Ecosystem Services In Agricultural And Urban Landscapes Wratten Stephen Etal
Ecosystem Services In Agricultural And Urban Landscapes Wratten Stephen Etal
Ecosystem Services In Agricultural And Urban Landscapes Wratten Stephen Etal
Ecosystem Services In Agricultural And Urban Landscapes Wratten Stephen Etal
1. Ecosystem Services In Agricultural And Urban
Landscapes Wratten Stephen Etal download
https://ebookbell.com/product/ecosystem-services-in-agricultural-
and-urban-landscapes-wratten-stephen-etal-4303450
Explore and download more ebooks at ebookbell.com
2. Here are some recommended products that we believe you will be
interested in. You can click the link to download.
Regional Assessment Of Climate Change In The Mediterranean Volume 2
Agriculture Forests And Ecosystem Services And People 1st Edition
Monia Santini
https://ebookbell.com/product/regional-assessment-of-climate-change-
in-the-mediterranean-volume-2-agriculture-forests-and-ecosystem-
services-and-people-1st-edition-monia-santini-4406900
Tropical Forest Ecosystem Services In Improving Livelihoods For Local
Communities 1st Edition Zaiton Samdin Editor
https://ebookbell.com/product/tropical-forest-ecosystem-services-in-
improving-livelihoods-for-local-communities-1st-edition-zaiton-samdin-
editor-48844074
Sustaining Biodiversity And Ecosystem Services In Soils And Sediments
Scientific Committee On Problems Of The Environment Scope Series 1st
Edition Diana H Wall
https://ebookbell.com/product/sustaining-biodiversity-and-ecosystem-
services-in-soils-and-sediments-scientific-committee-on-problems-of-
the-environment-scope-series-1st-edition-diana-h-wall-2178724
A Catalogue Of Ecosystem Services In Slovakia Benefits To Society 1st
Ed Peter Mederly
https://ebookbell.com/product/a-catalogue-of-ecosystem-services-in-
slovakia-benefits-to-society-1st-ed-peter-mederly-22505222
3. Payment Schemes For Forest Ecosystem Services In China Policy
Practices And Performance Dan Liang
https://ebookbell.com/product/payment-schemes-for-forest-ecosystem-
services-in-china-policy-practices-and-performance-dan-liang-4668764
Estuaries A Lifeline Of Ecosystem Services In The Western Indian Ocean
1st Edition Salif Diop
https://ebookbell.com/product/estuaries-a-lifeline-of-ecosystem-
services-in-the-western-indian-ocean-1st-edition-salif-diop-5482790
Planning For Ecosystem Services In Cities 1st Ed 2020 Davide Geneletti
https://ebookbell.com/product/planning-for-ecosystem-services-in-
cities-1st-ed-2020-davide-geneletti-10797130
Role Of Ecosystem Services In Sustainable Food Systems Rusinamhodzi
https://ebookbell.com/product/role-of-ecosystem-services-in-
sustainable-food-systems-rusinamhodzi-10818914
Recommendations On Payments For Ecosystem Services In Integrated Water
Resources Management Illustrated Edition United Nations
https://ebookbell.com/product/recommendations-on-payments-for-
ecosystem-services-in-integrated-water-resources-management-
illustrated-edition-united-nations-1945760
6. Ecosystem Services in
Agricultural and Urban
Landscapes
Edited by
Steve Wratten
Bio-Protection Research Centre
Lincoln University, New Zealand
Harpinder Sandhu
School of the Environment
Flinders University, Australia
Ross Cullen
Department of Accounting, Economics and Finance
Lincoln University, New Zealand
Robert Costanza
Crawford School of Public Policy
Australian National University, Australia
A John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., Publication
8. Contents
Contributors xi
Reviewers xiv
Foreword xv
Introduction xvi
Steve Wratten, Harpinder Sandhu, Ross Cullen and Robert Costanza
Part A: Scene Setting 1
1 Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 3
Harpinder Sandhu and Steve Wratten
Abstract 3
Introduction 4
What are ecosystem services? 4
Ecosystem functions, goods and services 5
The ES framework 6
Engineered systems 7
Agricultural systems 7
Urban systems 10
ES and their interactions in engineered systems 11
2 Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem
Services: Inextricable Linkages between Wetlands
and Agricultural Systems 16
Onil Banerjee, Neville D. Crossman and Rudolf S. de Groot
Abstract 16
Introduction 17
9. vi Contents
Linking ecosystem function with ecosystem service 18
Wetlands 19
Wetland functions 20
Wetland–agricultural systems interactions 22
Some research challenges 24
Understanding complexity and resilience 24
Trade-offs 25
3 Key Ideas and Concepts from Economics
for Understanding the Roles and Value
of Ecosystem Services 28
Pamela Kaval and Ramesh Baskaran
Abstract 28
How can ecosystem services be valued? 28
Ecosystem service valuation methodologies 31
Revealed preference methods 32
Stated preference methods 32
Other methods 33
How ecosystem services have been measured in the past 34
Ecosystem service valuation study recommendations 37
Conclusions 39
Part B: Ecosystem Services in Three Settings 43
4 Viticulture can be Modified to Provide
Multiple Ecosystem Services 45
Sofia Orre-Gordon, Marco Jacometti, Jean Tompkins
and Steve Wratten
Abstract 45
Introduction 45
Enhancing CBC in vineyards 46
Leafrollers and Botrytis cinerea in the vineyards 48
Habitat modification to enhance naturally occurring
pest control 48
Floral resource supplementation as a form of
habitat modification 48
Mulch application as a form of habitat modification 49
Combining two forms of habitat modification 51
The deployment of herbivore-induced plant volatiles
as a form of habitat modification 51
Habitat modification may provide further
ecosystem services 52
The future 55
10. Contents vii
5 Aquaculture and Ecosystem Services:
Reframing the Environmental and Social Debate 58
Corinne Baulcomb
Abstract 58
Introduction 58
Aquaculture and the environment 59
A typology of aquaculture operations and the link
to ecosystem services 60
Inland production systems 64
Overview 64
Case study 1: hypothetical integrated agriculture–aquaculture
carp polyculture 65
Case study 2: hypothetical inland marine
shrimp cultivation 68
Marine and coastal-based production systems 71
Overview 71
Case study 3: hypothetic nearshore, intensive and raft-based
shellfish cultivation 72
Case study 4: hypothetical ‘best-case’ offshore
aquaculture cultivation 75
The value of a complementary life-cycle approach 75
Conclusion 77
6 Urban Landscapes and Ecosystem Services 83
Jürgen Breuste, Dagmar Haase and Thomas Elmqvist
Abstract 83
Growing urban landscapes 83
The process of urbanization 83
Urbanization, biodiversity and ecosystems 86
Urbanization and management of ecosystems –
challenges 86
Urban ecosystem services 87
What are urban ecosystem services? 87
Classification of UES 88
Land use – basic information on human influence
on ecosystem services 88
Urban green – carrier of UES 89
Types of urban green space 89
Recreation 90
Climate regulation 91
Biodiversity 94
Carbon mitigation 95
Rapid growth of soil sealing – destruction of UES
and its avoidance 95
11. viii Contents
Climate change – challenges for UES 97
Increase in temperature 98
Precipitation 99
Sea level rise 100
UES in urban landscape planning 100
Part C: Measuring and Monitoring Ecosystem Services
at Multiple Levels 105
7 Scale-dependent Ecosystem Service 107
Yangjian Zhang, Claus Holzapfel and Xiaoyong Yuan
Abstract 107
Introduction 107
Scale 108
Ecosystem service is scale dependent 108
The ecosystem beneficiary is scale dependent 109
Ecosystem service measurement is scale dependent 109
Ecosystem service management decision making is scale dependent 112
Ecosystem service types 112
Ecosystem service studies need to consider scale 113
Case studies 114
Liberty State Park Interior 115
Qinghai-Tibet plateau 117
Conclusions 118
8 Experimental Assessment of Ecosystem Services
in Agriculture 122
Harpinder Sandhu, John Porter and Steve Wratten
Abstract 122
Introduction 122
ES in agroecosystems 123
Provisioning goods and services 124
Supporting services 124
Regulating services 124
Cultural services 124
Field-scale assessment of ES 127
The combined food and energy system 128
New Zealand arable farmland 129
Scenarios of production and ES in agroecosystems 131
The ethnocentric systems 131
The technocentric systems 131
The ecocentric systems 131
The ecotechnocentric systems 132
The sustaincentric systems 132
Conclusions 133
12. Contents ix
Part D: Designing Ecological Systems
to Deliver Ecosystem Services 137
9 Towards Multifunctional Agricultural Landscapes
for the Upper Midwest Region of the USA 139
Nicholas Jordan and Keith Douglass Warner
Abstract 139
Introduction 139
Multifunctional agroecosystems 140
Re-designed agricultural landscapes for the Upper Midwest 141
Moving forward on design and implementation
of multifunctional landscapes for the Upper Midwest 142
Theory of change: a social–ecological system model for
increasing multifunctionality of agricultural landscapes 143
Focal level: enterprise development via ‘virtuous circles’ 143
Subsystem level: collaborative social learning
for multifunctional agriculture 147
Supersystem level: re-visioning the social metabolism
of American agriculture 148
Applying the theory of change: the Koda Energy fuelshed project 149
Enterprise development 150
Agroecological partnership 152
Re-shaping public opinion and policy 153
Conclusions 153
10 Supply Chain Management and the Delivery of
Ecosystems Services in Manufacturing 157
Mary Haropoulou, Clive Smallman and Jack Radford
Abstract 157
Towards the sustainable economic production of goods
and services? 158
Ecological economics and supply chain management:
a review and synthesis 158
Conventional economic and ecologically economic production 158
Conventional SCM: economic efficiency through distribution
network configuration and strategy 160
Green SCM: the economic inefficiency of waste 161
Sustainable SCM: connecting social, economic
and ecological performance 162
Enabling ecological economics: SSCM 163
A case in point: ‘what do we do with it now?’ 165
WYM background 166
The economic production of wool yarn 167
Goods 168
Wastes 169
13. x Contents
Ecological services and amenities 169
Natural capital 169
Human capital 171
Social capital 173
Manufactured capital 174
Community and individual well-being 175
Discussion 175
Conclusion 176
11 Market-based Instruments and Ecosystem Services:
Opportunity and Experience to Date 178
Stuart M. Whitten and Anthea Coggan
Abstract 178
Introduction 179
Market-based instruments: definition and preconditions 180
Types of MBIs 180
Examples of MBIs for ecosystem services 184
Price-based MBIs 184
Quantity-based MBIs 186
Market friction MBIs 188
The brave new world of ecosystem markets 189
Designing effective MBIs 189
Where to next in the brave new world of markets
for ecosystem services? 190
Epilogue: Equitable and Sustainable Systems 194
Steve Wratten, Harpinder Sandhu, Ross Cullen and Robert Costanza
Index 196
14. Contributors
Onil Banerjee
CSIRO Ecosystem Sciences
PMB2
Glen Osmond
South Australia 5064
Australia
Ramesh Baskaran
Faculty of Commerce
PO Box 84
Lincoln University
Christchurch 7647
New Zealand
Corinne Baulcomb
Scottish Agricultural College
West Mains Road
Edinburgh EH9 3JG
Scotland
Jürgen Breuste
Department of Geography/Geology
University Salzburg
Hellbrunnerstrasse 34
A 5020 Salzburg
Austria
Anthea Coggan
CSIRO Ecosystem Sciences
GPO Box 2583
Brisbane 4102
Queensland
Australia
Robert Costanza
Crawford School of Public Policy
Crawford Building (132)
Australian National University
Canberra ACT 0200
Australia
Neville D. Crossman
CSIRO Ecosystem Sciences
PMB2
Glen Osmond
South Australia 5064
Australia
Ross Cullen
Department of Accounting,
Economics and Finance
PO Box 84
Lincoln University 7647
Christchurch
New Zealand
15. xii Contributors
Rudolf S. de Groot
Environmental Systems Analysis
Group
Wageningen University
PO Box 47
6700 AA Wageningen
the Netherlands
Thomas Elmqvist
Department of Systems Ecology and
Stockholm Resilience Centre
Stockholm University
SE-106 91 Stockholm
Sweden
Dagmar Haase
Institute of Geography
Humboldt-University Berlin
Berlin
Germany
and
Helmholtz Centre for Environmental
Research GmbH-UFZ
Permoserstraße 15
04318 Leipzig
Germany
Mary Haropoulou
Faculty of Commerce
Lincoln University
PO Box 84
Christchurch 7647
New Zealand
Claus Holzapfel
Department of Biological Sciences
Rutgers University
Newark
New Jersey 07102
USA
Marco Jacometti
Bio-Protection Research Centre
PO Box 84
Lincoln University
Lincoln 7647
New Zealand
Nicholas Jordan
Agronomy and Plant Genetics
Department
University of Minnesota
411 Borlaug Hall
1991 Buford Circle
St. Paul
Minnesota 55018
USA
Pamela Kaval
Havelock North
New Zealand and
Marylhurst University
Oregon
USA
Sofia Orre-Gordon
Barbara Hardy Institute
University of South Australia
GPO Box 2471
Adelaide
South Australia 5001
Australia
and
Bio-Protection Research Centre
PO Box 84
Lincoln University
Lincoln 7647
New Zealand
John Porter
Department of Plant and
Environmental Science
Faculty of Life Sciences
University of Copenhagen (KU-LIFE)
HøjbakkegårdAlle 9
2630 Taastrup
Denmark
Jack Radford
Lincoln University
Faculty of Commerce
PO Box 84
Christchurch 7647
New Zealand
16. Contributors xiii
Harpinder Sandhu
School of the Environment
Flinders University
GPO Box 2100
Adelaide SA 5001
Australia
Clive Smallman
University of Western Sydney
School of Business
Locked Bag 1797
Penrith NSW 2751
Australia
Jean Tompkins
Bio-Protection Research Centre
PO Box 84
Lincoln University
Lincoln 7647
New Zealand
Keith Douglass Warner
Center for Science, Technology and
Society
Santa Clara University
500 El Camino Real
Santa Clara
California 95053
USA
Stuart M. Whitten
CSIRO Ecosystem Sciences
GPO Box 1700
Canberra
ACT 2601
Australia
Steve Wratten
Bio-Protection Research Centre
PO Box 84
Lincoln University
Lincoln 7647
New Zealand
Xiaoyong Yuan
Key Laboratory of Ecosystem
Network Observation and
Modelling
Institute of Geographic Sciences
and Natural Resources Research
Chinese Academy of Sciences
Beijing 100101
China
Yangjian Zhang
Key Laboratory of Ecosystem
Network Observation and
Modelling
Institute of Geographic Sciences
and Natural Resources
Research
Chinese Academy of Sciences
Beijing 100101
China
17. Reviewers
Editors acknowledge the contribution of following reviewers for their helpful
comments and suggestions that helped to improve clarity of the chapters.
t Andrew Davidson, SEQ Catchments Ltd, Brisbane, Queensland, Australia.
t Brenda Lin, CSIRO Marine & Atmospheric Research, Melbourne, Victoria,
Australia.
t Francis Turkelboom, Research Institute for Forest and Nature (INBO), Brussels,
Belgium.
t Gupta Vadakattu, CSIRO Ecosystem Sciences, Adelaide, Australia.
t Uday Nidumolu, CSIRO Ecosystem Sciences, Adelaide, Australia.
t Yuki Takatsuka, Temple University, Japan.
18. Foreword
It is now becoming clear that an ecosystem approach is the most appropriate
methodology to ensure sustainable food security and conservation of urban
landscapes. Hence this book by Steve Wratten and colleagues is a timely one. At
the time of the origin of agriculture or settled cultivation over 10000 years ago,
the early cultivators, mostly women, adopted an ecosystem approach for
standardizing cultivation practices, as well as in the choice of crops. For example,
in the state of Tamil Nadu in India, ancient scholars divided the state into five
major agroecological zones. These were: coastal, hill, arid, semiarid and wet
zones. Agricultural practices were followed according to the specific ecosystem,
keeping in view the extent of rainfall, the incidence of sunlight and the moisture-
holding capacity of the soil. From the naturally occurring biodiversity, plants
with specialized adaptations, such as halophytes for coastal areas and xerophytes
for the arid zone, were identified and cultivated.
