Cases from Denmark. An issue paper for the OECD study on the efficient management of living resources. Roberts, C.M. (2007) The Unnatural History of the Sea. Island Press, Washington, DC. Roberts, C.M., Hawkins, J.P. & Gell, F.R. (2005) The role of marine reserves in achieving sustainable fisheries. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 360(1453):123-132. Roberts, C.M., Bohnsack, J.A., Gell, F., Hawkins, J.P. & Goodridge, R. (2001) Effects of Marine Reserves on Adjacent Fisheries. Science, 294: 1920-1923. Robinson, J.A. (2010) The Political Economy of Institutions and Resources. In D. Leal, ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Wash- ington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Department, the World Bank. Roe, D., Nelson, F. & Sandbrook, C., eds. (2009) Community Management of Natural Resources in Africa: Impacts, experiences and future directions. Natural Resources Issues No. 18, International Institute for Environment and Develop- ment, London, UK.
  • 114. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 96 Rudd, M.A., Tupper, M.H., Folmer, H. & van Kooten, G.C. (2003) Policy analysis for tropical marine reserves: challenges and directions. Fish and Fisheries, 4(1): 65-85. Ruddle, K. & Hviding, E. (1992) Marine Resources Management in the Context of Customary Tenure. Marine Resource Economics, 7: 249-273. Ruddle, K. & Johhannes, R. (1985) The Traditional Knowledge and Management of Coastal Systems in Asia and the Pacific. Papers presented at the UNESCO-ROT- SEA Regional Seminar at UNESCO Regional Office for Science and Technology for Southeast Asia, 5-7 December 1983. UNESCO, Jakarta. Salagrama, V. (2005) Traditional Community-Based Management Systems (TCBMS) in two Fishing Villages in East Godavari District, Andhra Pradesh, India. In Cun- ningham S. & Bostock T., eds. Successful Fisheries Management: Issues, case studies and perspectives. SIFAR/World Bank Study. Eburon Academic Publishers, The Hague. Salagrama, V. & Koriya, T. (2008) Assessing Opportunities for Livelihood Enhance- ment and Diversification in Coastal Fishing Communities in Southern India. United Nations Team for Tsunami Recovery Support (UNTRS), Chennai. Salas, S. & Gaertner, D. (2004) The Behavioural Dynamics of Fishers: Management implications. Fish and Fisheries, 5: 153–167. Samonte, G., Karrer, L. & Orbach, M. (2010) People and Oceans. Science and Knowledge Division, Conservation International, Arlington, Virginia, USA. Scott, A. (2010) New Direction in Fishery Management. In Leal, D., ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Agriculture and Rural Development Department, the World Bank, Washington, DC. Scudder, T. & Connelly, T. (1985) Management Systems for Riverine Fisheries. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper (263) 85pp. Sen, S. & Nielsen, J.R. (1996) Fisheries co-management: a comparative analysis. Marine Policy, 20(5): 405-418. Smith, I.R. (1981) Improving fisheries incomes when resources are overfished. Marine Policy, 5: 17-22. Spergel, B. & Moye, M. (2004) Financing Marine Conservation A Menu of Options. WWF Center for Conservation Finance, Washington, DC, 74pp. Stobutzki, I.C., Silvestre, G.T. & Garces, L.R. (2006) Key issues in coastal fisheries in South and Southeast Asia, outcomes of a regional initiative. Fisheries Research, 78(2-3): 109-118. Sugiyama, S., Staples, D. & Funge-Smith, S.J. (2004) Status and potential of fisheries and aquaculture in Asia and the Pacific. FAO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific (RAP) Publication 2004/25. 53 pp. Sumaila, U.R., Khan, A.J., Dyck, A., Watson, R., Munro, G., Tyedmerset, P. & Pauly, D. (2010) A Bottom-up Re-estimation of Global Fisheries Subsidies. Journal of Bioeconomics, 12(3): 201–225.
