Economics of the Firm Analysis Evolution and History 1st Edition Michael Dietrich
Economics of the Firm Analysis Evolution and History 1st Edition Michael Dietrich
Economics of the Firm Analysis Evolution and History 1st Edition Michael Dietrich
Economics of the Firm Analysis Evolution and History 1st Edition Michael Dietrich
1. Visit https://ebookultra.com to download the full version and
explore more ebooks or textbooks
Economics of the Firm Analysis Evolution and
History 1st Edition Michael Dietrich
_____ Click the link below to download _____
https://ebookultra.com/download/economics-of-the-firm-
analysis-evolution-and-history-1st-edition-michael-dietrich/
Explore and download more ebooks or textbooks at ebookultra.com
2. Here are some recommended products that we believe you will be
interested in. You can click the link to download.
Alternative Theories of the Firm 1st Edition Michael
Pirson
https://ebookultra.com/download/alternative-theories-of-the-firm-1st-
edition-michael-pirson/
Pareto Economics and Society The Mechanical Analogy
Routledge Studies in the History of Economics 1st Edition
Michael Mclure
https://ebookultra.com/download/pareto-economics-and-society-the-
mechanical-analogy-routledge-studies-in-the-history-of-economics-1st-
edition-michael-mclure/
Krupp A History of the Legendary German Firm Harold James
https://ebookultra.com/download/krupp-a-history-of-the-legendary-
german-firm-harold-james/
Classical Economics and Modern Theory Studies in Long
Period Analysis Routledge Studies in the History of
Economics 63 1st Edition Heinz D. Kurz
https://ebookultra.com/download/classical-economics-and-modern-theory-
studies-in-long-period-analysis-routledge-studies-in-the-history-of-
economics-63-1st-edition-heinz-d-kurz/
3. Essays in the History of Economics Routledge Studies in
the History of Economics 67 1st Edition William Henderson
https://ebookultra.com/download/essays-in-the-history-of-economics-
routledge-studies-in-the-history-of-economics-67-1st-edition-william-
henderson/
Trust and Economics The Co evolution of Trust and Exchange
Systems 1st Edition Yanlong Zhang
https://ebookultra.com/download/trust-and-economics-the-co-evolution-
of-trust-and-exchange-systems-1st-edition-yanlong-zhang/
The Pledge 1st Edition Cale Dietrich
https://ebookultra.com/download/the-pledge-1st-edition-cale-dietrich/
Paleolimnology The History and Evolution of Lake Systems
1st Edition Andrew S. Cohen
https://ebookultra.com/download/paleolimnology-the-history-and-
evolution-of-lake-systems-1st-edition-andrew-s-cohen/
The Volatility Machine Emerging Economics and the Threat
of Financial Collapse 1st Edition Michael Pettis
https://ebookultra.com/download/the-volatility-machine-emerging-
economics-and-the-threat-of-financial-collapse-1st-edition-michael-
pettis/
5. Economics of the Firm Analysis Evolution and History 1st
Edition Michael Dietrich Digital Instant Download
Author(s): Michael Dietrich
ISBN(s): 9780415395090, 0415395097
Edition: 1
File Details: PDF, 3.03 MB
Year: 2006
Language: english
7. Economics of the Firm
This volume presents an interdisciplinary, critical perspective on current
issues surrounding the economics of firms. The contributions largely depart
from traditional approaches and stress the importance of interdisciplinary
study of the firm as a dynamic evolving organisation.
The chapters emphasise the themes of change and evolution, and explore
issues arising from the history and organisation of firms. This combination of
economics and history is the characteristic setting for interdisciplinary analy-
sis of evolution and change.
The contributors include Bart Nooteboom, Stavros Ioannides and Sue
Bowden.
Michael Dietrich is Senior Lecturer at the Department of Economics,
University of Sheffield, UK.