An ecosystem approach to soil and water management helps to ensure
successful agriculture. Water security is important not only for agriculture and
industry, but also for domestic needs and for ecosystem maintenance. The book
covers all aspects of soil health conservation and enhancement, and water and
biodiversity management. Ecosystem-based agriculture ensures stability of
production and at the same time enhances the coping capacity of farming
families to meet the challenges of climate change. I therefore hope that this book
will be widely read and used both by farming practitioners and policy makers. We
owe a deep debt of gratitude to the editorial team for their dedication to the
cause of sustainable agriculture and food security.
M.S. Swaminathan
PROF MS SWAMINATHAN
Member of Parliament (Rajya Sabha)
Emeritus Chairman, MS Swaminathan Research Foundation
Third Cross Street, Taramani Institutional Area
Chennai - 600 113 (India)
19. Ecosystem goods and services provide mankind with most necessities of life and
survival. They include such processes as biological control of pests, weeds and
diseases, pollination of crops, amelioration of flooding and wind erosion, provi-
sion of food (including fisheries), the hydro-geochemical cycle, capture of carbon
by plants and by soil and providing settings for much of the world’s tourism.
A pivotal paper by Robert Costanza and colleagues written in 1997 used a range
of methods to quantify ecosystem services (ES) and to estimate their total economic
value worldwide. The estimate was $US33 trillion (1012
) per annum. Costanza
et al.’s valuation stimulated much debate, including the suggestion that $US33
trillion is ‘a serious underestimate of infinity’. In other words, some people believe
that mankind cannot survive without ES, so evaluating it is futile. However, ES
world-wide are being degraded more rapidly than ever before and this degrada-
tion poses serious threats to quality of life and therefore to modern economies.
The Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MEA) pointed to the very high rate of ES
loss and the consequences for global stability if that rate continues.
In the same year as Costanza et. al.’s paper, Gretchen Daily, of Stanford
University, USA, published a key book entitled Nature’s Services. Those two
publications led to a change in the paradigm within which mankind’s depend-
ence on living things is viewed. However, Costanza and Daily concentrated
largely on ‘natural’ ecosystems and biomes, such as boreal forests, coral reefs
and mangroves. They did not concentrate on the many ecosystem services
provided by highly modified or managed areas, such as farmland and cities.
However, ES in these systems are of vital significance to the survival and pro-
ductivity of those systems, as more than 50% of the world’s population lives in
cities and this proportion is increasing by 1–2% per annum. The ‘ecological
footprint’ of cities is enormous and, with cities such as Shanghai forecast to
grow from 17 million to 70 million over the next decade, the extent to which
Introduction
20. Introduction xvii
cities can support themselves in even a limited number of ecosystem functions is
likely to continue to decline.
ES underpin life on earth, provide major inputs to many sectors of the econ-
omy and support our lifestyles. This book explores the role that ES play in two
settings where humans have actively modified ecological systems: agriculture and
urban areas. It addresses the hitherto under-estimation of ES in farmland and cit-
ies and explores ways to develop concepts, policies and methods of evaluating
ES, as well as the ways in which ES in these systems can be maintained and
enhanced. This approach is timely and will be of high scientific and political
value, especially given that the MEA disappeared from world media and discus-
sion very soon after it was announced, because of a widely-held but increasingly
erroneous belief that technology will rescue mankind as the environmental
equivalent of ‘peak oil’ is approached.
The book is divided into four parts with a series of self-contained chapters con-
nected by the overall aim of the book. The Introduction is written by the editorial
team to highlight the importance of ES in natural and managed landscapes. Part
A sets the scene by introducing the concept of ES in managed landscapes such as
farmland and cities. Chapter 1 explains the concept of ES and their importance.
Chapter 2 provides links between ecosystem function to economic benefits by
exploring changes in these due to change in land and water management. Chapter
3 deals with key concepts and methods to value ES. Part B provides information
on ES in three different managed systems: viticulture, aquaculture and urban
areas. Chapter 4 discusses ES associated with viticulture and techniques to
enhance them. Chapter 5 explores environmental and social impacts of aquacul-
ture and maps them through an ES typology. Chapter 6 develops the concept of
ES in urban planning and management. It discusses ES relevant to urban areas
and their importance in planning and management of cities. Part C focuses on
measuring and monitoring ES at different scales. Chapter 7 develops this theme
by also exploring ES at a range of spatial scales with case studies ranging from
landscape, to regions and biomes. Chapter 8 provides frameworks to evaluate ES
using ‘bottom-up’ field-scale measurements. It also discusses scenarios for balanc-
ing production and ES on farmland. Part D discusses design of ecological systems
for the delivery of ES. In this Part, Chapter 9 explores the concept of multifunc-
tional agriculture in the Upper Midwest region of the US. Chapter 10 discusses
the role of ES through supply chain management in a wool enterprise. Chapter
11 analyses the concept of market-based instruments by providing examples to
improve the delivery of ES. The epilogue examines prospects for the future and
the role of ES in contributing to sustainable agriculture and cities.
We believe this book will be useful to senior undergraduates, postgraduates,
environmental economists, agriculturalists, theoretical and applied ecologists,
local and regional planners and government personnel in understanding the role
of ES in a sustainable future. This book has been written by an international team
of researchers. We acknowledge the effort, expert knowledge and care of team
members that brought this project to completion and sincerely thank all of the
authors for their contributions. The editors thank their family and friends for
their continued support.
21. xviii Introduction
We end this Introduction with one of our favourite quotations about ES and
‘future farming’: ‘I am a photosynthesis manager and an ecosystem-service
provider’, Peter Edlin, farmer, Sweden, 2003.
Steve Wratten (Lincoln), Harpinder Sandhu (Adelaide),
Ross Cullen (Lincoln), Robert Costanza (Canberra)
May 2012
24. 4 Scene Setting
Introduction
Natural and modified ecosystems support human life through functions and pro-
cesses known as ecosystem services (ES; Daily, 1997). These are the life-support
systems of the planet (Myers, 1996; Daily, 1997; Daily et al., 1997) and it is evident
that human life cannot exist without them.
The importance of ecosystem goods and services in supporting human life and as
a life-support system of the planet (Myers, 1996; Daily, 1997; Costanza et al., 1997;
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005) is now very well established and ES were
demonstrated to be of very high economic value 15 years ago (US $33 trillion year−1
;
Costanza et al., 1997). Although that value-transfer approach has been heavily
criticized (Toman, 1998), no subsequent attempt to quantify ES globally has been
made. However, for particular biological groups, such as insects, value transfer has
again been used (Losey and Vaughan, 2006) or for one taxon for one region, experi-
mental techniques to evaluate animals’ populations have been combined with the
economic value of the support they provide (e.g. earthworms and soil formation;
Sandhu et al., 2008). Also, a whole-of-farm approach has been again based on in situ
measurements followed by spatial scaling (Porter et al., 2009), in that case for the
whole of the European Union in relation to current agricultural subsidies. Yet because
most ES are not traded in economic markets, they carry no ‘price tags’ (no exchange
value in spite of their high use value) that could alert society to changes in their sup-
ply or deterioration of underlying ecological systems that generate them. Despite
this, there has been a recent trend of decline in ES globally, with 60% of the ES
examined having been degraded in the last 50 years (Millennium Ecosystem
Assessment, 2005). Global efforts to halt this decline in ES have increased consider-
ably since the completion of the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MEA) in 2005.
The United Nations has established the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform
on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services (IPBES) to translate science into action
world-wide in consultation with governments and research partners (IPBES, 2010).
Because the threats to ES are increasing, there is a critical need for identifica-
tion, monitoring and enhancement of ES both locally and globally, and for the
incorporation of their value into decision-making processes (Daily et al., 1997;
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005; IPBES, 2010; UN, 2012). It is well
known that agroecosystems and urban areas contribute substantially to the
welfare of human societies by providing highly demanded and valuable ES. Many
of these, however, remain outside conventional markets. This is especially the
case for public goods (climate regulation, soil erosion control, etc.) and external
costs related to the active protection and management of these ecosystems. The
capacity of ecosystems to deliver ES is already under stress (Millennium Ecosystem
Assessment, 2005) and additional challenges imposed by climate change in the
coming years will require better adaptation (Mooney et al., 2009).
What are ecosystem services?
The Millennium Ecosystem Assessment sponsored by the United Nations
(Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005) defines ecosystem services (ES) as
25. Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 5
the benefits people obtain from ecosystems. There is a general lack of
understanding of what an ecosystem actually is, however; for example, among
university undergraduates and even researchers it is probably worth remember-
ing that single species can provide ES, albeit as part of their place in a trophic
web. The facts that honey bees pollinate crops and ladybugs (ladybirds) eat
insect pests are often a simple way of illustrating the power of ES to land
owners, among others. In these circumstances, ‘nature’s services’ can be a more
useful phrase. These benefits sustain human existence through four types of
service that include supporting (e.g. water and nutrient cycling), provisioning
(e.g. food production, fuel wood), regulating (e.g. water purification, erosion
control), and cultural (e.g. aesthetic and spiritual values) services. Benefits arise
from managed as well as natural ecosystems. Recent studies have contributed to
further understanding of ES for natural resource management (Wallace, 2007),
for accounting purposes (Boyd and Banzhaf, 2007), for valuation (Fisher and
Turner, 2008), and for policy-relevant research (Fisher et al., 2008; Balmford
et al., 2011). Sagoff (2011) points out the differences in ecological and economic
criteria in assessing and valuing ES and advocates for a conceptual framework
to integrate market-based and science-based methods to manage ecosystems for
human well-being.
Ecosystem functions, goods and services
Ecosystem functions can be defined as ‘the capacity of natural processes and
components to provide goods and services that satisfy human needs, directly or
indirectly’ (de Groot, 1992). Using this definition, ecosystem functions are best
conceived as a subset of ecological processes and ecosystem structures. Each
function is the result of the natural processes of the total ecological subsystem
of which it is a part. Natural processes, in turn, are the result of complex
interactions between biotic (living) and abiotic (chemical and physical) compo-
nents of ecosystems through the universal driving forces of matter and energy
(de Groot et al., 2002).
One of the key insights provided by the MEA (2005) is that not all ES are
equal – there is no one single category that captures the diversity of what fully
functioning ecological systems provide humans. Rather, researchers must
recognize that ES occur at multiple scales, from climate regulation and carbon
sequestration at the global scale, to soil formation and nutrient cycling more
locally. To capture the diversity of ES, the MEA (2005) grouped them into four
basic services based on their functional characteristics.
1 Regulating services: ecosystems regulate essential ecological processes and
life support systems through biogeochemical cycles and other biospheric
processes. These include climate regulation, disturbance moderation and
waste treatment.
2 Provisioning services: the provisioning function of ecosystems supplies
a large variety of ecosystem goods and other services for human consumption,
26. 6 Scene Setting
ranging from food in agricultural systems, raw materials and energy
resources.
3 Cultural services: ecosystems provide an essential ‘reference function’ and
contribute to the maintenance of human health and well-being by providing
spiritual fulfilment, historical integrity, recreation sites and aesthetics.
4 Supporting services: ecosystems also provide a range of services that are nec-
essary for the production of the other three service categories. These include
nutrient cycling, soil formation and soil retention.
The ES framework
The ES framework has been increasingly used to explain the interactions between
ecosystems and human well-being. Several studies classified ES into different
categories based on their functions (Costanza et al., 1997; Daily, 1997; de Groot
et al., 2002). The MEA assessed the consequences of ecosystem change for human
well-being and provided a framework to identify and classify ES (Millennium
Ecosystem Assessment, 2005). It established the scientific basis for actions needed
to balance nature and human well-being by sustainable use of ecosystems. In the
following section, we follow MEA typology and discuss the ES approach and
ecosystem-based adaptation.
The ecosystem services approach
An ES approach is one that integrates the ecological, social and economic dimen-
sions of natural resource management (Cork et al., 2007). Cork and colleagues
(2007) have described an ES approach as the following.
t An ES approach helps to identify and classify the benefits that people derive
from ecosystems. It also includes market and non-market, use and non-use,
tangible and non-tangible benefits.
t It also explains consumers and producers of ES for maintenance and improve-
ment of ecosystems for human well-being.
t This approach helps to describe and communicate benefits derived from
natural and modified ecosystems to a wide range of stakeholders.
Ecosystem-based adaptation (EbA)
This approach integrates biodiversity and ES into an overall adaptation strategy
to help people to adapt to the adverse effects of, for example, climate change
(Colls et al., 2009). EbA can be applied at different geographical scales (local,
regional, national) and over various periods (short to long term). It can be
implemented as projects and as part of overall adaptation programmes. It is most
effective when implemented as part of a broad portfolio of adaptation and devel-
opment interventions (Colls et al., 2009). It is cost-effective and more accessible
to rural or poor communities than measures based on hard infrastructure and
engineering. It can integrate and maintain traditional and local knowledge and
cultural values, such as in the New Zealand Maori concept of Kaitiakitanga.
27. Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 7
This embraces the philosophy and practice of valuing inherited places and
practices and aims to pass them on undamaged or improved. Some examples of
EbA activities (CBD, 2009; Colls et al., 2009) are:
t coastal defence through the maintenance and/or restoration of mangroves
and other coastal wetlands to reduce coastal flooding and coastal erosion;
t sustainable management of upland wetlands and floodplains for maintenance
of water flow and quality;
t conservation and restoration of forests to stabilize land slopes and regulate
water flows;
t establishment of diverse agroforestry systems to cope with increased risk
from changed climatic conditions;
t conservation of agrobiodiversity to provide specific gene pools for crop and
livestock adaptation to climate change.
Engineered systems
Engineered systems are landscapes such as farmland and cities that are actively
modified to supply a particular set of ES. Farmland has been modified or ‘engi-
neered’ to provide food and fibre, whereas cities have been actively managed to
accommodate a human population. ‘Engineered’ or modified ecosystems are
providers and consumers of different types of ES. Optimally managed ‘engineered’
or ‘designed’ ecosystems can provide a range of important ES; for instance, more
fresh water, cleaner air and greater food production, as well as fewer floods and
pollutants (Palmer et al., 2004). However, pursuit of commercial gains often
reduces the ability to supply other vital ES. In this section and indeed in the
following chapters, we discuss two modified or designed systems – agricultural
and urban.
Agricultural systems
‘Engineered’ or modified ecosystems such as farmland are providers and con-
sumers of different types of ES. Farmland comprises highly modified landscapes
designed to generate revenue for farmers. Farmers use many inputs as well as
natural inputs to produce food and fibre. The production of these is an ES.
Intensive agriculture replaces many other ES with chemical inputs, resulting in a
decrease in these services and their importance on farmland (Sandhu et al., 2008,
2010a, 2010b, 2012). This ‘substitution agriculture’ has to a large extent replaced
these ES world-wide in the twentieth century. Severe environmental destruction,
increasing fuel prices and the external costs of modern agriculture have resulted
in increased interest among researchers and farmers in using ES for the more
sustainable production of food and fibre (Daily, 1997; Costanza et al., 1997;
Tilman, 1999; Cullen et al., 2004; Gurr et al., 2004, 2012; Robertson and
Swinton, 2005). The above global trends have led to world-wide concerns about
the environmental consequences of modern agriculture (Millennium Ecosystem
28. 8 Scene Setting
Assessment, 2005; De Schutter, 2010). There is also an additional concern that
as the world approaches ‘peak oil’ and is already experiencing high oil prices,
agriculture may no longer be able to depend so heavily on oil-derived ‘substitu-
tion’ inputs (Pimentel and Giampietro, 1994). Such a grave situation does not
detract from the responsibility of agriculture to meet the food demands of a
growing population but it does question its ability to increase yields without fur-
ther ecosystem damage (Escudero, 1998; Tilman, 1999; Pimentel and Wilson,
2004; Schröter et al., 2005; UN, 2012). Therefore, the current challenge is to
meet the food demands of a growing population and yet maintain and enhance
the productivity of agricultural systems (UN, 1992). There is, therefore, cur-
rently an increasing interest in the services provided by nature.