  • 115. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 97 Sutinen, J. (2010) Governance and Fiscal Requirements for Marine Resources Man- agement. In Leal, D., ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development Depart- ment, the World Bank. Swan, J. & Greboval, D. (2004) Overcoming Factors of Unsustainability and Over- exploitation in Fisheries, Selected Papers on Issues and Approaches. Interna- tional Workshop on the Implementation of International Fisheries Instrument and Factors of Unsustainability and Overexploitation in Fisheries. Siem Reap, Cambodia, 13-16 September 2004: FAO Fisheries Report, 782. Silvestri, S. & Kershaw, F., eds. (2010) Framing the flow: Innovative Approaches to Understand, Protect and Value Ecosystem Services across Linked Habitats, UNEP World Conservation Monitoring Centre, Cambridge, UK. The Western Star (2009). Hilborn, R. video conference from University of Washington. http://www.thewesternstar.com/Business/2009-09-18/article-1479752/Cod- quotas-cant-be-increased-even-if-stocks-are-recovering:-fisheries-specialist/1 Thompson, B.T. (2010) Legal Issues in Fisheries Reform: Lessons from Resource Management. In Leal, D., ed. Political Economy of Natural Resource Use: Lessons for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC: Agriculture and Rural Development De- partment, the World Bank. Tobey, J. & Torell, E. (2006) Coastal poverty and MPA management in mainland Tanzania and Zanzibar. Ocean & Coastal Management, 49: 834-854. Townsley, P., Chandra Mohan, G.M. & Karthikeyan, V. (2011) Fisheries Stakehold- ers and Their Livelihoods in Tamil Nadu and Puducherry. A Report prepared for the Fisheries Management for Sustainable Livelihoods (FIMSUL) Project, undertaken by the FAO in association with the World Bank, the Government of Tamil Nadu and the Government of Puducherry. Report No. FIMSUL/R2. FAO/ UTF/IND/180/IND. New Delhi, Chennai and Puducherry, India (available at https://38549c75-a-62cb3a1a-s-sites.googlegroups.com/site/fimsulreports/ home/reports/R2L.pdf?attachauth=ANoY7cq8-ODJEt4Da7ok-LHoDyUG53IIXh- 75hckKvA9h2RmN7vUVwa0TyCZbyZ3KKv-UucLTbWQt8b8RSGPLMkLKQOR- murlZkQZyRmLcDMHkOYyq_Y4E_n_pWwtAC9-23xiA_0LKAJsmkON3EnSrqz- B15wdHDSpGeCenAbjiAic0j8PufftpKOLmzVQP-lN-H52wTRE8gmbSA-98XYYT 6z7fVVeUBFAMJ2qUWine1VsLw10Q8K9aUTo%3D&attredirects=0 Tupper, M.H. & Rudd, M.A. (2003) Species-specific impacts of a small marine reserve on shellfish production and fishing productivity in the Turks and Caicos Islands. Environmental Conservation, 29: 484-492. van Tuyen, T.V., Armitage D. & Marschke, M. (2010) Participatory planning for co- management in Tam Giang Lagoon. Ocean and Coastal Management, 53: 327-335. von Brandt, A. (1972) Fish Catching Methods of the World. Fishing News (Books) Ltd, West Byfleet, UK. Walmsley, S., Purvis, J. & Ninnes, C. (2006) The role of small-scale fisheries manage- ment in the poverty reduction strategies in the Western Indian Ocean region. Ocean & Coastal Management, 49: 812-833.
  • 116. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 98 Wakumota, A.W., Cinner, J.E. & McClanahan, T.R. (2012) Co-management of coral reef fisheries: A critical evaluation of the literature. Marine Policy, 36(2): 481-488. Waycott, M., Duarte, C.M., Caruthers, T.J.B., Orth, R.J., Dennison, W.C. & Olyarnik, S. (2008) Accelerating loss of seagrasses across the globe threatens coastal eco- systems. PNAS, 106(30): 12377-12381. Weeratunge, N., Bene, C., Siriwardane, R., Charles, A., Johnson, D. & Allison, E.H. (2013) Small-scale fisheries through the wellbeing lens. Fish and Fisheries, doi: 10.1111/faf.12016. White, A., Deguit, E. & Jautlan, W. (2006) Integrated Coastal Management in Philip- pine Local Governance: Evolution and Benefits. Coastal Management, 34: 287-302. Whittingham, E., Campbell, J. & Townsley, P. (2003) Poverty and Reefs. DFID-IMM- IOC/UNESCO, UNESCO, Paris, France. Wilson, D.C., Ahmed, M., Siar, S.V. & Kanagaratnam, U. (2006) Cross-scale linkages and adaptive management: Fisheries co-management in Asia. Marine Policy, 30: 523-533. Willmannm, R. (2010) Good Practices in the Governance of Small-Scale Fisheries, with a Focus on Rights-Based Approaches. In Report of the APFIC/FAO Regional Consultative Workshop “Securing sustainable small-scale fisheries: Bringing together responsible fisheries and social development”, Bangkok, Thailand, 6-8 October 2010. FAO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific (RAP) publication 2010/19. 56 pp. World Bank & FAO (2009) The Sunken Billions: The economic justification for fisheries reform. Worsley, P. (1997) Knowledges: What Different Peoples Make of the World. Profile Books Ltd, London. WWF (2012) Raising the Sunken Billions: a new model for financing fisheries reform. WWF Factsheet July 2012, 2pp (available at http://awsassets.panda.org/ downloads/fact_sheet_the_firme.pdf). Zhou, S., Smith, A.D.M., Punt, A.E., Richardson, A.J., Gibbs, M., Fulton, E.A., Pascoe S., Bulman C., Bayliss P. & Sainsbury K. (2010) Ecosystem-based fisheries man- agement requires a change to the selective fishing philosophy. PNAS, 107(21): 9485-9.