8. Studies in global competition
A series of books edited by John Cantwell
The University of Reading, UK
and David Mowery
University of California, Berkeley, USA
Volume 1
Japanese Firms in Europe
Edited by Frédérique Sachwald
Volume 2
Technological Innovation, Multinational Corporations and New
International Competitiveness
The case of intermediate countries
Edited by José Molero
Volume 3
Global Competition and the Labour Market
Nigel Driffield
Volume 4
The Source of Capital Goods Innovation
The role of user firms in Japan and Korea
Kong-Rae Lee
Volume 5
Climates of Global Competition
Maria Bengtsson
Volume 6
Multinational Enterprises and Technological Spillovers
Tommaso Perez
Volume 7
Governance of International Strategic Alliances
Technology and transaction costs
Joanne E. Oxley
Volume 8
Strategy in Emerging Markets
Telecommunications establishments in Europe
Anders Pehrsson
9. Volume 9
Going Multinational
The Korean experience of direct investment
Edited by Frédérique Sachwald
Volume 10
Multinational Firms and Impacts on Employment, Trade
and Technology
New perspectives for a new century
Edited by Robert E. Lipsey and Jean-Louis Mucchielli
Volume 11
Multinational Firms
The global–local dilemma
Edited by John H. Dunning and Jean-Louis Mucchielli
Volume 12
MIT and the Rise of Entrepreneurial Science
Henry Etzkowitz
Volume 13
Technological Resources and the Logic of Corporate Diversification
Brian Silverman
Volume 14
The Economics of Innovation, New Technologies and Structural Change
Cristiano Antonelli
Volume 15
European Union Direct Investment in China
Characteristics, challenges and perspectives
Daniel Van Den Bulcke, Haiyan Zhang and Maria do Céu Esteves
Volume 16
Biotechnology in Comparative Perspective
Edited by Gerhard Fuchs
Volume 17
Technological Change and Economic Performance
Albert L. Link and Donald S. Siegel
Volume 18
Multinational Corporations and European Regional Systems
of Innovation
John Cantwell and Simona Iammarino
10. Volume 19
Knowledge and Innovation in Regional Industry
An entrepreneurial coalition
Roel Rutten
Volume 20
Local Industrial Clusters
Existence, emergence and evolution
Thomas Brenner
Volume 21
The Emerging Industrial Structure of the Wider Europe
Edited by Francis McGowen, Slavo Radosevic and Nick von Tunzelmann
Volume 22
Entrepreneurship
A new perspective
Thomas Grebel
Volume 23
Evaluating Public Research Institutions
The U.S. advanced technology program’s intramural research initiative
Albert N. Link and John T. Scott
Volume 24
Location and Competition
Edited by Steven Brakman and Harry Garretsen
Volume 25
Entrepreneurship and Dynamics in the Knowledge Economy
Edited by Charlie Karlsson, Börje Johansson and Roger R. Stough
Volume 26
Evolution and Design of Institutions
Edited by Christian Schubert and Georg von Wangenheim
Volume 27
The Changing Economic Geography of Globalization
Reinventing space
Edited by Giovanna Vertova
Volume 28
Economics of the Firm
Analysis, evolution, history
Edited by Michael Dietrich
11. Economics of the Firm
Analysis, evolution, history
Edited by
Michael Dietrich
13. List of figures and tables ix
List of contributors xi
Preface xiii
1 Introduction: the firm in an interdisciplinary context 1
MICHAEL DIETRICH
PART I
The economics of the firm: analysis and background 17
2 The nature of the firm revisited 19
MICHAEL DIETRICH
3 Trust, learning and the firm 43
BART NOOTEBOOM
4 Accounting and the economic analysis of the firm as an entity 65
YURI BIONDI
5 The value of integration: old institutional economics and new
institutional sociology 88
HASSAN YAZDIFAR
PART II
The economics of the firm: change and evolution 109
6 The evolutionary theory of the firm: routines, complexity
and change 111
WERNER HÖLZL
Contents
14. viii Contents
7 Insights into the self-reproduction of the firm with the
Von Neumann automaton model 127
PAVEL LUKSHA
8 A Penrosean theory of the firm: implications and applications
for the study of the growth of young firms 146
ERIK STAM, ELIZABETH GARNSEY AND PAUL HEFFERNAN
9 Entrepreneurship and corporate ownership: an Austrian view 169
STAVROS IOANNIDES
PART III
The economics of the firm: history and organization 185
10 Business history and the organization of industry 187
JACKIE KRAFFT
11 The firm in history: city–industry relations: a case study of
the engineering sector in the UK economy during the
interwar years 209
SUE BOWDEN, DAVID HIGGINS AND CHRISTOPHER PRICE
Index 228
15. Figures and tables
Figures
1.1 A taxonomy of interdisciplinary economics 2
1.2 The transaction cost layer schema 6
2.1 A fully connected model of the firm 34
2.2 Environmental impacts on the firm 37