It is now urgent that ES on farmland be enhanced as part of global food
policy because increasingly dysfunctional biomes and ecosystems are appearing
and agriculture, which largely created the problem, has become more intensive
in its use of non-renewable resources, driven by a world population which is
likely to reach nine billion people by 2050 (Foley et al., 2005). This intensifica-
tion is compounded by a grain demand which is rising super-proportionally to
human population increase and which is largely caused by biofuels develop-
ment and a rapid rise in per capita meat consumption in parts of Asia (Rosegrant
et al., 2001). Continuing with the current energy-intense (Pimentel et al.,
2005), wasteful (Vitousek et al., 2009), polluting and unsustainable ‘substitution
agriculture’, with its associated problems, which are likely to be exacerbated by
climate change, is not an option for future world food security and productiv-
ity. There is, therefore, an urgent need for enhanced biodiversity-driven ES in
world farming. Different types of agricultural systems and ES interactions are
discussed in following chapters. More information is provided by Orre-Gordon
et al., Sandhu et al. and Jordan and Warner in Chapters 4, 8 and 9, respectively.
The relationship between aquaculture and ES is discussed in detail by Baulcomb
in Chapter 5.
ES associated with agriculture
Costanza et al. (1997) estimated, with limited available data, the ES of world
croplands to be only US$92 ha−1
year−1
. This was in marked contrast with other
world biomes, for which ES were estimated to be worth US$23000 ha−1
year−1
for estuaries, US$20000 ha−1
year−1
for swamps and US$2000 ha−1
year−1
for
tropical forests (Costanza et al., 1997). There are, however, two recent experi-
mental agroecological approaches that can be used to demonstrate how this
croplands figure can be much higher. The first involves agroecological experi-
ments to measure ecosystem functions combined with value-transfer techniques
to calculate their economic value. These studies demonstrate that some current
farming practices have much higher ES values than in the Costanza et al. (1997)
work. For example, recent data show that the combined value of only two ES
(nitrogen mineralization and biological control of a single pest by one guild of
invertebrate predators) can have values of US$197, $271 and $301 ha−1
year−1
in terms of avoided costs for conventional (Sandhu et al., 2008), organic
(Lampkin, 1991) and integrated (Porter et al., 2009) arable farming systems,
respectively. The above values comprise reduced variable costs (labour, fuel and
29. Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 9
pesticides) and lower external costs to human health and the environment. Paying
for these variable costs is a charge to society, not to the individual farmer and
although they contribute to GDP
, that is a poor indicator of sustainability and of
human well-being (Costanza, 2008).
The second recent realization that can transform ES on farmland is that a
better understanding of ecological processes in agroecosystems can generate
protocols which do not require a major farming system change but which enhance
ES by returning selective functional agricultural biodiversity (FAB) to agriculture
(Landis et al., 2000). For example, the role of leguminous crops in nitrogen
fixation is a well-known enhancement of farmland ES and can have a value of
US$40 ha−1
year−1
in terms of reduced oil-based fertilizer inputs (Vitousek
et al., 2009), without including the value of reduced ES damage. More recent
farmland ES improvements are illustrated by agroecological research on biological
control of insect pests. In New Zealand and Australia, strips of flowering
buckwheat Fagopyrum esculentum (Moench.) between vine rows provide nectar
in an otherwise virtual monoculture and thereby improve the ecological fitness
of parasitoid wasps that attack grape-feeding caterpillars. This in turn leads to
the pest population being brought below the economic threshold. An investment
of US$3 ha−1
year−1
in buckwheat seed and minimal sowing costs can lead to
savings in variable costs of US$200 ha−1
year−1
as well as fewer pesticide residues
in the wine, higher well-being for vineyard workers and enhanced ecotourism
(Fountain and Tomkins, 2011).
Although the ecotechnologies now exist to improve farming sustainability
when the negative consequences of oil-based inputs are well recognized, farmers
world-wide are still largely risk averse (Anderson, 2003). They have traditionally
rejected the idea that non-crop biodiversity on their land can improve production
and/or minimize costs. The challenge now for agroecologists and policymakers is
to use a range of market-based instruments or incentives, government interven-
tions and enhanced social learning among growers to accelerate the deployment
of sound, biodiversity-based ES-enhancement protocols for farmers. These pro-
tocols need to be framed in the form of service-providing units (Luck et al.,
2003), which precisely explain the necessary ES-enhancement procedures and
which should ideally include cost–benefit analyses. Such a requirement invites
the design of new systems of primary production that ensure positive net carbon
sequestration, are species diverse, have low inputs and provide a diverse suite of
ES. An experimental example of such a system is a combined food, energy and
ecosystem services (CFEES) agroecosystem in Denmark that uses non-food
hedgerows as sources of biodiversity and biofuel. This novel production system
is a net energy producer, providing more energy in the form of renewable bio-
mass than is consumed in the planting, growing and harvesting of the food and
fodder (Porter et al., 2009).
An approach to encouraging the uptake of ES-enhancing farming systems such
as CFEES is through ‘payment for ecosystem services’ (PES) to private landown-
ers (Food and Agriculture Organization, 2007). In this approach, those that
benefit from the provision of ES make payments to those that supply them,
thereby maintaining ES. Examples of working PES schemes currently in practice
are found in different areas of the world. The current focus of these schemes is
30. 10 Scene Setting
on water, carbon and biodiversity in addressing environmental problems through
positive incentives to land managers (Food and Agriculture Organization, 2007).
Such schemes would not only help to improve the environment and human well-
being but also ensure food security and long-term farm sustainability (Rosegrant
and Cline, 2003).
Although agricultural ecosystems may have low ES values per unit area when
compared with others such as estuaries and wetlands, they offer the best chance
of increasing global ES by developing appropriate goals for agriculture and the
use of land management regimes that favour ES provision. This is because agri-
culture occupies 40% of the earth’s land area and is readily amenable to changing
practices, if the sociopolitical impediments are met. Agriculture can be consid-
ered to be the largest ecological experiment on Earth, with a high potential to
damage global ES but also to promote them via ecologically informed approaches
to the design of agroecosystems that value both marketed and non-marketed ES.
The extensive Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (Millennium Ecosystem
Assessment, 2005) of global ecosystems completed by science and policy com-
munities provided a new framework for analysing socioecological processes and
suggested that agriculture may be the ‘largest threat to biodiversity and ecosys-
tem function of any single human activity’. As 45% of the global population is
engaged in farming activities, and such a large proportion of the global land area
is in agriculture, achievement of human well-being as agreed by the UN-led
Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) (UN, 2000) is not possible without
clear pathways for the design of future agroecosystems. There are major global
advantages of enhancing ES on farmland through adoption of ES-enhancement
protocols. Therefore, global agricultural systems that utilize and maintain high
levels of ES are required so that they can provide sustainable economic well-being
and food security within ecological constraints (Royal Society, 2009). To con-
dense this discussion into a simple goal, the farmer of the future needs to be
encouraged to re-define his/her role to ‘I am a photosynthesis manager and an
ecosystem-service provider’.
Urban systems
Urbanization and urban growth are major drivers of ecosystem change globally.
Urban areas are providing habitats for more than half the human population. In
spite of these trends, the ecosystem idea has generally been applied to locations
distant from the places where people live. However, knowledge about ecosys-
tems is important for maintaining the quality of life in cities, suburbs and the
fringes of metropolitan areas. Urban ecosystem concepts remind citizens and
decision makers that we all ultimately depend on our ecosystems and their ser-
vices (Daily, 1997). As the ‘ecological footprint’ of cities will increase in the com-
ing decades, because they ‘sequester’ the products of ES from elsewhere, there is
need to incorporate ES into decision making during planning and management
of urban areas.
Urban ecosystems have been neglected due to the lack of understanding of the
complex processes involved, the lack of mechanisms to govern them, and the
failure to incorporate ES into day-to-day decision making. Urban development
31. Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 11
trends pose serious problems with respect to ES and human well-being. The
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005) treated urban systems as ecosystems
necessary for human welfare. As they are dominated by humans, these systems
can be classified on the basis of population size, economic condition and loca-
tion. Nearly half the world’s population lives in cities of less than half a million
people and about 10% lives in those with more than 10 million (Millennium
Ecosystem Assessment, 2005). The ES challenges within cities are enormous and
are discussed in this chapter below and later in this book.
ES in urban systems
Urban systems are not functional or self-contained ecosystems. They depend
largely on surrounding ecosystems in rural areas or more distant ecosystems to
fulfil their daily needs including food, water and material for housing and other
needs. In cities, urban parks, forests and green belts have their strategic impor-
tance for the quality of life. They provide essential ES such as gas regulation, air
and water purification, wind and noise reduction, etc. They also enhance social
and cultural services such as feelings of well-being, and provide recreational
opportunities for urban dwellers (Miller, 1997; Smardon, 1988; Botkin and
Beveridge, 1997; Bolund and Hunhammar, 1999; Lorenzo et al., 2000; Tyrväinen
and Miettinen, 2000).
Towns and cities are also both consumers and producers of ES. However, the
net flow of ES is invariably into rather than out of urban systems. Even if they are
not major producers of ES, urban activities can alter the supply and flow of ES at
every scale, from local to global level. Urban development threatens the quality
of the air, the quality and availability of water, the waste processing and recycling
systems, and many other qualities of the ambient environment that contribute to
human well-being.
ES and their interactions in engineered systems
Both agricultural and urban systems are dependent and impact on the provision
of ES. These designed systems are affected by direct and indirect drivers that in
turn impact ES (Fig. 1.1). It is very important to understand these interactions
between ES and ‘engineered systems’ for the achievement of equitable and sus-
tainable human welfare (Swaminathan, 2012).
Human society, as part of the planetary system of interacting biomes depends
on these ES as life support functions. Yet simultaneously we are impacting nega-
tively on ecosystem goods and services. This is the dilemma facing society as our
ecological footprint on planet earth increases. Projected economic expansion to
meet the demands of a growing population (projected to be 9 billion by 2050)
along with global climate change will jeopardize future human well-being by
further degrading ecosystems. There is a great need to incorporate the value of
ES into day-to-day decision making, into government policies and in business
practices so that sustainable and desirable futures can be achieved. Waste of
energy, food and other resources in the ‘developed’ world points to areas where
our current practices can be readly modified.
32. 12 Scene Setting
In this context, global studies have largely focused on natural ecosystems and
biomes, such as the boreal forests and the sea and have put little emphasis on
managed ecosystems such as farmland and cities. However, the continued supply
of ecosystem goods and services is of vital significance for the survival and
productivity of our farmland and our cities. Agricultural systems comprise the
largest managed ecosystems on Earth, and are often confronted by ecosystem
degradation. Much of the success of modern agriculture has been from provision-
ing services such as food and fibre. However, the expansion in the demand and
supply of these marketable ecosystem goods has resulted in the suppression of
other valuable and essential ES such as pollination, climate and water regulation,
biodiversity and soil conservation. Similarly, demands from urban areas to support
and enhance human lifestyles have resulted in the degradation of other valuable
ES in other parts of the world. As economic wealth is underpinned by ecological
wealth, we need to recognize and understand the role of ES in sustaining societies,
nations and individuals. This can help to achieve food security and environmental
sustainability at scales from local to global. It can help ensure a sustainable
development and an equitable future. Without the evaluation, protection and
enhancement of ES in agriculture and cities, the world’s future is bleak indeed.
References
Anderson, J.R. (2003). Risk in rural development: challenges for managers and policy
makers. Agricultural Systems, 75, 161–197.
Ecosystem Services
s 0ROVISIONING SERVICES
s 2EGULATING SERVICES
s #ULTURAL SERVICES
s 3UPPORTING SERVICES
Urban systems
s (ABITAT
s 0ERSONAL SAFETY
s 3OCIAL COHESION
s &REEDOM OF CHOICE
s #LEAN AIR AND WATER
Agricultural systems
s !DEQUATE LIVELIHOODS
s 3UFFICIENT NUTRITIOUS
FOOD FIBRE
s 3ECURE RESOURCE ACCESS
s #ULTURAL ASPECTS
Indirect drivers of
ecosystem change
s %CONOMIC
s 3OCIAL
s #ULTURAL
Direct drivers of
ecosystem change
s .ATURAL
s "IOLOGICAL
s ,AND USE CHANGE
Impacts Dependence
Human well-being
Fig. 1.1 Framework of drivers of ecosystem change and the interaction between ES
and two ‘engineered systems’ – urban and agricultural systems.
33. Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 13
Balmford, A., Fisher, B., Green, R.E., et al. (2011). Bringing ecosystem services into the
real world: an operational framework for assessing the economic consequences of los-
ing wild nature. Environmental and Resource Economics, 48, 161–175.
Bolund, P
. and Hunhammar, S. (1999). Ecosystem services in urban areas. Ecological
Economics, 29, 293–301.
Botkin, D.B. and Beveridge, C.E. (1997). Cities as environments. Urban Ecosystems,
1, 3–19.
Boyd, J. and Banzhaf, S. (2007). What are ecosystem services? Ecological Economics, 63,
616–626.
CBD (2009). Connecting Biodiversity and Climate Change Mitigation and Adaptation.
Report of the Second Ad Hoc Technical Expert Group on Biodiversity and Climate
Change. Montreal, Technical Series No. 41.
Colls, A., Ash, N. and Ikkalal, N. (2009). Ecosystem Based Adaptation: a Natural Response
to Climate Change. IUCN Report, p. 16.
Cork, S., Stoneham, G. and Lowe, K. (2007). Ecosystem Services and Australian Natural
Resource Management (NRM) Futures. Paper to the Natural Resource Policies and
Programs Committee (NRPPC) and the Natural Resource Management Standing
Committee (NRMSC). Australian Government Department of the Environment, Water,
Heritage and the Arts, Canberra, Australia.
Costanza, R. (2008). Stewardship for a ‘full’ world. Current History, 107, 30–35.
Costanza, R., d’Arge, R., De Groot, R., et al. (1997). The value of the world’s ecosystem
services and natural capital. Nature, 387, 253–260.
Cullen, R., Takatsuka, Y., Wilson, M. and Wratten, S. (2004). Ecosystem Services on New
Zealand Arable Farms. Agribusiness and Economics Research Unit, Lincoln University,
Discussion Paper 151, pp. 84–91.
Daily, G.C. (1997). Nature’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems. Island
Press, Washington, DC.
Daily, G.C., Alexander, S., Ehrlich, P
.R., et al. (1997). Ecosystem services: benefits sup-
plied to human societies by natural ecosystems. Issues in Ecology, 2, 18.
de Groot, R.S. (1992). Functions of Nature: Evaluation of Nature in Environment
Planning, Management and Decision Making. Wolters-Noordhoff, Gröningen.
de Groot, R.S., Wilson, M. and Boumans, R.M.J. (2002). A typology for the classifica-
tion, description and valuation of ecosystem functions, goods and services. Ecological
Economics, 41, 393–408.
De Schutter, O. (2010). Agroecology and the Right to Food, Report submitted by the
Special Rapporteur on the Right to Food, p.21. United Nations General Assembly.
Escudero, G. (1998). The vision and mission of agriculture in the year 2020: towards a
focus that values agriculture and the rural environment. Agricultura, Medioambiente y
Pobreza Rural en America Latina (eds L.G. Reca and R.G., Echeverria), pp. 21–54.
CAB Direct, Washington, DC.
Fisher, B. and Turner, K. (2008). Ecosystem services: classification for valuation. Biological
Conservation, 141, 1167–1169.