  • 117. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 99 Annexes ANNEX 1: A: Electronic database search log DATE OF SEARCH SEARCH DATABASE SEARCH TERMS SEARCH FIELD NO. OF RESULTS 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge –Web of Science Fish* *manage* Topic 29,916 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Fish* *manage* coast* Topic 5,189 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Fish* community-based Topic 550 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Fish* adaptive NEAR/3 manage* Topic 447 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Ecosystem *manage* Topic 32,823 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Ecosystem *manage* coast* Topic 4,267 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Ecosystem community-based Topic 438 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Ecosystem adaptive NEAR/3 manage* Topic 1,041 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Natural resource *manage* Topic 15,408 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Natural resource *manage* coast* Topic 1,288 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Natural resource community-based Topic 622 02/07/13 Web of Knowledge – Web of Science Natural resource adaptive NEAR/3 manage* Topic 460 03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* Complete document Query too general 03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* coast* Complete document Query too general 03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* Title 18,445 03/07/13 Scirus Fish* *manage* coast* Title 514 03/07/13 Scirus Fish* community-based Complete document 2,095,331 03/07/13 Scirus Fish* community-based Title 342 03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* Complete document Query too general 03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* coast* Complete document Query too general 03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* Title 9,323 03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem *manage* coast* Title 72 03/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem community-based Completed document 772, 268
  • 118. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 100 DATE OF SEARCH SEARCH DATABASE SEARCH TERMS SEARCH FIELD NO. OF RESULTS 10203/07/13 Scirus Ecosystem community-based Title 102 03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* Complete document 4,725,634 03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* Title 8,874 03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* coast* Complete document 937, 141 03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource *manage* coast* Title 105 03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource community-based Complete document 1,858,356 03/07/13 Scirus Natural resource community-based Title 360 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Fish* *manage* All Fields No matches 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Fish* *manage* Title No matches 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Fisheries management All Fields 32+ 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Fish* community-based All Fields 4+ 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Ecosystem *manage* All Fields No matches 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Ecosystem *manage* Title No matches 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Ecosystem management All Fields 3+ 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Ecosystem community-based All Fields 3+ 04/04/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Natural resource *manage* All Fields No matches 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Natural resource *manage* Title No matches 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Natural resource management All Fields 1+ 04/07/13 Directory of Open Access Journals Natural resource community-based All Fields 5+ 04/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts Fish* *manage* All Fields 10+ 08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts Fish* community-based All Fields 2+ 08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts Ecosystem *manage* All Fields 0 08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts Ecosystem community-based All Fields 0 08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts Natural resource *manage* All Fields 1+ 08/07/13 Applied Social Sciences Index and Abstracts Natural resource community-based All Fields 0 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Fish* *manage* All Fields 94, 247 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Fish* *manage* coast* All Fields 21, 127