3.1 Hierarchy of bodily and mental regulation 52
4.1 The firm-entity as economic organisation and institution 79
5.1 Mechanisms and drivers of homogeneity in organizational
forms and practices – an NIS view 92
5.2 The process of institutionalization 98
5.3 Multi-institutional framework incorporating both NIS
and OIE 101
7.1 Structure and operation of a JVN automate 132
7.2 Processes of an enterprise 140
8.1 Growth and non-growth by age of firm, Cambridgeshire
cohort 158
8.2 Growth paths of new firms, Netherlands sample 160
8.3 Turning points among Cambridgeshire firms founded in
1990, surviving 10 years 161
11.1 Number of companies listed on the London Stock Exchange,
1917–38 213
11.2 Total book value of listed companies: engineering 213
11.3 Electrical engineering: debt and equity 218
11.4 Vehicle engineering: debt and equity (total) in the interwar
years 218
11.5 General engineering: debt and equity book values 219
11.6 General engineering: the move from loan to overdraft
finance 219
Tables
3.1 Sources of (intentional) reliability 46
4.1 Equilibrium and accounting frames 73
16. x Figures and tables
4.2 Proprietary and entity views 74
5.1 A continuum of managerial responses to institutional
pressures 95
7.1 Analogies between a JVN automate and a self-reproducing
firm 134
7.2 Classification of self-reproducing firms 137
8.1 Characteristics of the research samples 157
10.1 Competence, innovation and the vertical structure of the
industry 198
11.1 Capitalisation (book value £), motor vehicle firms quoted
on the London Stock Exchange in 1917 214
11.2 Significant entrants to London Stock Exchange listing,
general engineering in the 1920s: date of first listing and
book value (£) 215
11.3 Choice of finance instrument 217
11.4 Electrical engineering: finance by debt and equity of pre-1900
and 1900–14 cohorts of firms 220
11.5 Vehicle engineering: finance by debt and equity of pre-1900
and 1900–14 cohorts of firms 221
11.6 Interest rates levied on long-term debt 223
11.7 Re-capitalisation and survival 224
17. Contributors
Yuri Biondi, Conservatoire National des Arts et Métiers (CNAM), France
Sue Bowden, University of York, UK
Michael Dietrich, University of Sheffield, UK
Elizabeth Garnsey, University of Cambridge, UK
Paul Heffernan, University of Cambridge, UK
David Higgins, University of York, UK
Werner Hölzl, Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Austria
Stavros Ioannides, Panteion University, Athens, Greece
Jackie Krafft, CNRS-GREDEG, University of Nice, France
Pavel Luksha, Higher School of Economics, Moscow, Russia; University of
Hertfordshire, UK
Bart Nooteboom, Tilburg University, The Netherlands
Christopher Price, University of York, UK
Erik Stam, University of Cambridge, UK; Utrecht University, The Nether-
lands; Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena, Germany
Hassan Yazdifar, University of Sheffield, UK
19. This volume emerged from the inaugural workshop of the European Net-
work on the Economics of the Firm (ENEF) held at the University of
Sheffield, UK, in July 2004. The guiding philosophy of this network was a
perceived need to facilitate a loose coordination of academic research on
the economics of the firm that was not constrained by a rigid view of the
nature of economics. In particular the network was guided by the following
principles:
1 To support and promote discussion, research contacts and collaborative
work among primarily European university academics on the economics
of the firm.
2 This research activity covers both theoretical and empirical work on the
firm.
3 The primary intellectual focus of ENEF involves a research agenda that
views the firm not simply as an economic entity. This implies that econ-
omics should be viewed as the base from which interdisciplinary work is
undertaken.
4 This interdisciplinary work does not involve a dominant economic
methodology taking over other disciplines but instead using the insights
offered to develop new and richer frameworks for understanding the
nature of the firm than those traditionally on offer within economics.
Anyone interested in this network might want to look at the website: www.
enef.group.shef.ac.uk.
Such was the enthusiasm generated at the Sheffield workshop that it was
decided to build on the work undertaken by holding an annual workshop.
ENEF2 was held at Erasmus University, Rotterdam, in September 2005, and
at the time of writing plans are being developed for ENEF3 to be held at the
University of Nice in 2006. In addition it was felt that the work being under-
taken was sufficiently interesting that a wider audience might be interested.