Fisher, B., Turner, K., Zylstra, M., et al. (2008). Ecosystem services and economic theory:
integration for policy-relevant research. Ecological Applications, 18, 2050–2067.
Foley, J.A., deFries, R., Asner, G.P
., et al. (2005). Global consequences of land use. Science,
309, 570–573.
Food and Agriculture Organization (2007). The State of Food and Agriculture: Paying
Farmers for Environmental Services, p. 222.
Fountain, J. and Tompkins, J. (2011).The potential of wine tourism experiences to impart
knowledge of sustainable practices: the case of the Greening Waipara biodiversity trails.
Proceedings of the 6th AWBR International Conference, 9–10 June, Bordeaux
Management School, France.
Gurr, G.M., Wratten, S.D. and Altieri, M.A. (eds) (2004). Ecological Engineering for Pest
Management: Advances in Habitat Manipulation for Arthropods. CSIRO, Victoria.
Gurr, G.M., Wratten, S.D., Snyder, W
.E. and Read, D.M. (2012). Biodiversity and Insect
Pests – Key Issues for Sustainable Management. Wiley-Blackwell, UK.
34. 14 Scene Setting
IPBES (2010). Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem
Services. UNEP
. Available at http://ipbes.net/ (accessed August 2012).
Lampkin, N. (1991). Organic Farming. Farming Press, Ipswich, UK.
Landis, D.A., Wratten, S.D. and Gurr, G.M. (2000). Habitat management to conserve natural
enemies of arthropod pests in Agriculture. Annual Review of Entomology, 45, 175–201.
Lorenzo, A.B., Blanche, C.A., Qi, Y. and Guidry, M.M. (2000). Assessing residents’ will-
ingness to pay to preserve the community urban forest: a small-city case study. Journal
of Arboriculture, 26, 319–325.
Losey, J.E. and Vaughan, M. (2006).The economic value of ecological services provided
by insects. BioScience, 56, 311–323.
Luck, G.W
., Daily, G.C. and Ehrlich, P
.R. (2003). Population diversity and ecosystem
services. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 18, 331–336.
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005). Synthesis Report. Island Press, Washington, DC.
Miller, R. W
. (1997). Urban Forestry – Planning and Managing Urban Greenspaces, 2nd
edn. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Mooney, H., Larigauderie, A., Cesario, M., et al. (2009). Biodiversity, climate change and
ecosystem services. Current Opinion in Environment Sustainability, 1, 46–54.
Myers, N. (1996). Environmental services of biodiversity. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences USA, 93, 2764–2769.
Palmer, M., Bernhardt, E., Chornesky, E., et al. (2004). Ecology for a crowded planet.
Science, 304, 1251–1252.
Pimentel, D., Hepperly P
., Hanson, J., Douds, D. and Seidel, R. (2005). Environmental,
energetic, and economic comparisons of organic and conventional farming systems.
Bioscience, 55, 573–582.
Pimentel, D. and Giampietro, M. (1994). Food, Land, Population and the U.S. Economy.
Carrying Capacity Network, Washington, DC.
Pimentel, D. and Wilson, A. (2004). World population, agriculture and malnutrition.
World Watch, 17, 22–25.
Porter, J.R.P
., Costanza, R., Sandhu, H., Sigsgaard, L. and Wratten, S. (2009). The value
of producing food, energy, and ecosystem services within and agro-ecosystem. Ambio,
38, 186–193.
Robertson, G.P
. and Swinton, S.M. (2005). Reconciling agricultural productivity and
environmental integrity: a grand challenge for agriculture. Frontiers in Ecology and
Environment, 3, 38–46.
Rosegrant, M.W
. and Cline, S.A. (2003). Global food security: challenges and policies.
Science, 302, 1917–1919.
Rosegrant, M.W
., Paisner, M., Meijer, S. and Whitcover, J. (2001). Global Food Projections
to 2020: Emerging Trends and Alternative Futures. IFPRI, Washington, DC.
Royal Society (2009). Reaping the Benefits: Science and the Sustainable Intensification of
Global Agriculture. Available at http://royalsociety.org/Reapingthebenefits/ (2009),
p. 86 (accessed August 2012).
Sagoff, M. (2011). The quantification and valuation of ecosystem services. Ecological
Economics, 70, 497–502.
Sandhu, H., Crossman, N. and Smith, F. (2012). Ecosystem services in Australian agricul-
tural enterprises. Ecological Economics, 74, 19–26.
Sandhu, H.S., Wratten, S.D. and Cullen, R. ( 2010a). Organic agriculture and ecosystem
services. Environmental Science and Policy, 13, 1–7.
Sandhu, H.S., Wratten, S.D. and Cullen, R. (2010b). The role of supporting ecosys-
tem services in conventional and organic arable farmland. Ecological Complexity,
7, 302–310.
Sandhu, H.S., Wratten, S.D., Cullen, R. and Case, B. (2008).The future of farming: the
value of ecosystem services in conventional and organic arable land. An experimental
approach. Ecological Economics, 64, 835–848.
Schröter, D., Cramer, W
., Leemans, R., et al. (2005). Ecosystem service supply and
vulnerability to global change in Europe. Science, 310, 1333–1337.
35. Ecosystem Services in Farmland and Cities 15
Smardon, R.C. (1988). Perception and aesthetics of the urban environment: review of the
role of vegetation. Landscape and Urban Planning, 15, 85–106.
Swaminathan,M.S.(2012).SustainableDevelopment:TwentyYearsafterRio.International
Consultation on Twenty years of Rio: Biodiversity-Development-Livelihoods, Chennai,
India.
Tilman, D. (1999). Global environmental impacts of agricultural expansion: The need for
sustainable and efficient practices. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
USA, 96, 5995–6000.
Toman, M. (1998). Why not to calculate the value of the world’s ecosystem services and
natural capital. Ecological Economics, 25, 1, 57–60.
Tyrväinen, L. and Miettinen, A. (2000). Property prices and urban forest amenities.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 39, 205–223.
UN (1992). Promoting Sustainable Agriculture and Rural Development. United Nations
Conference on Environment and Development. Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 3 to 14 June.
Agenda 21, 14.1-14.104. Available at http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/agenda21.htm
(accessed August 2012).
UN (2000). United Nations Millennium Declaration. Available at: http://www.un.org/
millennium/declaration/ares552e.pdf (accessed August 2012).
UN (2012). The Future We Want. United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development.
United Nations, Rio de Janeiro.
Vitousek, P
.M., Naylor, R., Crews, T., et al. (2009). Nutrient imbalances in agricultural
development. Science, 324,1519–1520.
Wallace, K.J. (2007). Classification of ecosystem services: problems and solutions.
Biological Conservation, 139, 235–246.
37. Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem Services 17
Introduction
A critical challenge in the integration of ecosystem and economic science is the
development of an operational classification of ecosystems and their functions
which lends itself to the valuation of ecosystem services (de Groot et al., 2002;
National Research Council, 2005). In the absence of either a political mandate to
protect ecosystem integrity or a method of assigning value to ecosystem services
for use in decision making, land use and development decisions will continue to
be made without sufficient consideration for the important role ecosystems play
in sustaining life (National Research Council, 2005; Daily et al., 2009).
Furthermore, assigning monetary value to ecosystem services can aid in making
environmental problems visible and thus inform decision processes (Wilson and
Howarth, 2002; Spangenberg and Settele, 2010).
The provision of ecosystem services and subsequent benefit to humans is
underpinned by a series of biophysical processes and ecological functions which
themselves are driven by biological diversity (Balvanera et al., 2006). These
linkages are highlighted in Fig. 2.1. Experiments have shown that increasing the
amount of biological diversity has in most cases an increasingly positive effect
on ecosystem function and service. For example, greater abundance of soil myc-
orrhiza and a higher rate of soil decomposer activity increases the rate of nutri-
ent cycling, which is a regulating ecosystem service. A faster rate of nutrient
cycling can be of direct benefit to humans if harnessed to increase agricultural
productivity.
Service
Biophysical
structure
or process
Function*
(e.g. flood-
protection,
products)
Ecosystems and Biodiversity
(econ) Value
Benefit(s)
Human well-being
(sociocultural context)
(e.g. WTP for
protection
or products)
(contribution
to health,
safety, etc)
(e.g. slow
water
passage
biomass)
(e.g. vegetation
cover or net
primary
productivity)
* Subset of biophysical structure or
process providing the service
Fig. 2.1 The interdependencies of biological diversity, biophysical process, ecosystem
function and service, human well-being, and willingness to pay (WTP). From de Groot,
R.S., Alkemade, R., Braat, L., Hein, L. and Willemen, L. (2010). Challenges in integrating
the concept of ecosystem services and values in landscape planning, management and
decision making. Ecological Complexity, 7, 260–272.
38. 18 Scene Setting
Agricultural commodities, valued in the market place, are just one of the
ecosystem services agricultural systems produce. Ecosystem services have use and
non-use values, and are valued using various methods. Non-use values include
existence, bequest and altruistic values, or simply put – the knowledge that an
ecosystem exists for us and for others now and in the future is valuable (National
Research Council, 2005; Turner et al., 2008). Use values are categorized as direct
and indirect. Direct-use values include timber production; a scenic lake may have
recreational value which is captured by a management authority, or a home with a
view of a natural and structurally diverse forest may fetch a better market price
than a similar house without a scenic view. Ecosystems generate a multitude of
indirect use values such as water filtration, nutrient retention and erosion mitiga-
tion. These values are less tangible than direct-use values and do not directly
involve interaction between a beneficiary and the ecosystem (TEEB, 2010).
In this chapter we document the relationship between biological diversity,
ecosystem function and service within agricultural systems. To guide the discus-
sion, we focus on the interdependencies between agricultural production and the
ecosystem services provided by freshwater wetlands (hereafter wetlands) and the
impacts agricultural systems can have on the health and functioning of wetlands.
We focus on wetlands because they are biologically complex yet relatively well
understood, and critical to the provision of freshwater for agricultural use and
human benefit. In the section that follows, ecosystem function and its linkages
with ecosystem services are established. The ecological functions and subsequent
ecosystem services generated by wetlands are defined and their interactions with
agricultural systems are discussed in detail. We conclude the chapter with a dis-
cussion of the research challenges involved in managing complexity, resilience
and trade-offs between ecosystem services and agriculture.
Linking ecosystem function with ecosystem service
Ecosystems directly contribute to human well-being via the provision of ecosys-
tem services (Costanza et al., 1997; Daily, 1997; Millennium Ecosystem
Assessment, 2003; Perrings, 2006; TEEB, 2010). The benefits provided by ecosys-
tem services within agricultural systems are direct, such as food and raw materials,
and indirect and include the regulation of water supply and quality and nutrient
cycling example. Underpinning these services is a suite of ecological functions that
must be understood in a first step to valuing, managing and enhancing ecosystem
service provision. Importantly, a healthy and functioning wetland purifies water
via biogeochemical and nutrient-retention processes, making freshwater available
for irrigated agricultural production, which in turn provides food for human con-
sumption. Making the link between function and service also enables us to iden-
tify threats to ecosystem services from unsustainable management practices. For
example, agricultural run-off that follows from excessive pesticide or fertilizer use
impedes biogeochemical and nutrient retention processes, threatening the ability
of wetlands to purify water, which in turn threatens food production.
Ecosystem functions result from the interactions between characteristics,
structures and processes (Turner et al., 2000) constituting the physical, chemical
39. Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem Services 19
and biological exchanges and processes that contribute to the self-maintenance
and self-renewal of an ecosystem (e.g. nutrient cycling and food-web interactions).
Ecosystem functions involve interactions between biotic and abiotic system com-
ponents in achieving any and all ecosystem outcomes (National Research Council,
2005). de Groot (1992) illustrates the link between ecosystem function and
human benefit by defining function as the capacity of natural processes and com-
ponents to provide goods and services that generate human utility. Linking eco-
system function to human benefit should encourage ecosystem-based management
because of the monetary or non-monetary benefits provided by functionally
diverse systems (Turner et al., 2008; Willemen et al., 2010).
Following the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (Millennium Ecosystems
Assessment, 2005), ecosystem functions may be conveniently grouped into four
categories, namely: production, regulation, habitat and informational functions.
Regulatory functions include gas and nutrient exchange, disturbance prevention,
water regulation, soil retention and formation, waste treatment, pollination and
biological control. Critical habitat functions are the provision of habitat and
maintenance of biological diversity, while the production function includes the
production of food and other raw materials such as medicinal, genetic and
ornamental resources. Informational functions include aesthetic, recreational,
cultural and spiritual functions.
Ecosystem function and their resulting services have an inherently spatial
nature. Services may be created and the benefits enjoyed in situ. An example of
this is the provision of habitat which may be used by animals that are subse-
quently hunted for recreation. Benefits may be omnidirectional where services
are created in one location, though the benefits are spatially extensive, which is
the case of the role of wetlands in sequestering carbon (Zedler and Kercher,
2005) and thus mitigating climate change – a benefit enjoyed globally. Finally,
services may be directional, where a function occurs in one location, while the
benefits are perceived directionally from that location due to the direction of
flow. An example of this is the function riparian ecosystems serve in downstream
flood control (Zedler and Kercher, 2005; Turner et al., 2008).
Wetlands
Wetlands are particularly diverse and productive ecosystems (Woodward and
Wui, 2001; Zedler and Kercher, 2005) providing direct and indirect benefits at
local, landscape and global scales (Acharya, 2000). Wetlands may be defined as
areas exhibiting a temporary or permanent presence of water above or close to
the soil surface and are maintained by waterlogging. Water is the primary factor
affecting plant and animal life in these systems. Wetlands, although occupying
less than 9% of the earth’s terrestrial surface, contribute significantly in the
provision of ecosystem services (Zedler and Kercher, 2005).
There are three major types of freshwater wetlands (Barbier et al., 1997):
riverine, palustrine and lacustrine wetlands. Riverine wetlands are areas that are
periodically flooded by a river rising above its banks and include water meadows,
flooded forests and oxbow lakes. Palustrine wetlands are characterized by a
40. 20 Scene Setting
mostly permanent presence of water and include ponds and kettle and volcanic
crater lakes. Lacustrine wetlands are permanently inundated areas with minimal
water flow. The following sections provide an overview of key wetland functions,
linkages to ecosystem services and their relationship with agricultural systems.
Wetland functions
Wetlands provide regulation (hydrological and biogeochemical), production,
habitat and informational functions. The hydrological aspects of a wetland are
critical in defining their characteristics and processes (Maltby, 2009). Three prin-
cipal hydrological functions of wetlands are floodwater detention, groundwater
recharge/discharge and sediment retention (Turner et al., 2008). Table 2.1
describes the linkages between wetland function and ecosystem service, and
presents metrics to assess the presence and level of service provision.
A wetland’s hydrological function contributes to its high productivity through
the capture and cycling of nutrients from upstream (Barbier et al., 1997). Wetlands
reduce overbank flooding and slope run-off (Zedler and Kercher, 2005). By stor-
ing water, wetlands delay and reduce peak flows which could otherwise cause
downstream flood damage. Wetlands may have significant interactions with
groundwater where the substrate between the two is permeable. In these cases,
wetlands may be involved in groundwater recharge and/or discharge of aquifers
(Maltby, 2009). Finally, wetlands serve to retain sediments thereby alleviating
downstream navigational problems, water treatment costs and damage to pump-
ing infrastructure and spawning habitat.
The interaction of a wetland’s biogeochemical function with hydrological
functions enables interactions with surrounding wetlands (Mander et al., 2005).
Specifically, biogeochemical functions of wetlands influence water quality, pollu-
tion control and biodiversity (Mander et al., 2005; Zedler and Kercher, 2005;
Maltby, 2009). Oxidization and reduction processes in the soil are responsible for
significant biogeochemical reactions. Wetland flooding results in oxygen deple-
tion where, through time, organic substrates are consumed and oxygen, nitrates
and other compounds are reduced. The inundation of floodplains facilitates
nutrient exchange; these sites are also often important spawning grounds for fish.