  • 119. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 101 DATE OF SEARCH SEARCH DATABASE SEARCH TERMS SEARCH FIELD NO. OF RESULTS 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Fish* *manage* coast* Abstract 7, 248 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Fish* *manage* coast* Document Title 316 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Fish* community-based All Fields 923 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Ecosystem *manage* All Fields 49, 666 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Ecosystem *manage* coast* All Fields 13, 184 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Ecosystem *manage* coast* Abstract 3,811 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Ecosystem *manage* coast* Document Title 111 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Ecosystem community-based All Fields 516 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Ecosystem community-based coast* All Fields 155 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Natural resource *manage* All Fields 38,446 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Natural resource *manage* coast* All Fields 9,953 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Natural resource *manage* coast* Abstract 1,438 10/07/13 Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts Natural resource *manage* coast* Document Title 9 + results screened for language and relevance criteria B: Institutional grey literature search log DATE OF SEARCH INSTITUTION WEBSITE: SEARCH AREA NO. OF RESULTS 14.07.2013 http://www.coopesolidar.org/ Sent by author 2 14.07.2013 http://www.wcs.org/ Sent by co-author 2 15.07.2013 http://fish.washington.edu/ Sent by co-authors 7 15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/13261/en FAO Fish Ecosystem 7 15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/mpas//en FAO Fish Ecosystem Marine protected areas 1 15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/2880/en FAO Fisheries Ecosystems 1 15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/3542/en FAO Fisheries Ecosystems Coastal & marine ecosystems 1
  • 120. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 102 DATE OF SEARCH INSTITUTION WEBSITE: SEARCH AREA NO. OF RESULTS 15.07.2013 http://www.fao.org/fishery/topic/3320/en FAO Fisheries Ecosystems Coastal & marine ecosystems Types of ecosystems 1 15.07.2013 ftp://ftp.fao.org/fi/DOCUMENT/eaf/eafguidelines_278364.pdf Sent by co-author 1 18.07.2013 http://toobigtoignore.net/ Books 2 18.07.2013 http://toobigtoignore.net/ Articles 1 19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/Pages/ partnerlanding.aspx Marine - 19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/initiatives/ fisheries/Pages/sustainable_fisheries.aspx Sustainable fisheries - 19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/initiatives/ seascapes/pages/seascapes.aspx Seascapes 2 19.07.2013 http://www.science2action.org/ Research and innovation 8 19.07.2013 http://www.science2action.org/files/sciencereports/ Science reports 4 19.07.2013 http://www.conservation.org/global/marine/publications/ Marine, Resources and publications 2 19.07.2013 http://equatorinitiative.org/ - 19.07.2013 http://sfg.msi.ucsb.edu/current-projects/sustainable-ocean- solutions Sustainable Oceans Solutions - 19.07.2013 http://sfg.msi.ucsb.edu/current-projects/unassessed_fisheries Un-assessed fisheries 1 19.07.2013 http://www.ifad.org/ ‎ Sent by author 1 19.07.2013 http://sfg.msi.ucsb.edu/ Sent by co-author 1 23.07.2013 http://www.mrcmekong.org/ Sent by author 1 23.07.2013 http://www.mrcmekong.org/publications/topic/ fisheries?start=20 Publications Fisheries 1 23.07.2013 http://www.rflp.org/co_management Co-management 7 25.07.2013 http://www.protectplanetocean.org/ Tools and resources 1 27.07.2013 https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/ browse?order=ASC&rpp=20&sort_by=-1&etal=- 1&offset=200&type=topic Fisheries and aquaculture 1 27.07.2013 http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/ EXTARD/0, contentMDK:23070469~pagePK:148956~piPK:216 618~theSitePK:336682,00.html World Bank Profish 20 29.07.2013 http://www.iucn.org/about/union/commissions/sustainable_ use_and_livelihoods_specialist_group/ Lessons learned 2 30.07.2013 http://www.afma.gov.au/resource-centre/research/reports/ Research reports 5 30.07.2013 http://www.afma.gov.au/search/?query=ecosystem+based+m anagement Ecosystem-based management guidelines 2 30.07.2013 http://www.afma.gov.au/ Sent by author 1 30.07.2013 http://www.cdu.edu.au/ Sent by author 4 01.08.2013 http://www.lmmanetwork.org/resourcecenter Resource center 3 14/08/13 http://www.idrc.ca/EN/Resources/Publications/Pages/ default.aspx Publications - Co-management 2 14/08/13 Publications - Fisheries management 0 14/08/13 Publications – Fish 1