So, the main Sheffield workshop organiser became an editor and Routledge
(Taylor and Francis) were sufficiently interested in the project to offer a
publication contract.
Preface
20. xiv Preface
Eight of the eleven chapters in this volume are developed from papers that
were originally written for the Sheffield workshop, i.e. chapters 2, 3, 6, 7, 8, 9,
10 and 11. Chapters 4 and 5 are authored by people who became interested in
ENEF after the first workshop. They have been included by the editor
because they complement the guiding philosophy of the volume and the con-
tent of other chapters. Chapter 1 has been specifically written for this volume
to provide this guiding philosophy and context for the various essays. To
some extent this introduction can also be viewed as an attempt to develop an
ENEF manifesto. But this suggested status to Chapter 1 does not reflect any
agreement by the various authors in this volume, let alone the academics
associated with ENEF. Although the content of this first chapter has been
improved by comments offered by the other contributors, the editor is solely
responsible for its content. If anyone associated with ENEF disagrees with
what is written here, then I will offer a weak apology but equally I would be
happy because the content of this volume will have stimulated academic
debate.
The editor has been reliant on the help and support of many people with-
out which this project, and the wider ENEF initiative of which it is a part,
would have been much more difficult than it turned out to be. Formal thanks
are therefore due to many people. First, the authors of the various essays
have responded to my comments in the positive way that was intended. In
addition everyone submitted final copy by the deadline. This is a first in my
experience! Also I would like to thank Abhi, Donna, and Mohamed who
interrupted their PhD research to help organise the 2004 ENEF workshop
and also coped with equanimity when confronted with my worries as the
workshop approached and took place. Also as the main ENEF organiser I
would like to thank everyone who has been remarkably enthusiastic about
the network and those who attended the two workshops to date. But in
particular I have to put on record my appreciation for the efforts of Erik,
Albert, Jackie and Jacques for workshop organisation. Finally, I would like
to thank the University of Sheffield for funding the 2004 ENEF workshop
and for providing an academic environment that allows me to undertake
research on the economics of the firm informed by an interdisciplinary
perspective.
To all concerned I hope this volume reflects your efforts.
Michael Dietrich
21. 1 Introduction
The firm in an interdisciplinary
context
Michael Dietrich
It is now somewhat standard to recognise that the firm is one of the funda-
mental institutions in a market economy. Not, of course, the black-box firm
of equilibrium price theory, but real firms that enact strategies, manage the
creation and acquisition of information and knowledge, and that have inter-
nal organisational structures and processes. In terms of modern economics,
these real firms, at the core of a market economy, are analysed by writers
as different as, for example, Edith Penrose, Herbert Simon and Oliver
Williamson. But the fundamental importance of the firm is not merely a
modern observation. It can be traced back into the writing of, for example,
Marx and Schumpeter.
The essays presented in this volume continue this tradition, emphasising
the fundamental institutional significance of the firm, without which a
market economy cannot function. They are all original contributions to the
economics of the firm. While the various chapters cover different aspects of
this overall topic they are united by two common themes: that an adequate
economics of the firm can be usefully informed by an interdisciplinary
perspective and that much existing writing on the firm is overly static. This
introduction will set out the basis and background of these themes and, in
particular, explore the ways in which they are interlinked in their application
to the firm. For instance, for reasons set out below, an interdisciplinary
perspective on the firm gains a comparative advantage in dynamic circum-
stances. Stressing the importance of an interdisciplinary perspective can, of
course, mean different things to different people: perhaps even more so than
emphasising the importance of non-comparative static reasoning. Hence,
the discussion here will initially consider interdisciplinary economics in
general before applying this to the firm. To some extent what is meant by
‘interdisciplinary’ depends on how we define an intellectual discipline in
the first place. To identify the possibilities involved here, and also locate
the background to the contributions in this volume, we can initially use
Figure 1.1.
In Figure 1.1 the idea of an intellectual discipline is defined in terms of two
features: an analytical focus and an analytical method. The possible com-
binations involved are illustrated, for economics, with a few suggestive
22. 2 Michael Dietrich
examples. In philosophical terms the focus and method of a subject can be
viewed as, respectively, the ontological and epistemological bases involved,
both of which are necessary for an effective consideration of any subject
(Lawson, 1997). The analytical focus of a subject involves its domain of refer-
ence, for example:
Economics: the study of the production, distribution and consumption
of goods and services.