The nutrient retention function of wetlands can affect water quality consider-
ably, especially through the mitigation of incoming pollution. Nutrients and trace
elements may be retained in plant structures or soil and organic matter (Mander
et al., 2005), while nutrient export contributes to water quality maintenance and
occurs through gaseous emission (Zedler, 2003), biomass harvest or erosion.
Carbon is also retained in wetlands and is dependent on waterlogging, pH, nutri-
ents and temperature. The level of pH and aerobic conditions in a wetland affects
biodiversity in terms of the species and community assemblages possible. Organic
carbon concentrations affect water turbidity and pH (Maltby, 2009).
With regards to habitat function, wetlands often support a disproportionately
large amount of biodiversity, including a significant number of rare or endangered
species. Efforts aimed at protecting wetlands are often driven by concern for
their biodiversity (Zedler and Kercher, 2005). A higher level of species diversity
is promoted by ecological disturbance that occurs as a consequence of wetting
41. Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem Services 21
Table 2.1 Wetland ecosystem function, service and indicator.
Ecosystem
function
Ecosystem
service
Establishing
presence State indicator; sustainable yield
Provisioning
Food Fish, game, fruits
and grains
Total or average stock (kgha−1
)
Net productivity (Kcalyear−1
)
Water Water storage for
domestic/
industrial/
agricultural use
Total water (cubic mha−1
)
Net water inflow (m3
year−1
)
Fibre, fuel and
other raw
material
Biotic/ abiotic
resources, e.g.
peat, fodder, fuel
wood
Total biomass (kgha−1
)
Net productivity (kgyear−1
)
Genetic
resources
Genes for pathogen
resistance,
ornamental
species
Number of species
Maximum sustainable harvest
(kgha−1
)
Biochemical
and
medicinal
resources
Potential medicines
and other biotic
materials
Amount of useful substances
(kgha−1
)
Maximum sustainable harvest
(kgha−1
)
Regulating
Air quality Capacity to extract
atmospheric
aerosols and
chemicals
Leaf Area Index or NOx-fixation
Quantity of aerosols/ chemicals
extracted
Climate Influence on global
and local climate
Greenhouse gas balance, carbon
sequestration, land cover
Quantity of GHGs fixed
Water
regulation
Groundwater
recharge/
discharge
Surface or soil water retention
capacity
Quantity of water stored
and influence of
hydrological regime
Waste
treatment
Biotic and abiotic
processes to
remove excess
nutrients/
pollutants
Denitrification (kg Nha−1
year−1
)
Immobilization in plants and soil
Maximum amount of waste
recycled and influence on water
and soil parameters
Erosion
protection
Soil and sediment
retention
Root matrix
Amount of soil/ sediment
captured/ retained
Soil formation
and
regeneration
Natural processes in
soil formation and
regeneration
Bioturbation
Pollination Habitat for
pollinators
Number and impact of pollinating
species
(continued)
42. 22 Scene Setting
and drying cycles of wetlands. The production function of wetlands involves the
conversion of energy, nutrients, water and gases into living biomass. This is a
form of food-web support – the efficient primary production of biomass (Maltby,
2009). This function generates significant human utility through its production
and provision of raw materials. Wetlands also serve an important function in
maintaining habitat connectivity (Zedler, 2003; Mander et al., 2005; Tscharntke
et al., 2005). Finally, information functions contribute to human cognitive, emo-
tional and spiritual health, among other things.
Wetland–agricultural systems interactions
Agricultural systems rely on ecosystem services to enable the production of
food, fibre, bioenergy and pharmaceuticals, and other important commodities.
This present volume as well as recent research discuss in detail the ecosystem
Ecosystem
function
Ecosystem
service
Establishing
presence State indicator; sustainable yield
Biological
regulation
Control of pests
through trophic
relations
Number and impact of pest-
control species
Reduction of disease and pests,
and crop pollination dependence
Natural hazard Forests and
dampening
extreme events
Water storage in cubic meters
Reduction of flood danger and
prevention of infrastructure
damage
Habitat
Nursery Breeding, feeding
and resting habitat
Number of species and individuals
Ecological value
Gene pool Maintenance of
ecological balance
Natural biodiversity; endemic species
Habitat integrity
Information
Aesthetic Structural diversity
and other factors
Number/area of landscape features
Number of sustainable users
Recreational
and
inspirational
Landscape features Number/area of landscape features
Number of sustainable users
Cultural Culturally significant
features
Number/area or presence of
landscape features
Number of users
Spiritual Spiritually significant
features
Number/area or presence of
landscape features
Number of users
Sources: de Groot et al. (2002); de Groot et al. (2006); Food and Agriculture
Organization (2008).
Table 2.1 (Cont’d)
43. Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem Services 23
services on which agriculture depends (Porter et al., 2009; Power, 2010;
Ribaudo et al., 2010; Sandhu et al., 2010a, 2010b, 2012). Approximately 20%
of global agriculture depends on blue water (i.e. freshwater) extracted from
surface water and groundwater resources and close to 70% of global water
withdrawal is used for agricultural purposes (Comprehensive Assessment of
Water Management in Agriculture, 2007). The water filtration service under-
taken by wetlands is therefore critical to agricultural productivity.
In addition to ensuring adequate water quality and supply, wetlands provide
agriculture with services related to pollination, biological pest control, mainte-
nance of soil structure and fertility, and erosion mitigation. Wetlands mitigate
floods and reduce floodwater peaks; they replenish stream flow through subsur-
face flow, contribute to water table recharge and, depending on their position in
the landscape, wetlands may retain water from aquifer discharge (Food and
Agriculture Organization, 2008). Wetlands and riparian areas influence microcli-
mates of adjacent fields by regulating humidity and evapotranspiration, and serve
in filtering often contaminated overland flow from intensively managed
agricultural areas (Mander et al., 2005).
Various crops such as rice, corn, some vegetables and fruits are grown in, or in
proximity to, wetlands. Activities such as fishing, livestock grazing and hay pro-
duction are also conducted in or supported by these ecosystems. Soils in these
areas are typically quite fertile with high clay content, particularly in seasonally
inundated floodplains (Food and Agriculture Organization, 2008). Agricultural
systems themselves produce ecosystem services (Tscharntke et al., 2005): they
sequester carbon, regulate soil fertility, retain and cycle nutrients, and provide
landscapes with aesthetic, cultural and spiritual values (Antle and Stoorvogel,
2006; Porter et al., 2009; Ribaudo et al., 2010). Wetlands support not only agri-
culture in these ways, but also agricultural communities, by providing potable
water and adequate supply for hydroelectric power generation. Wetlands and
agricultural systems are therefore inextricably linked as they provide agriculture
with critical and valuable services.
Negative feedbacks, otherwise known as disservices (Power, 2010), created by
agricultural systems have adverse impacts on wetlands through habitat deteriora-
tion, contamination of fisheries and spawning areas, biodiversity loss, run-off,
sedimentation, greenhouse gas emissions and the release of toxins into the envi-
ronment. The primary pathway by which agricultural systems affect wetlands is
through the diversion of water for irrigation and nutrient loading of nitrogen
and phosphorous (Millennium Ecosystems Assessment, 2005; Comprehensive
Assessment of Water Management in Agriculture, 2007).
Irrigated agriculture in some regions has resulted in soil salinization, equating
to a global loss of 1.5 million hectares of arable land per year. Furthermore, large
quantities of salt from land salinization are transported into wetlands by irriga-
tion run-off, having substantial impacts on biodiversity, productivity and biogeo-
chemical composition in wetlands (Williams, 2001). Changes to water regimes
can have devastating effects on wetlands and their regulating functions including
those dependent on groundwater, surface water and direct rainfall. Wetland
degradation may expose agricultural systems to increased vulnerability to storm,
flood and eutrophication events.
44. 24 Scene Setting
The interactions between wetlands and agricultural systems may be characterized
as in situ or external where the former constitutes an agricultural intervention
within a wetland and the latter is an intervention that is upstream, downstream
or peripheral to a wetland. In situ interactions may involve a substantial transfor-
mation of the wetland ecosystem or a more benign interaction. Significantly
altering the ecosystem could involve drainage, grazing, ploughing or the applica-
tion of pesticides and fertilizers. Fishing or the managed gathering of plants and
animals is considered non-transformative, while enhancement can include
manipulation of wetlands for agricultural or aquacultural purposes, including
the creation of rice paddies, fish ponds and water storage areas (Food and
Agriculture Organization, 2008).
External interactions are more common than direct wetland interventions.
Upstream interactions can involve diversion of water to agriculture which may
have water quantity, quality and flow effects to wetlands situated downstream.
Return flows of diverted water will be lower in quantity and may contain sub-
stantial amounts of nutrients and toxins. Hydraulic gradients may also be cre-
ated resulting in more rapid release of upland water and a lower watertable.
Upstream agricultural practices that create erosion, sedimentation and runoff
are detrimental to wetland ecosystems (Zedler and Kercher, 2005). Less com-
mon is the case where wetlands affect agricultural activity upstream through
their capacity for water storage and sediment retention; should their capacity
in this regard be compromised, upstream waterlogging of agricultural areas
may result (Food and Agriculture Organization, 2008). Furthermore, these
types of interactions are seldom confined to one agricultural production unit
and wetland, rather these interactions typically occur and are compounded at
the catchment scale.
Some research challenges
Understanding complexity and resilience
Ecosystems provide numerous goods and services, many of which have indirect
value and are not traded in the market place. Our understanding of the ecosys-
tem functions underpinning these services is limited, complicated by the spatial
and temporal scales over which ecosystem services operate, and the interdepend-
encies between ecosystem components and functions. Ecosystem functions are
dynamic, exhibiting thresholds, complementary relationships to keystone
processes, and system integrity and irreversibility (Turner et al., 2008). A thresh-
old occurs where an ecosystem may cease to function or may function in an
alternative undesirable state because one or more of its attributes are degraded
beyond a specific level. Complementary relationships describe the interactions
and interdependence of ecosystem components where the survival of one species
depends on the existence of other species. These relationships have contributory
value, which is a reflection of limited substitution possibilities. The notion of
keystone processes describes system dependence on a limited number of ecosys-
tem functions. A reduction in ecosystem diversity (e.g. structural or species
45. Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem Services 25
diversity) can affect system resilience and adaptability to shocks. Ecosystem
structure and function reflects the notion that the health of an ecosystem depends
on system integrity and the whole functioning of the system.
Trade-offs
Management and planning for wetlands and agriculture should focus on enhanc-
ing multifunctionality where multiple ecosystem services are provided for human
well-being and economic development. There is great potential to achieve syner-
gies and win–win outcomes from effective planning and the development of
economic incentives (DeFries and Rosenzweig, 2010; Gordon et al., 2010;
Raudsepp-Hearne et al., 2010). However, the less desirable lose–lose or lose–win
outcomes are commonplace due to trade-offs between services and agriculture
production (Tallis et al., 2008; Gordon et al., 2010; Crossman et al., 2011).
Trade-offs arise when provisioning services, especially agricultural production,
seem to conflict with regulating, habitat and information services. Globally, most
wetland ecosystems have been heavily modified to make way for food provision-
ing at the expense of other ecosystem services (Comprehensive Assessment of
Water Management in Agriculture, 2007). The principle cause for the decline of
ecosystem services other than provisioning services, and a major barrier to the
evolution of multifunctional landscapes, is the lack of economic valuation of
these services. Where the value of these services is not accounted for in decision-
making frameworks, such as cost–benefit analysis, the importance of these
services in support of agricultural production are overlooked and trade-offs may
be made using poor information.
Management of wetlands and surrounding agricultural landscapes needs to
account for the values of multiple ecosystem services (Carpenter et al., 2009).
While there are an increasing number of examples of the creation of markets for
ecosystem goods and services, including the provision of freshwater (Carroll
et al., 2008; Bayon et al., 2009; Garrick et al., 2009), markets for most services
are either absent or immature, leading to a lack of appropriate price signals for
enhancing multifunctionality. Major challenges that lie ahead are the design of
efficient markets for ecosystem service provision, and the development of strong
institutions and regulatory instruments that underpin these markets. The goal is
the sustainable growth of agricultural provisioning services without increasing
the production of ecosystem disservices as these markets and institutions evolve.
References
Acharya, G. (2000). Approaches to Valuing the hidden hydrological services of wetland
ecosystems. Ecological Economics, 35, 63–74.
Antle, J.M. and Stoorvogel, J.J. (2006). Predicting the supply of ecosystem services from
agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 88, 1174–1180.
Balvanera, P
., Pfisterer, A.B., Buchmann, N., et al. (2006). Quantifying the evidence for
biodiversity effects on ecosystem functioning and services. Ecology Letters, 9, 1146–1156.
Barbier, E.B., Acreman, M. and Knowler, D. (1997). Economic Valuation of Wetlands. A
Guide for Policy Makers and Planners. Ramsar Convention Bureau, Gland.
46. 26 Scene Setting
Bayon, R., Hawn, A. and Hamilton, K. (2009). Voluntary Carbon Markets: An International
Business Guide to What They Are and How They Work. Earthscan, London.
Carpenter, S.R., Mooney, H.A., Agard, J., et al. (2009). Science for managing ecosystem
services: beyond the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences, 106, 1305–1312.
Carroll, N., Fox, J. and Bayon, R. (eds) (2008). Conservation and Biodiversity Banking: A
Guide to Setting up and Running Biodiversity Credit Trading Systems. Earthscan, London.
Comprehensive Assessment of Water Management in Agriculture (2007). Water for Food,
Water for Life: A Comprehensive Assessment of Water Management in Agriculture.
Earthscan and International Water Management Institute, London and Colombo.
Costanza, R., D’Arge, R., De Groot, R., et al. (1997). The value of the world’s ecosystem
services and natural capital. Nature, 387, 253–260.
Crossman, N.D., Bryan, B.A. and Summers, N.D. (2011). Carbon payments and low cost
conservation. Conservation Biology, 25, 835–845.
Daily, G.C. (ed.) (1997). Nature’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems.
Island Press, Washington, DC.
Daily, G.C., Polasky, S., Goldstein, J., et al. (2009). Ecosystem services in decision mak-
ing: time to deliver. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 7, 21–28.
DeFries, R. and Rosenzweig, C. (2010). Toward a whole-landscape approach for sustain-
able land use in the tropics. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107,
19627–19632.
de Groot, R.S. (1992). Functions of Nature: Evaluation of Nature in Environmental
Planning Management and Decision Making. Wolters-Noordhoff, Amsterdam.
de Groot, R.S., Alkemade, R., Braat, L., Hein, L. and Willemen, L. (2010). Challenges in
integrating the concept of ecosystem services and values in landscape planning, man-
agement and decision making. Ecological Complexity, 7, 260–272.
de Groot, R.S., Stuip, M.A.M., Finlayson, C.M. and Davidson, N. (2006). Valuing
Wetlands: Guidance for Valuing the Benefits Derived from Wetland Ecosystem Services.
Secretariat of the Convention on Wetlands and the Secretariat of the Convention on
Biological Diversity, Gland and Montreal.
de Groot, R.S., Wilson, M.A. and Boumans, R.M.J. (2002). A typology for the classifica-
tion, description and valuation of ecosystem functions, goods and services. Ecological
Economics, 41, 393–408.
Food and Agriculture Organization (2008). Scoping Agriculture–Wetland Interactions,
Towards a Sustainable Multiple-Response Strategy. FAO Water Reports, 33. Available
at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/011/i0314e/i0314e00.htm (accessed August 2012).
Garrick, D., Siebentritt, M.A., Aylward, B., Bauer, C.J. and Purkey, A. (2009). Water
Markets and freshwater ecosystem services: policy reform and implementation in the
Columbia and Murray-Darling basins. Ecological Economics, 69, 366–379.