  • 121. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 103 DATE OF SEARCH INSTITUTION WEBSITE: SEARCH AREA NO. OF RESULTS 14/08/13 http://www.idrc.ca/EN/Resources/Publications/Pages/ IDRCBooksList.aspx IDRC Books – Co-management 0 14/08/13 IDRC Books – Fisheries management 0 14/08/13 IDRC Books - Fish 2 14/08/13 http://www.smu.ca/webfiles/Dr.TonyCharles.pdf Co-management; community- based; ecosystem approach to fisheries; fishery management and governance; international fisheries; rights based management; small- scale fisheries; successful fisheries 26 14/08/13 http://www.southampton.ac.uk/oes/research/publications. page? Publications 0 14/08/13 http://www.enaca.org/modules/library/tag.php?label_type=1 Better management practices 0 14/08/13 Livelihoods, gender and social issues 1 14/08/13 http://www.afdb.org/en/documents/environment/12/ Environment 0 14/08/13 http://www.adb.org/publications/search/448?keyword=fish Agriculture and natural resource – Fish 2 15/08/13 http://www.worldfishcenter.org/worldfish-publications Fisheries management – open access 23 15/08/13 http://r4d.dfid.gov.uk/Search/SearchResults.aspx ?search=advancedsearch&SearchType=3&Projects= false&Documents=true&DocumentsOnly=true&Any word=fisheries+management&AnywordCondition= AND&AnyWordPhrase1=1&AnyWordChooseField1=- 1&Keywords=2188&PageNo=7 Fisheries management 7 15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/ Co-management 2 15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat. php?cid=59 Fishery and aquaculture policy 1 15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat. php?cid=57 Ecosystem approach to fisheries 3 15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat. php?cid=67 Promoting co-managemenet 2 15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/viewcat. php?cid=76 Gender in fisheries and aquaculture 1 15/08/13 http://www.apfic.org/modules/wfdownloads/singlefile. php?cid=68&lid=274 Participatory development approaches 1 16/08/13 http://caricom-fisheries.com/PublicationsandDocuments/ CRFMResearchPaperCollection/tabid/86/Default.aspx CRFM Research Paper Collection 2 16/08/13 http://caricom-fisheries.com/PublicationsandDocuments/ CRFMTechnicalandAdvisoryDocuments/tabid/87/Default.aspx CRFM Technical and Advisory Documents 4 20/08/13 http://www.macfound.org/press/publications/conservation- sustainable-development-white-papers/ Conservation and Sustainable development white papers 1 20/08/13 http://www.castlefoundation.org/grants-marine.htm Nearshore Marine Resource Conservation 0 20/08/13 http://www.waltonfamilyfoundation.org/environment/marine- conservation Marine Conservation 0 20/08/13 http://www.oakfnd.org/library Environment 0 20/08/13 http://www.packard.org/what-were-learning/program-area/ children-families-and-communities/ Conservation and Science; Children, Families and Communities 0
  • 122. KEYFACTORSSUPPORTINGSMALL-SCALECOASTALFISHERIESMANAGEMENT-SYNTHESISREVIEW 104 ANNEX 2: Informal knowledge search checklist NAME(S) ORGANIZATION(S) POSITION(S) LOCATION DATE The checklist below lays out some broad questions about your knowledge and experience of eco-system based community management approaches (left hand column) while the middle column contains some additional more specific issues that you may want to consider while writing your responses in the right hand column. Please feel free to treat these questions as freely as you wish and by all means make suggestions regarding their relevance. In your responses to some of the questions, you might want to make a distinction between your personal opinions and experience, and those of the organization that you work for. GENERAL QUESTIONS PROMPTS KEY KNOWLEDGE AREAS/OUTPUTS What do you feel are the key characteristics or defining features of an ecosystem-based community management (ECM) approach? What experience have you had of these approaches? What ECM initiatives have you been involved with / are you familiar with? Describe the key features of the approaches used? What do you regard as the strengths and weaknesses of ECM approaches (based on your experience) and what factors contribute to them? How would you define a successful ECM approach? What are/were the strengths of the approaches you have experienced or used? What were the weaknesses? What specific factors contribute/d to their success or positive impacts / failure? Ecological / resource characteristics? Social setting? Governance arrangements? Characteristics of the organisations involved? Wider institutional context? Scale? Markets? Wider economy? Timing? Cost-effectiveness? Can you suggest key initiatives, individuals or organisations who work on ECM who we should be in contact with as part of this review? What other individuals or organisations are you aware of working on ECM and/or community- based management? What documents would you regard as the most useful for understanding ECM approaches? Papers. Reports. Books. Guidelines and manuals. Articles.
  • 123. Financial support provided by www.rockefellerfoundation.org