Psychology: the study of mental processes and behaviour.
Sociology: the study of the relationships between people living in
groups.
Politics: the study of the ways in which a country is governed.
To some extent these broad subject domains are artificial aggregates. For
example, within economics it is common to distinguish between the micro
and macro domains of the subject. Furthermore, either of these domains are
also aggregates; so, for instance, microeconomics can be divided into con-
sumer economics, the economics of the firm, etc. A complete depiction of
the domain of any subject can involve a level of detail that is not necessary
for the current discussion; not least because Figure 1.1 is only intended for
illustrative purposes. More fundamentally, there would appear to be no
unique taxonomy for any subject. Instead any detailed taxonomy would
seem to depend on the use to which it is being put.
Turning to the analytical method, or epistemological base, of a subject,
this is also an artificial aggregate as few subjects have a single or dominant
method. Within economics, and also other subjects, we commonly distin-
guish between theoretical and empirical work with different characteristic
methods involved. In addition, further disaggregation of both theoretical
and empirical work can involve different traditions. For instance, we have
Figure 1.1 A taxonomy of inderdisciplinary economics.
Analytical method
Economics Psychology Sociology Politics
Economics Core
economics
Experimental
economics,
Behavioural
theory
Economic
sociology
Political
economy
Analytical
focus
Psychology Core
psychology
Sociology Becker
(1981)
Core
sociology
Politics Buchanan
and Tullock
(1962)
Core
politics
23. Introduction: the firm in an interdisciplinary context 3
neoclassical and Austrian economic theory. But as with a subject’s domain,
the level of detail shown in Figure 1.1 is useful for illustrative purposes.
At this point we can recognise two important complexities concerned
with any discussion of the analytical methods of a subject. First, there is no
obvious single taxonomy of analytical methods within any discipline. Take,
for instance, the relevant (for this volume) case of transaction cost econ-
omics (TCE). The core analytical method involved here is based on the
comparison of alternative institutional arrangements (or governance struc-
ture in transaction cost language) using a cost economising lens to assess the
relevance of arrangements in particular circumstances (see, for example,
Williamson, 1985). This analytical method is then used with a particular
focus: for example, the study of the firm. But it is by no means obvious
whether TCE is an analytical method in its own right. On the one hand,
Williamson (1985) argues that TCE is complementary to neoclassical econ-
omics. The implication here is that the methods are consistent but different.
On the other hand, it is common to view TCE as part of the same theoretical
project as neoclassical economics (Hodgson, 1993; Lawson, 1994; Dietrich,
1994). The logic here is that both TCE and neoclassical theory have the same
methodological principles involving, for example, individualism, atomism
and a comparative static method. A key issue involves the same complexity
as was just highlighted when discussing analytical focus: there may be no
single taxonomy because the particular taxonomy involved can depend on
the particular research agenda. So, for example, at a sufficient level of detail,
and from a perspective that describes analytical tools, TCE is different from
standard neoclassical theory because, for example, it recognises a form of
bounded rationality that results in incomplete contracting. But if we move
to a lower level of detail and move beyond description of tools to (often
implicit) analytical methods the two approaches have the same roots.
The second complexity that we can recognise about the analytical
methods adopted by a subject is a point suggested by Groenewegen and
Vromen (1996): particular theories can be silent on particular issues. To give
an example, the relevance of which will become clear in later discussion, a
theory built on a comparative static method can make statements (at most)
about the direction of change from one equilibrium to another, but it cannot
make statements about the dynamics of the change process. In short,
analytical frameworks are silent on particular issues. In terms of Figure 1.1, if
we imagine a fully specified, and detailed, grid (rather than the illustrative
aggregate grid shown) some cells will be empty. An important principle is
that these empty cells should not be seen as reflecting an analytical failure.
If we conjecture that ‘formulating an all-embracing, all-condition theory is
infeasible’ (Groenewegen and Vromen, 1996: 372), it follows that empty
cells are a pragmatic response to our intellectual bounded rationality. But
even ignoring our bounded rationality, there is the danger that a theory that
claims to be universal can degenerate into tautology. Take, for example,
the view expressed by Hayek (1948: 33): ‘the tautologies, of which formal
24. 4 Michael Dietrich
equilibrium analysis in economics essentially consist [require] definite state-
ments about how knowledge is acquired and communicated’. Alternatively
we can cite the not inconsistent view expressed by Joan Robinson (1964: 48):
‘Utility is a metaphysical concept of impregnable circularity; utility is the
quality in commodities that makes individuals want to buy them, and the fact
that individuals want to buy commodities shows that they have utility’
(emphasis in original).