Gordon, L.J., Finlayson, C.M. and Falkenmark, M. (2010). Managing water in agricul-
ture for food production and other ecosystem services. Agricultural Water Management,
97, 512–519.
Maltby, E. (2009). Functional Assessment of Wetlands: Towards Evaluation of Ecosystem
Services. Woodhead Publishing, Cambridge.
Mander, Ü., Hayakawa, Y. and Kuusemets, V
. (2005). Purification processes, ecological
functions, planning and design of riparian buffer zones in agricultural watersheds.
Ecological Engineering, 24, 421–432.
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2003). Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: A
Framework for Assessment. Island Press, Washington, DC.
Millennium Ecosystems Assessment (2005). Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: Synthesis.
Island Press, Washington, DC.
National Research Council (2005). Valuing Ecosystem Services. Toward Better
Environmental Decision-Making. National Academies Press, Washington, DC.
Perrings, C. (2006). Ecological economics after the millennium assessment. International
Journal of Ecological Economics and Statistics, 6, 8–22.
47. Ecological Processes, Functions and Ecosystem Services 27
Porter, J., Costanza, R., Sandhu, H., Sigsgaard, L. and Wratten, S. (2009). The value of
producing food, energy, and ecosystem services within an agro-ecosystem. AMBIO: A
Journal of the Human Environment, 38, 186–193.
Power, A.G. (2010). Ecosystem services and agriculture: tradeoffs and synergies.
Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 365 (1554),
2959–2971.
Raudsepp-Hearne, C., Peterson, G.D. and Bennett, E.M. (2010). Ecosystem service bun-
dles for analyzing tradeoffs in diverse landscapes. Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences, 107, 5242–5247.
Ribaudo, M., Greene, C., Hansen, L. and Hellerstein, D. (2010). Ecosystem services from
agriculture: steps for expanding markets. Ecological Economics, 69, 2085–2092.
Sandhu, H.S., Crossman, N.D. and Smith, F.P
. (2012). Ecosystem services and Australian
agricultural enterprises. Ecological Economics, 74, 19–26.
Sandhu, H.S., Wratten, S.D. and Cullen, R. (2010a). Organic agriculture and ecosystem
services. Environmental Science and Policy, 13, 1–7.
Sandhu, H.S., Wratten, S.D. and Cullen, R. (2010b). The role of supporting ecosystem
services in conventional and organic arable farmland. Ecological Complexity, 7,
302–310.
Spangenberg, J.H. and Settele, J. (2010). Precisely incorrect? Monetising the value of
ecosystem services. Ecological Complexity, 7, 327–337.
Tallis, H., Kareiva, P
., Marvier, M. and Chang, A. (2008). An ecosystem services frame-
work to support both practical conservation and economic development. Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences, 105, 9457–9464.
TEEB (ed.) (2010). The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity: Ecological and
Economic Foundations. Earthscan, London.
Tscharntke, T., Klein, A.M., Kruess, A., Steffan-Dewenter, I. and Thies, C. (2005).
Landscape perspectives on agricultural intensification and biodiversity – ecosystem ser-
vice management. Ecology Letters, 8, 857–874.
Turner, R.K., Georgiou, S. and Fisher, B. (2008). Valuing Ecosystem Services: The Case of
Multi-Functional Wetlands. Earthscan, London.
Turner, R.K., van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., Söderqvist, T., et al. (2000). Ecological-economic
analysis of wetlands: scientific integration for management and policy. Ecological
Economics, 35, 7–23.
Willemen, L., Hein, L. and Verburg, P
.H. (2010). Evaluating the impact of regional devel-
opment policies on future landscape services. Ecological Economics, 69, 2244–2254.
Williams, W
.D. (2001). Anthropogenic salinisation of inland waters. Hydrobiologia, 466,
329–337.
Wilson, M.A. and Howarth, R.B. (2002). Discourse-based valuation of ecosystem
services: establishing fair outcomes through group deliberation. Ecological Economics,
41, 431–443.
Woodward, R.T. and Wui, Y.-S. (2001). The economic value of wetland services: a meta-
analysis. Ecological Economics, 37, 257–270.
Zedler, J.B. (2003). Wetlands at your service: reducing impacts of agriculture at the
watershed scale. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 1, 65–72.
Zedler, J.B. and Kercher, S. (2005). Wetland resources: status, trends, ecosystem services
and restorability. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 30, 39–74.
49. Key Ideas and Concepts from Economics 29
because most people use currency as a unit of value and medium of exchange
(Costanza et al., 1997; Daily, 1997; Daily et al., 1997; de Groot et al., 2002).
Placing a dollar value on ecosystem services requires extensive reflection on
the interconnectedness of ecosystems. As there are so many ecosystem services,
there are also many ecosystem service values, from the price of gold, to the value
of swimming in a stream, to the value of the safety of a fledgling in a bird nest on
a tall cliff (Pearce and Turner, 1990; Merlo and Croitoru, 2005). By considering
all ecosystem service values, the total economic value of nature is considered.
The total economic value approach depends on the spatial and temporal scales
being assessed, thus requiring analysts to be clear about the intended scope of
their study. The total economic value conceptual framework views ecosystem
goods and services as the flows of benefits and costs provided by the stock of
natural capital (eftec, 2006).
Because there are so many types of ecosystem services, it is often preferable to
group them together before attempting to calculate their value. The Millennium
Ecosystem Assessment (2005) divided ecosystem services into four categories:
supporting, provisioning, regulation and cultural services. Similarly, de Groot et
al. (2002) also divided ecosystem services into four categories: regulation, habi-
tat, production and information. In order to calculate the total economic value
of ecosystem services, it may be easier to think of these services according to the
type of value they provide (Fig. 3.1). Values can be assessed in the ways in which
ecosystem services provide intangible benefits, or non-use values, where the
resource is not directly used, and ways in which they support consumption, or
use values, where the resource is being used.
More specifically, non-use values include altruistic, existence, bequest and
option value. Altruistic value is the value people have knowing that others can
enjoy goods and services from ecosystem services, even though they may never
enjoy them themselves. For example, people may value knowing that others
enjoy viewing the wildlife in Kenya’s national parks and reserves, even though
they will never go there to see the wildlife themselves. Existence value is derived
from the satisfaction of knowing that a certain species or ecosystem exists, even
if it will never be seen or used directly. An example of an existence value is know-
ing and feeling good about the existence of the blue whale, the largest mammal
in the world living today. A person may believe that it is important that blue
whales exist even though they may never see them although they may read about
it in a book or see it on a television or movie programme. Bequest value is the
satisfaction one obtains from being able to pass on environmental benefits to
future generations. In this way, a person knows that the wildlife in Kenya’s
national parks and reserves will be available for their grandchildren and great
grandchildren to visit someday. Option value pertains to the value people have
knowing they have the option to use a resource in the future, even if they never
do. This value relates to uncertainty and risk aversion, in that they are unsure
they will ever use it, but don’t want to risk the chance of it being lost.
Use values focus on the actual use of a resource and can be further subdivided
into direct-use values, where a resource is directly being used in some way, and
indirect-use values, where the resource is only indirectly being used. Direct use is
further divided into extractive-use values that are extracted or consumed from
50. 30 Scene Setting
ecosystems, such as logging and fishing, and non-extractive-use values, from
activities that are directly enjoyed, such as swimming, bird watching and cross-
country skiing. The indirect-use value is referred to as a non-extractive-use value
derived from functional services that the environment provides. For example,
ecosystem regulatory processes that indirectly provide support and protection
include erosion control and ultraviolet radiation protection (Freeman, 2003;
National Research Council, 2005; Anderson, 2006; Tietenberg, 2006; Hanley
and Barbier, 2009).
Total economic value
of ecosystem services
Market values
(the dollar value
people
knowingly pay
for an ES)
Non-market
values
(ES is not
directly
exchanged on
the market,
but may be
indirectly
exchanged)
Non-use
values –
includes
altruistic,
existence,
bequest, and
option value
Use values
(when people
use the
resource in
some way,
but do not
directly pay
to use it)
Use values
(when people
use the
resource in
some way
and directly
pay to use it)
Direct use
values – can
be extractive
(e.g.,
purchasing
lumber) or
non-extractive
(e.g., the fee
paid to climb
at a
rockclimbing
crag)
Non-use
values (e.g.,
paying
someone to
protect a
beach that
they will
never visit to
save an
endangered
species)
Indirect use
values (e.g.,
volunteering to
pay your
homeowners
association extra
money for an
erosion control
project in your
neighborhood)
Direct use
values – can
be extractive
(e.g., picking
wild berries you
don’t pay a fee
for) or non-
extractive
(e.g.,
swimming,
assuming
there is no fee)
Indirect use
values – (e.g.,
natural flood
and erosion
control)
Fig. 3.1 Total economic value of ecosystem services. Note that market values are
typically measured as direct use values; whereas indirect use and non-use values are
more commonly measured as non-market values.
51. Key Ideas and Concepts from Economics 31
The next step is to determine whether the resource was paid for directly, as
then it is considered a market value, or whether it was not paid for directly, or
not paid for at all, as then it is a non-market value. For consumptive goods, when
directly using a resource, such as eating a fish that you have purchased, we can
consider the market value, in that a specific amount of money is exchanged in a
market by people to directly use these products. When paying for something that
will not be used directly, such as giving money to your neighbour’s son to raise
bees, you are experiencing an indirect-use market value. More specifically, since
the son is raising bees for honey and not providing you with any of the honey, but
you are still benefitting from the bees’ pollination of the flowers in your yard, it
is an indirect-use market value. However, if you donate money to sponsor a trip
for your neighbour’s son to work on an island to prevent poachers from stealing
turtle eggs, you have a non-use market value because you feel good about saving
the turtles even though you may never see them (Pearce and Turner, 1990;
Freeman, 2003; National Research Council, 2005; Anderson, 2006).
Using similar examples, if you are fishing on your uncle’s boat on the ocean
and catch and eat a fish, but do not pay directly for this fish, as you do not need
a fishing license to fish on the ocean, it is a non-market direct-use value. You have
value in this trip, as you chose to go on the trip, may have paid for petrol to drive
to your uncle’s house and may pay to camp overnight somewhere to get there,
but you did not pay ‘directly’ for the fish. If you did not give money to your
neighbour’s son for the bees, but the bees are still pollinating your flowers, you
have an indirect non-market-use value. And if you did not give your neighbour’s
son any money to work on the island, but still feel good about him being there
saving the turtles, you have a non-market non-use value for the turtles (Freeman,
2003; Anderson, 2006; Hanley and Barbier, 2009).
It is clear that a single person may benefit in more than one way from the same
ecosystem. Thus, total economic value is the sum of all the relevant use and non-
use, market and non-market values, for goods and services in a particular ecosys-
tem.Thesemeasuresofvaluecanbeincludedinpolicyandotherland-management
decisions.
Ecosystem service valuation methodologies
Economists have developed a number of market and non-market techniques to
estimate the value of the environmental amenities from ecosystem services. Market
values are calculated as out-of-pocket expenses and can be used to estimate the
value of ecosystem goods and services that are traded in formal markets, such as
the sale of timber and fish. Market values also include for example a decrease in
the productivity of a fish stock, caused by an environmental effect such as an oil
spill, that could lead to an earnings loss of a person dependant on fishing for their
income. Defensive or preventive expenditures are another type of market value.
These expenditures are made by a firm, government or individual to avoid or
reduce an unwanted effect. An example of a defensive expenditure is the purchase
of a water filter to drink water from a well contaminated by an unwanted chemi-
cal that leached into the groundwater system from a nearby mining operation.
52. 32 Scene Setting
Methods for measuring non-market values fall into two general categories:
revealed preference and stated preference methods (Freeman, 2003; Hanley and
Barbier, 2009). Revealed preference methods are based on observations of actual
behaviour and allow us to make inferences about how individuals value changes
in environmental quality. In contrast, stated preference measurements are based
on responses to survey questions. Some common non-market valuation methods
used today include the contingent valuation method, choice experiments, the
travel cost method, and the hedonic pricing method. These methods are described
briefly.
Revealed preference methods
The travel cost method sometimes called the Clawson Method, is a revealed
preference method in that the respondent is revealing something that they actu-
ally did. Here, they report on the time they took and the costs they incurred to
take a specific trip, costs that they would not have spent normally. An example is
determining the cost of travelling to a lake to fish and camp. To do this, extra
money is spent on fuel and camping fees, assuming the person already has all of
their fishing equipment (Pearce and Turner, 1990; Haab and McConnell, 2002;
Kahn, 2005; Anderson, 2006; Hackett, 2006).
Hedonic pricing is a revealed preference method that investigates the prices
people pay for specific goods for the purpose of valuing an environmental
resource. Oftentimes, the price that is investigated is a house/ property price. For
example, to determine the value of seeing the beach from a house, the researcher
could compare the price of houses overlooking a beach to equivalent homes one
block away without a beach view (Hussen, 2000; Haab and McConnell, 2002;
Kahn, 2005; Anderson, 2006; Hackett, 2006).
Stated preference methods
The contingent valuation method is sometimes called the willingness-to-pay or
willingness-to-accept method. It is a stated preference method in that a person
‘states’ what they will do if a hypothetical situation were to arise. More specifi-
cally, they state how much they are willing-to-pay (willing-to-accept) for a change
in a particular good or service. An example is the amount of money they would
be willing-to-pay to hunt for deer in an area, if they were guaranteed to see at
least some deer on a particular hunting trip (Hussen, 2000; Haab and McConnell,
2002; Daly and Farley, 2004; Kahn, 2005; Anderson, 2006; Hackett, 2006).
Choice modelling is a stated preference method in which a respondent is faced
with a variety of alternatives and may be asked to select their most preferred
alternative from a choice set (choice experiment), group their preferences
(contingent grouping), rate their preferences (contingent rating), or rank their
preferences (contingent ranking). There will typically be three or four alternative
strategies with similar attributes (per question) presented to the respondents. An
53. Key Ideas and Concepts from Economics 33
example of choice modelling alternatives include variations in the risk of toxic
chemicals reaching the groundwater, the percentage of harvested trees, the per-
centage of species diversity, as well as a dollar value, such as an entrance fee or a
fee in your annual taxes/ rates (Louviere et al., 2000; Bateman et al., 2002;
Hensher et al., 2005; Street and Burgess, 2007; Riera et al., 2012).
These four methods, together with direct-market values, can aid us in valuing
many ecosystem services. But they fall short of valuing all ecosystem services, for
which other methods must be employed. These include the avoided cost method,
the replacement cost method, the restoration cost method, factor income, and
the benefit transfer method.1
Other methods
Avoided cost methods attempt to quantify the costs we do not have to pay
when nature is providing a particular good. One example is to calculate the value
of storm and buffer functions provided by coastal wetlands in the event of a hur-
ricane or cyclone. To do this, you could calculate the potential financial losses if
the wetlands did not exist. In 2005, Hurricane Katrina caused over $US81 billion
damage to the New Orleans area. If the wetlands around New Orleans had not
been destroyed by years of alterations to the Mississippi River, New Orleans
would not have been almost completely exposed to the Gulf of Mexico, and
there may not have been any, or as much, damage (Daily, 1997; Daily, 1997;
Knabb, 2006; Cleveland, 2006).
Replacement cost is a method used to calculate the cost of replacing a service
with a human-created product, such as fertilizers to replace the nutrients that are
recycled by earthworms and benefit the soil (Hussen, 2000; Kahn, 2005).
Restoration cost is a method used to calculate the cost of restoring an ecosys-
tem to the natural state that existed prior to an environmental damage, such as
the cost of repairing the environmental damage caused by the Exxon Valdez Oil
Spill of 1989 (Bragg et al., 1994; Kahn, 2005).
Factor income is the value of an ecosystem service that enhances the market
value of ecosystem services. For example, bees pollinate the flowers of the agri-
cultural crops sold on the market (Woodward and Wui, 2001; Brander et al.,
2006). The marginal benefit of pollination services to the crop can be used to
estimate the value of the service provided by the bees.
1
Some studies also consider group valuation or discourse based methods to obtain values for ecosystem
services. In a discourse based study, people get together in a designated location and discuss their values
for an ecosystem good or service. Since ecosystem services are commonly public goods that affect many
people, some feel that the valuation of these public services should not come from individual-based values,
such as in the previous approaches used, but from public discussion. In this way, the values derived are
considered those of society and are believed to lead to socially equitable and politically legitimate out-
comes (Wilson and Howarth, 2002). Consequently, this method focuses on qualitative values. The focus
of this study is quantitative methods, therefore, this method is not being considered here.
54. 34 Scene Setting
Benefit transfer or value transfer, is a method used as a result of time limita-
tions and/or budget constraints and focuses on applying secondary data. In this
method, a researcher uses existing economic valuation information from a study
conducted in a particular area, called the study site, and transfers those values to
a new site or area, sometimes called the policy site. Care should be made to trans-
fer values from an area that is similar to the policy site (Kaval and Loomis, 2003;
Kahn, 2005). There are two types of benefit transfers: value transfers and
function transfers. A value-transfer approach takes a single point estimate, usually
a mean willingness-to-pay or an average of point estimates from multiple studies
that have been developed elsewhere, to transfer to a new study area. A function
transfer approach transfers the entire estimated equation (function) of a study
site to the policy site. For example, a travel cost demand equation from a study
site could be used with the socioeconomic or demographic characteristics such as
income, average travel costs and quality conditions at the policy site to estimate
the average willingness-to-pay of different proposed plans at the policy site.
While this method is listed under non-market valuation methods, it can also be
used to transfer market values.
Table 3.1 is an extension of the de Groot et al. (2002) table and provides a list
of ecosystem services, their value types, as well as the methods commonly used
to calculate their dollar value. As can be seen, researchers use different methods
to calculate values. Recreation, for example, is a direct use value and can be cal-
culated as a market or non-market value. If you paid money to use an indoor
climbing wall, the price paid is a market value. However, if you went to climb in
a park that does not charge an entrance fee, this would be considered a non-
market value. Non-market-valuation methods commonly used to calculate rec-
reation values include the contingent-valuation method, travel-cost method,
choice experiments, factor income, hedonic method, avoided costs, restoration
costs and the benefit-transfer method. Science and education, on the other hand,
are considered a market value and a direct use. Valuation methods commonly
used for science and education include market valuation and benefit transfer
(Hartwick and Olewiler, 1998; de Groot et al., 2002; Kahn, 2005).
As can be seen, the valuation method used will depend on the type of service
being studied. Many different methods can work for any given service, and the
method of choice depends on the availability of the resources, time, data, specific
characteristics and goals of the study.
How ecosystem services have been measured in the past
Ecosystem service studies are well represented in the literature, even if they were
not always termed as such. One of the first and most thorough, original longitu-
dinal ecosystem service studies that predated this discipline was a Rhone Poulenc
farm management study conducted by Higgenbotham et al. (Higginbotham et al.,
1997, 1999, 2000). In this seminal study that began in 1994 on 57 hectares
in Essex, they compared organic farming to reduced input and conventional
farming for a variety of crops. They not only estimated the values, costs and
yields of the crops, but also measured food quality, the taste of the final goods,
56. Wayteglede, == watch-the-fire, i. e. one who sits in the chimney
corner, poking over the fire? Wright’s L. P. p. 47. Cf. the Norse phrase
Kólbitr; and see the Introduction to Dasent’s Popular Tales from the
Norse, pp. lxxx-lxxxii. 1st Edit.
We. See Woe
We. See I
We. See With
Weak, adj. HD. 1012
Weal, sb. 1277 B.
Wealth, sb. Ps. lxxii. 12
Weapon, sb. HD. 1436. O. and N. 1367
Wear, v. a. RG. 390; pret, ‘werede.’ RG. 434
Weariness, sb. RG. 240
Weary, adj. RG. 19
Weather, sb. RG. 560
Web, sb. Fr. Sci. 315
Webbe, sb. == weaver. Pol. S. 188
Wed, sb. == pledge. Pol. S. 151. Wright’s L. P. p. 110. RG. 393. AS.
wed
Wed, v. a. == marry. RG. 295, 439; said of the priest who marries
two persons. Pol. S. 159. AS. weddian, wed
Wedbreak, sb. == adulterer. Ps. xlix. 18
Wedding, sb. St Lucy, 88. Manuel des Pecches, 1712
Wede, vb. == wade, go. See Wade
57. Wedlock, sb. Marg. 11
Wednesday. RG. 509
Wee. See Woe
Weed, sb. == garment. RG. 560. AS. wǽd
Weed, sb. == herb. Alys. 796. AS. weód
Week, sb. RG. 113; pl. ‘wouke.’ RG. 387. AS. weoc
Weeles. See Well, sb.
Ween, v. n. == think. RG. 369. O. and N. 237. 2 s. pres. ‘wanst.’ O.
and N. 1642. AS. wénan
—— v. a. == impute. Ps. xxxi. 2
Weep, v. n. RG. 420; [wyppen]. O. and N. 1064
Weeping, sb. RG. 405. Wright’s L. P. p. 30; [wyping]. Ibid. p. 85
Wef, sb. == whiff or scent. Body and Soul, 56. AS. wiffan
Weight, sb. == a measure, weight. Ps. lxi. 10. AS. wæg
Weir, sb. Ps. cxiii. 8; [wore]. Wright’s L. P. p. 28. AS. wǽr
Welaway, interj. 1179 B.
Welcome, adj. RG. 508
—— v. a. 473 B.
Welde. See Wield
Welk, v. n. == fade, become pale. Ps. lxxxix. 6. See Weolewe
Welkin, sb. == the sky. Wright’s L. P. p. 114; [walken]. Alys. 5799.
Ps. cl. 1; dat. s. ‘weoluce.’ O. and N. 1680. AS. welcn, wolcen
Well, adj. == good. 89 B.
58. —— adv. RG. 375. O. and N. 31
—— == rightly. Rel. S. i. 20
Well, sb. (of water). RG. 1. Wright’s L. P. p. 94; pl. ‘weeles.’ Ps. xvii.
5. AS. well, wyl
Well, v. n. == boil, well up. Wright’s L. P. p. 40; [walle]. RG. 28;
pret. ‘wal.’ Body and Soul, 218; part. ‘wallyng.’ Alys. 1622. AS.
weallan
—— v. a. == boil. Marg. 60
Wellnigh, adv. == almost. O. and N. 44
Wellquemand, part. == pleasing. Ps. xci. 15
Wellqueme, sb. == pleasure. Ps. lxxxviii. 18; cv. 4
Wellquemeness, sb. == pleasingness. Ps. cxl. 5
Wellset, v. a. Ps. civ. 9; cxi. 5
Wellsetting, sb. Ps. cxviii. 91
Welly, adv. == kindly. Ps. l. 20
Wem, sb. == a spot or scar. RG. 336. St Kath. 151. AS. wem,
womm
Wem, v. a. == to defile, corrupt. Ps. lxxxviii. 35; [wemmy]. RG.
206; part. ‘wemmed.’ Ps. xv. 10. AS. wemman
Wemed, adj. ‘prout wemod’ == with a proud stomach. Fr. Sci. 285.
‘Wem’ is still used for ‘womb’ in the North of England. AS. wamb
Wemless, adj. == spotless. Creed of St Athan. 6. Ps. xiv. 2
Wemmand, sb. == sinner. Ps. cxviii. 158
Wemmedness, sb. Ps. c. 3
59. Wemming, sb. RG. 336
Wemmy, v. a. == defile. See Wem, vb.
Wench, sb. Cok. 139. Ps. lxvii. 26. AS. wencle. See Gloss. to Orm. s.
v. wenchell
Wend, v. n. == go. RG. 8. AS. wendan
—— == turn (as in bed). Wright’s L. P. p. 28
—— v. a. == turn. HD. 2138; change. Wright’s L. P. p. 91
Wending, sb. == departure. Alys. 920
Wene, adj. == frequent, rife? Pol. S. 150. AS. wune, custom. Dut.
wennen
Weole, sb. == wealth. Pol. S. 156. AS. weola
—— == happiness? Wright’s L. P. p. 44
Weolewe, v. n. == fade, become pale. Wright’s L. P. p. 50. AS.
wealwian
Wepmon, sb. == man. Pol. S. 153. O. and N. 1377. AS. wæpman
Were. See Be
Were, v. a. == defend. HD. 2298. Alys. 5836; [werye]. Alys. 3533.
AS. werian. Germ. wehren
Were, sb. == man, husband. O. and N. 1339. AS. wer
Werewed, part. == worried, killed? HD. 1915
Werien, v. a. == curse. O. and N. 1172; [werre]. Manuel des
Pecches, 1291; [warye]. Id. 1292. AS. werigan
Werth, == throweth. See Warp
60. Weryying, sb. == protection. Wright’s L. P. p. 75. Ps. xxi. 20;
[weryng]. Alys. 2798. AS. werian
West. RG. 544
West, vb. == shows? Alys. 238. AS. wísian
Westerness, sb. == the West country. K. Horn, 949
Westward, adv. RG. 20
Wet, sb. Fr. Sci. 136. AS. wæt
—— v. a. Wright’s L. P. p. 31; pret. ‘watte.’ RG. 322; part. ‘wet.’
Wright’s L. P. p. 30
—— v. n. == become wet. Wright’s L. P. p. 36
—— adj. [wete]. Wright’s L. P. p. 85
Wete, v. n. == weep. Wright’s L. P. p. 84
Wether, sb. Ps. lxiv. 14. RG. 52. AS. weðer
Weve, v. a. == make to go, cut off; part. ‘weved,’ ‘yweved.’ Alys.
3839, 3807
Weve, v. n. == go, move. RG. 64. Another form of ‘wawe,’ ‘wave,’
‘wag’
Weved, sb. == altar. RG. 369, 419, 433. AS. weofod
Weye, sb. == woe, q. v.
Weȝe, v. a. == carry, O. and N. 1020. AS. wegan
Whale, sb. [hwal]. HD. 755; [qual]. HD. 753. AS. hwæl
Whalebone, sb. [whalles bone]. Wright’s L. P. p. 38
What, interr. pron. O. and N. 1438
—— rel. pron. O. and N. 1439
61. —— interj. O. and N. 1296
What—what, == some—some. RG. 402
Whate, adv. == quickly. Alys. 2639. AS. hwæt
Whatkin, adj. == what kind of. Ps. lv. 10
Whatloker, adj. == much rather. RG. 429, 357. 1249 B. (?) AS.
hwætlíc, comp. hwætlicor
Wheat, sb. Alys. 5193. AS. hwǽte
Wheel, sb. RG. 408. AS. hweol
Whelp, sb. Ps. ciii. 21. AS. hwelp
When, adv. [wanne]. RG. 367, 378; [hwenne]. Rel. S. iv. 1;
[hwanne]. O. and N. 1416; [hwan]. O. and N. 1468; [whan]. 290 β;
[wane]. O. and N. 521; [wone]. O. and N. 324
Whence, adv. gen. of ‘when;’ [whonene]. O. and N. 138; [wanene].
O. and N. 1298; [whannes]. 288 β; [whethen]. Ps. cxx. 1
Where, adv. [war]. RG. 40. O. and N. 526; [whar]. 1078 B.
Whereby, adv. [warbi]. RG. 101
Wherefore, adv. 126 B.
Whereof, adv. RG. 405
Wheresoever, adv. 1389 B.
Wherethrough, adv. [war þoru]. RG. 432
Whereto, adv. 447 B. O. and N. 464
Whet, v. a. == sharpen; part. ‘y-whet.’ Alys. 6607. AS. hwettan
Whethen, == whence, q. v.
62. Whether, adv. RG. 16; [whar]. 67 B; ‘whether—the’ == whether—
or. O. and N. 1358, 1360
—— adj. RG. 408
Whey, sb. [wei]. O. and N. 1007. AS. wæg
Which, rel. pron. RG. 472; [hwucche]. O. and N. 934; [wuch]. O.
and N. 1376
—— == what. 974 B. RG. 454
While, sb. == time. O. and N. 1589
—— with the def. art. == whilst [þe wule]. RG. 377
Whilom, adv. == formerly (dat. pl. of while). Wright’s L. P. p. 87
Whine, v. n. [wonie]. O. and N. 973. AS. wánian. Dut. weynen
Whining, sb. [wonyng]. O. and N. 311
Whistle, v. n. Alys. 5348, 5263. AS. hwistlian
White, adj. RG. 2, 228; [with]. HD. 48
—— sb. == white of an egg. HD. 240
Whiten, v. a. Ps. l. 9
Whither, adv. 693 B.
Whitherward, adv. 59 B.
Who, rel. pron. [hoo]. RG. 40; [hwo]. O. and N. 1193
gen. ‘was.’ RG. 475
dat. and acc. ‘whom.’ RG. 10; ‘wham.’ 116 B.; ‘hwam.’ Rel. S. ii. 2;
‘hwan.’ O. and N. 1508
Who, == one, ‘as who seith’ == as one saith. RG. 328; ‘alle ho’ ==
every one. O. and N. 66
63. Whole, adj. == sound. RG. 377. 676 β
Whore, sb. RG. 279
Whoredom, sb. RG. 241, 479
Whoreling, sb. Rel. S. vii. 29
Whoreson, sb. Alys. 880
Whoso, pron. Wright’s L. P. p. 26; [whose]. Ibid. p. 114
Why, interr. [wu]. RG. 307; [hwi]. O. and N. 1256; [wi]. O. and N.
1232
—— rel. adv. O. and N. 474; [whi]. 1573 B.
Wick, adj. == wicked. RG. 208. From AS. wǽc, weak
—— == bad, wretched; ‘wikke clothes.’ HD. 2458
Wicke, adj. ‘wicke tune,’ O. and N. 730, means probably
‘establishments.’ From the AS. wíc-tunas
Wicked, adj. Wright’s L. P. pp. 24, 30; ‘a wicked weed’ == a
wretched garment. Serm. 40
Wickedness, sb. Pol. S. 230
Wickehede, sb. == wickedness. Body and Soul, 43
Wicket, sb. K. Horn, 1106. Fr. guichet
Wiclik, adv. == wickedly. Ps. xliii. 18
Wide, adj. RG. 410.
Widow, sb. HD. 79. AS. wuduwe
Wield, v. a. == govern, rule. 816 B.; [wolde]. RG. 147
Wife, sb. RG. 26, 380
64. Wigeling, sb. == an out-of-the-way place? Ps. cvi. 40. AS. wicelian,
to stagger, to go out of the direct road
Wight, sb. == a man. RG. 533. 470 β. AS. wiht
Wight, adj. == active. HD. 9; [with]. HD. 1756; comp. ‘wyghtyore.’
Alys. 2396. Swed. vig
—— adv. == immediately, quickly. Wright’s L. P. p. 44
Wighth, sb. == a space of time. Alys. 5362; a space. Ps. viii. 6. AS.
wuht, wiht
Wightness, sb. == valour, activity. Alys. 5001
Wike, sb. == dwelling. O. and N. 604. AS. wic
Wike, sb. == office, duty. O. and N. 603; station. Alys. 4608. See
Gl. to Orm. s. v. Wikenn
Wike, v. n. == be weary. Wright’s L. P. p. 87. AS. wícan
Wikness, sb. == wickedness. Ps. v. 5
Wil, adj. == wild, uncertain. HD. 1042
Wild, adj. == fierce. RG. 374, 510; ‘wild beasts.’ RG. 375
Wilderness, sb. == a desolate place. RG. 15
Wildfire, sb. RG. 410
Wile, sb. == trick, deceit. Ritson’s AS. viii. 180. AS. wile
Wilful, adj. RG. 359; [willesful]. RG. 77
—— == voluntary. Ps. lxvii. 10
Wilfully, adv. == without a cause. Ps. xxxiv. 7; lxviii. 5
Will, sb. RG. 367
—— v. n. == wish. RG. 384; pret. ‘wolde.’ RG. 550
65. Will, v. aux. pres. 1 s. ‘wole.’ 39 B.; 2 s. ‘wolt.’ 40 B.; ‘wlt.’ O. and N.
499; 3 s. ‘wule.’ O. and N. 1360; ‘wile.’ O. and N. 1358; pret. 3 s.