Both writers, although coming from very different analytical traditions,
stress the tautological or circular nature of formal equilibrium economics.
The removal of such analytical tautology or circularity requires inputs from
external methods or focus. From this perspective, being silent on particular
issues, i.e. being explicit about what a framework cannot say, is a necessary
characteristic of adequate theory. Groenewegen and Vromen (1996) link the
incomplete nature of theoretical frameworks to the importance of accepting
theoretical pluralism. We can stress a similar point and link empty cells in a
diagram such as Figure 1.1 as a necessary condition for the relevance of an
interdisciplinary perspective on a particular issue. In terms of the subject
matter presented in this volume, if a narrowly defined economics of the firm,
perhaps involving different analytical economic methods, results in all the
relevant cells in the intellectual grid being non-empty, there is no obvious
comparativeadvantageforusingeconomicsasthebaseforaninterdisciplinary
perspective. Hence interdisciplinary approaches to the firm are based on the
presumption that empty cells exist in the relevant part of the intellectual grid.
Given these background points, we can now suggest that along the main
diagonal of the grid in Figure 1.1 we define core subjects. In terms of the
language presented by Lakatos (see, for example, Blaug, 1980), this main
diagonal defines the hard core of different scientific research programmes.
We should, of course recognise that some authors, for example Rosenberg
(1986), deny that Lakatos’s framework can be applied to economics as it
gives the subject a sense of scientific content that it does not deserve. In
addition we can recognise the complication identified by Groenewegen and
Vromen (1996). The hard core of a scientific research programme is defined
in terms of fundamental propositions that make up the heart of any frame-
work. As such they are not subject to empirical falsification because they are
shielded by the general framework. But how can we tell when we compare
two different theoretical approaches whether they belong to the same or
different scientific research programmes? This problem exists because, as
was stressed above, the rows and columns in a grid such as Figure 1.1 have no
natural taxonomy but instead the particular taxonomy can reflect (a) the
level of aggregation and (b) the purpose for which the taxonomy is being
used. The implication here is that the hard core of any discipline, i.e. the
main diagonal of Figure 1.1, may be subject to different definitions and
hence is likely to be the subject of debate rather than simply acceptance. In
terms of interdisciplinary work, this contested nature of a subject’s hard core
might result in differing perceptions of its relevance and acceptability.
25. Introduction: the firm in an interdisciplinary context 5
Ignoring the complications hinted at in the previous paragraph, we can
now define two types of interdisciplinary study that correspond to connect-
ing along rows or columns of cells off the main diagonal of Figure 1.1. Down
the columns of the grid interdisciplinary work is defined in terms of applying
a dominant method outside a normal subject focus. In this tradition we can
identify Becker’s (1981) analysis of the family and Buchanan and Tullock’s
(1962) public choice theory. Along the off main diagonal rows of Figure 1.1
we have a more eclectic interdisciplinary world in which the analytical focus
of a subject is given priority. The necessary reasoning here is that, for
example, the firm or consumer behaviour is inherently interdisciplinary and
so requires different analytical methods for a complete understanding. The
essays presented in this volume are based on interdisciplinary connections
that involve such row linkages. Before giving an introduction to this work,
the arguments presented above will be rendered more concrete by briefly
considering two examples that involve the analysis of the firm: Oliver
Williamson’s transaction cost theory and John Dunning’s OLI framework.
Among other things, these two examples will allow the development of
linkages between interdisciplinary approaches to the firm and non-steady-
state analysis.
Example 1: Oliver Williamson’s transaction cost theory
The basic principles of Williamson’s transaction cost approach to the firm
are set out in many places, perhaps most famously in his 1975 and 1985
volumes. For current purposes the development presented in Williamson
(1996) is useful. In the latter work discussion is organised around a diagram,
a slightly adapted version of which is reproduced here as Figure 1.2. The
primary analytical focus are institutions of governance (e.g. inter-firm con-
tracts, corporations, bureaus, non-profits, etc.), shown here in the centre of
Figure 1.2. These are explained in terms of two general factors: the institu-
tional environment and individual behavioural attributes. ‘Secondary effects
are drawn as dashed arrows’ (Williamson, 1996: 17–18, emphasis added).
Changes in the institutional environment, either historically or geographic-
ally, are argued to shift the relative costs of different forms of governance
and so lead to micro-institutional change. The key behavioural assumptions
are bounded rationality and opportunism. Different form of governance are
seen to evolve to mitigate the adverse effects of these behavioural assump-
tions. An important intervening variable here is the degree of human or
physical asset specificity.
A moment’s consideration of this transaction cost logic will reveal the now
commonly recognised characteristic that the framework is a comparative
static approach to institutions (for example, Dietrich, 1994). Among other
things, this comparative static characteristic implies that the structure and
functioning of the institutional environment is common knowledge to all
actors. Note that this common knowledge is a matter of belief as well as
27. PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK
To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free
distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or
any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.
Section 1. General Terms of Use and
Redistributing Project Gutenberg™
electronic works
1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree
to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be
bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund
from the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in
paragraph 1.E.8.
1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be
used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people
who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a
few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic
works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement.
See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.
28. 1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the
collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the
individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the
United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law
in the United States and you are located in the United States, we do
not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing,
performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the
work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of
course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™
mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely
sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of
this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name associated
with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of this
agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its attached
full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without charge
with others.
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the
terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.
1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:
1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other
immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must
appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™
work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears,
or with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is
accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed:
29. This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United
States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with
almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away
or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License
included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you
are not located in the United States, you will have to check the
laws of the country where you are located before using this
eBook.
1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived
from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a
notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright
holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the
United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must
comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through
1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.
1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted
with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted
with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning
of this work.
1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project
Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a
part of this work or any other work associated with Project
Gutenberg™.
1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this
electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1
30. with active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or
expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or
a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original
“Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must
include the full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in
paragraph 1.E.1.
1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,
performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.
1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing
access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
31. about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who
notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt
that s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project
Gutenberg™ License. You must require such a user to return or
destroy all copies of the works possessed in a physical medium
and discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of
Project Gutenberg™ works.
• You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of
any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in
the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90
days of receipt of the work.
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™
electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.
1.F.
1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend
considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe
and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating
the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may
be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to,
incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a
copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or
32. damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer
codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment.
1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except for
the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph 1.F.3,
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner of the
Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party distributing a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this agreement, disclaim
all liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including legal
fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR
NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF WARRANTY OR
BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH
1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK
OWNER, AND ANY DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL
NOT BE LIABLE TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT,
CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF
YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE.
1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you
discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving
it, you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by
sending a written explanation to the person you received the work
from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must
return the medium with your written explanation. The person or
entity that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide
a replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work
electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to
give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in
lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may
demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the
problem.
1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
33. INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied
warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted
by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.
1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the Foundation,
the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the Foundation,
anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in
accordance with this agreement, and any volunteers associated with
the production, promotion and distribution of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works, harmless from all liability, costs and expenses,
including legal fees, that arise directly or indirectly from any of the
following which you do or cause to occur: (a) distribution of this or
any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b) alteration, modification, or
additions or deletions to any Project Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any
Defect you cause.
Section 2. Information about the Mission
of Project Gutenberg™
Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers.
It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and
donations from people in all walks of life.
Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the
assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
34. remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a
secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help,
see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at
www.gutenberg.org.
Section 3. Information about the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.
The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,
Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact
Section 4. Information about Donations to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation
Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without
widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can
be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the
widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many
35. small donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to
maintaining tax exempt status with the IRS.
The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating
charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and
keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in
locations where we have not received written confirmation of
compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of
compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate.
While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where
we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no
prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in
such states who approach us with offers to donate.
International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make
any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.
Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.
Section 5. General Information About
Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project
Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be
freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and
distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of
volunteer support.
36. Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed
editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in
the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not
necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper
edition.
Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.
This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™,
including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how
to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.
57. Welcome to our website – the ideal destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. With a mission to inspire endlessly, we offer a
vast collection of books, ranging from classic literary works to
specialized publications, self-development books, and children's
literature. Each book is a new journey of discovery, expanding
knowledge and enriching the soul of the reade
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
Let us accompany you on the journey of exploring knowledge and
personal growth!
ebookultra.com