‘wolde.’ 17 β; 2 s. ‘woldest.’ 35 B. ‘Will’ is constantly used with the
infin. of the verb to form an imperative, as ‘nil þou niþe’ == strive
not. Ps. xxxvi. 8, and cf. Ps. lxxiv. 5, 6
Willesful, == wilful, q. v.
Willing, sb. Rel. Ant. ii. 212
Wilne, v. n. == wish. RG. 217. AS. wilnian
—— v. a. == covet, desire. RG. 46; part. ‘y-wilned.’ RG. 309
Wimple, sb. Marg. 47. AS. winpel
Win, v. a. == subdue, get possession of [i-winne]. RG. 519; recover,
obtain. RG. 523, 549; pret. ‘wonne.’ RG. 384; ‘wonde.’ RG. 258;
‘wan.’ Alys. 5561. AS. winnan
Wind, sb. RG. 367
Wind, v. a. == twist. pret. ‘wond.’ Pilate, 126. AS. windan
Windmill, sb. RG. 547
Window, sb. Wright’s L. P. p. 91
Wine, sb. RG. 6, 542. AS. wín
Wine, sb. == a friend. M. Ode, 111. AS. wine
Wineyard, sb. == vineyard. Wright’s L. P. p. 41. AS. wín-geard
Wing, sb. RG. 28
Winli, adj. == winsome. Ps. xxiii. 3. AS. wynlíc
Winne, sb. == joy. Pol. S. 195. AS. wyn
Winne, sb. == labour. O. and N. 670. AS. win
66. Winsome, adj. == lovely, delightful. Ps. lxxviii. 9. AS. wynsum
—— v. n. == be propitious. Ps. cii. 3
Winter, sb. RG. 371, 539
Wipe, v. a. RG. 435. AS. wípian
Wippen, v. n. == weep? O. and N. 1064
Wire, sb. [wyred]. Alys. 208. AS. wír
Wirwed, part. == strangled. HD. 1921. Dut. wurghen
Wisdom, sb. RG. 384
Wise, sb. == manner, ‘in no wise.’ 1212 B.; [wes]. O. and N. 748
Wise, adj. RG. 468, 506; sup. ‘wisest.’ RG. 266
Wisely, adv. RG. 550
Wisse, v. a. == direct. HD. 104. 1057 B. O. and N. 971. AS. wísian
Wissing, sb. == advice. HD. 2902. AS. wissung
Wit, sb. == knowledge, sense. RG. 457, 526; [i-wit]. O. and N. 772
Witch, sb. Wright’s L. P. p. 38. AS. wicca, a wizard
—— v. n. == sing charms. Ps. lvii. 6
Witchcraft, sb. Body and Soul, 27
Witching, sb. == witchcraft. St Lucy, 122
Wite, v. a. == know. RG. 374; [y-wyte]. RG. 10; [iwite]. RG. 487;
[wot]. 1625 B.; [wat]. O. and N. 1200; [wod]. Ib. 1188; 2 s. pres.
‘wost.’ O. and N. 717; pret. ‘wuste.’ RG. 374; ‘wiste.’ 208 B.; ‘west.’
Alys. 5834; part. ‘iwiste.’ 137 B.
Wite, v. n. == think, or expect. 2 s. pres. ‘west.’ O. and N. 47; pret.
‘wiste.’ RG. 93
67. Wite, v. a. == defend. RG. 487; pret. ‘wuste.’ RG. 549; S. S. witen.
See Gloss. to Laȝ.
Wite, v. n. == go forth. Ps. lxxxix. 6; part. ‘wited.’ Ps. ix. 22;
‘witand.’ Ps. cxviii. 118. AS. wítan
Wite, v. a. == blame. O. and N. 1354; accuse. Wright’s L. P. p. 39.
AS. witian
Witerlike, adv. == certainly. HD. 671. Ps. ii. 6
Witermon, sb. == a wise man. Wright’s L. P. p. 28
With, prep. == together with. 279 B.; [we]. RG. 457
—— == by means of. RG. 41
—— == against. O. and N. 62
—— == from. O. and N. 610. AS. wíð
With, adj. == white, q. v.
With, adj. for ‘wight,’ q. v.
With, adj. == pleasant? Wright’s L. P. p. 45. AS. wéðe
Withal, adv. RG. 28
Withclepe, v. a. == oppose. Alys. 1301
Withdraw, v. a. RG. 447
—— v. n. Ps. cxviii. 115; ‘withdraw of’ == withdraw from. RG. 497
Wither, adj. == hostile. Rel. S. i. 12; S. S. wiðer. See Gloss. to Laȝ.
Withering, sb. == adversary. K. Horn, 154
Witherthreat, v. a. Ps. xxxiv. 19; lxxiii. 10
Witherwendand, part. == opposing. Ps. iii. 8
68. Witherwine, sb. == adversary. RG. 325. AS. wiðer-winna, from
winnan, to strive
Witherword, sb. == a hostile word. Ps. xc. 3
Withhold, v. a. == to hold with, or make to accompany. HD. 2356,
2362
—— == restrain. Alys. 2302
Within, adv. RG. 375, 549
Without, adv. RG. 549. 267 B.; [widh wute]. O. and N. 1593
—— prep. RG. 369; [witute]. O. and N. 183; [withouten]. 33 B.
Withsay, v. a. RG. 369, 374
Withseek, v. a. == seek out. part. ‘wuthsoht.’ Rel. S. v. 54
Withsitten, v. a. == oppose. HD. 1683
Withstand, v. n. == oppose. 725 B.
Withy, sb. == halter of withy. Alys. 4714. AS. wíðie
Witless, adj. == mad. RG. 216; at a loss. Pilate, 242
Witness, sb. RG. 29
Witterli, adv. == certainly. Ps. cxix. 1. ON. víturlega
Witty, adj. == clever. RG. 189; full of knowledge. O. and N. 1187. F.
and P. 31
Witword, sb. == testimony. Ps. xxiv. 10. AS. wit-word
Wive, v. n. == marry. RG. 35
—— v. a. part. ‘iwived.’ RG. 529
Wiving, sb. == marriage. RG. 294
69. Wlak, adj. == lukewarm. Fr. Sci. 290 AS. wlæc
Wlate, v. a. == loathe. Ps. v. 7. AS. wlættian
—— v. n. == feel disgust for. O. and N. 354
—— sb. == disgust. O. and N. 1504. AS. wlætte
Wlatful, adj. == loathsome, abominable. Ps. lii. 2
Wlating, sb. == loathing, disgust. Ps lxxxvii. 9. AS. wlætung
Wlite, v. n. == look. Wright’s L. P. p. 43. AS. wlítan
—— sb. == countenance. O. and N. 439; Ps. xliv. 5. AS. wlíte
Wlonk, adj. == fair, proud. Pol. S. 156. AS. wlanc
Wluine, sb. == she wolf? HD. 573. Probably a metathesis of the
ON. ulfinna,
thus
ulvin
}
vluin
Wo, sb. RG. 172, 485; [wai]. O. and N. 120; [wee]. Pol. S. 152;
[weye]. Alys. 3449; [wa]. Ritson’s AS. viii. 152. AS. wá
Wo worth, i. e. woe be to, &c. Body and Soul, 7
Wobegone, adj. Body and Soul, 220
Wode, == went. See Go
Woderove, sb. == the woodruff; the asterula odorata of botanists.
Wright’s L. P. p. 43. In Wright’s Vocab. p. 140, ‘wuderove’ is given as
the transl. of ‘hastula regia’ or ‘muge de bois’
Wodewale, sb. == woodpecker. Wright’s L. P. p. 26
—— == wild thyme? Alys. 6793. AS. wudufille. Palsgrave has
‘wodewale, a herbe’
70. Woht, sb. == sin. See Woȝ
Wolc, sb. == some bird. Wright’s L. P. p. 26
Wold, sb. == power, governance. Alys. 6716
Woldeneyed, == wall-eyed. Alys. 5274. Probably from the ON.
vagl i augum == festuca, pterygion. ‘En hinde, som trækker sig over
öiet.’ B. Haldorson.
Wole, adj. == evil. O. and N. 8; [wle]. O. and N. 35. AS. wól
Wolf, sb. RG. 369
Wolfling, sb. Alys. 6272
Wollen, sb. == wollen garment. Fr. on Seven Sins, 16
Woman, sb. RG. 380; [wimman]. RG. 535. pl. ‘wymmen.’ Wright’s
L. P. p. 33
Womanly, adj. RG. 457
Womb, sb. RG. 369. AS. wamb
Wombed, adj. RG. 377; [wemod]. Fr. Sci. 286
Wombeling, sb. == womb. Alys. 5674
Won, sb. == hope. RG. 419; [iwon]. 1022, 1712, B.; [wunne]. Pol.
S. 153
—— == opinion. HD. 1972. AS. wén. ON. von
Won, sb. == plenty. RG. 2, 265; [iwon]. Rel. S. v. 76
—— == riches. Wright’s L. P. p. 24. Alys. 5658; [wane]. Ritson’s AS.
viii. 50; SS. winne, wunnen
Won, sb. == dwelling. Wright’s L. P. pp. 46, 51. AS. wunian
Won. See Wan
71. Wonde, v. n. == fear, hesitate. K. Horn, 345. AS. wandian
Wonde, v. n. == cease. Wright’s L. P. p. 29. AS. wendan
Wonde, v. n. == wound? Alys. 6525
Wonde, adj. == wicked. Rel. S. v. 112. ON. vondr. AS. wonn
Wonder, sb. RG. 376
—— == a wonderful thing. RG. 7, 417
—— v. n. O. and N. 228
—— adj. == wonderful. RG. 416
Wonderful, adj. RG. 414
Wondering, sb. Wright’s L. P. p. 40
Wonderliche, adv. == wonderfully. RG. 489
Wondred, == sorrow. See Wandreth
Wone. See When
Wone, sb. == want. See Wane, sb.
Wone, sb. == opinion. HD. 1711. AS. wénan
Wone, adj. == wont. HD. 2297; [i-wune]. O. and N. 1318; [y-
woned]. RG. 377
—— sb. == custom. RG. 392. AS. wune
Wong, sb. == cheek. Wright’s L. P. pp. 28, 30, 31. AS. wang
Wong, sb. == field, plain. HD. 397, 1444. AS. wang
Wonie, == whine, q. v.
Woning, sb. == a dwelling. RG. 275; [wonyghing]. Alys. 5930
72. Woningstede, sb. Ps. lxxxvi. 7. Ritson’s AS. viii. 53, 200
Wonne, v. n. == dwell. RG. 41. AS. wunian
Wonying, == whining, q. v.
Woo, v. a. [woȝe]. K. Horn, 558; [wowe]. Wright’s L. P. p. 44. AS.
wógan
Wood, sb. RG. 374, 565. AS. wudu
Wood, adj. == mad. RG. 496. AS. wód
Woodward, sb. == the keeper of the wood. Pol. S. 149
Wooing, sb. Wright’s L. P. p. 28
Wool, sb. RG. 2
Woolmonger, sb. RG. 539
Woolpack, sb. RG. 539
Wop, sb. == weeping. RG. 476
Word, sb. RG. 377, 501
—— == tidings. RG. 153
Woren, v. a. == trouble, disturb. Wright’s L. P. p. 24. AS. worian
Worewed, part. == worried. See Worry
Wori, adj. == troubled (of water). 255, 274 β
Work, sb. RG. 448
—— v. a. == cause. Wright’s L. P. p. 42, make, fashion; part
‘ywroȝte.’ RG. 447, ‘ywort.’ RG. 174
—— v. n. == do work. 186 B. Wright’s L. P. p. 60; pret. ‘wraht.’ Ibid.
p. 42, ‘wroȝte.’ RG. 287
73. Workman, sb. St Swithin, 55
World, sb. KG. 367
Worldly, adj. Fragm. on Seven Sins, 16
Worly, adj. == excellent, beautiful. Wright’s L. P. pp. 39, 45;
[wurhliche]. Ibid. p. 51. AS. wurðlic
Worm, sb. RG. 490
Worry, v. a. 1598 B.; part. ‘worewed.’ HD. 1915. AS. wérian
Worse, adj. RG. 374, 501
Worship, sb. [wurthsipe]. O. and N. 1097, 1342
Worshipful, adj. Ps. lxxi. 14
Worst, adj. Wright’s L. P. p. 99
Worst. See Worthe
Wort, sb. == a root. RG. 341. AS. wyrt
Worth, sb. == value. RG. 373
—— adj. == worthy of, ‘what hii were wurth.’ RG. 374
Worth, adv. = forth. RG. 457
Worthe, v. n. == be, become. [iworthe]. 947 B. 2 s. pres. ‘worst.’
1812; 3 s. pres. ‘worth.’ RG. 512; 1 pl. ‘wortheth.’ RG. 454; 3 s.
imper. (in the phrase ‘wo worth.’) Body and Soul, 7; part. ‘iworthe.’
O. and N. 660. AS. weorðan
Worthful, adj. O. and N. 1479
Worthing, sb. == glory, honour. Fragm. in Warton, H. E. P. vol. i. p.
22. AS. weorðung
Worthship, sb. == worship, q. v.
74. Worthy, adj. == excellent. 412 B.
—— == powerful. Ps. xlix. 3
Wot, == know. See Wite
Wote ? RG. 361
Wou, See Woȝ
Would, sb. See Will
Wound, sb. RG. 49. Wright’s L. P. pp. 85, 84
—— v. a. part, ‘ywonded.’ RG. 49
Wow, See Woȝ
Wowe, sb. == wall. HD. 1963. K. Horn, 1000. AS. wáh
Wowe, v. n. == to woo, q. v.
Woȝ, sb. == wrong. O. and N. 164. RG. 39; [wou]. RG. 375, 550;
[wow]. RG. 379; [woht]. Rel. S. ii. 16. AS. wóh
Wrake, sb. == evil, destruction. O. and N. 1192. AS. wræc
Wrakeful, adj. == wicked. Wright’s L. P. p. 23. AS. wræcfull
Wrath, sb. 451 B. AS. wráð
—— v. n. == be angry. Ps. iv. 5
—— v. a. == make angry. RG. 376, 253
Wrathless, adj. Wright’s L. P. p. 42
Wray, v. a. == betray. 1226 B; [wrye]. Alys. 442. AS. wreian
Wrayli, v. n. == chatter, rail, abuse. St Swithin, 70. Dut. rallen.
Swed. ralla
Wreche, sb. == vengeance. RG. 380, 419. AS. wræc
75. Wreche, == misery. RG. 252. But we should probably read
‘wrechede’
Wreier, sb. == betrayer, spoiler. HD. 39
Wreke, v. a. == avenge. HD. 1363. AS. wræccan
Wreker, sb. == avenger. Ps. viii. 3
Wren, sb. O. and N. 564. AS. wrenna
Wrench, sb. == trick. RG. 570, 535. AS. wrence
Wreon, v. a. == cover. Alys. 1606; 3 s. pres. ‘wrieth.’ Alys. 1992;
part. ‘ywrye.’ RG. 56, 92. AS. wreon, wríhan
Wrestle, v. n. RG. 22, 361. Alys. 1046. AS. wræstlian
Wrestling, sb. O. and N. 793. Alys. 1046
Wretch, sb. 524 β AS. wræcca
—— adj. == wretched. 449 B.
Wretched, adj. comp. ‘wretcheder.’ 2432 B.
Wretchede, sb. == wretchedness. RG. 386, 511
Wretchedly, adv. RG. 446
Wrethen—writhen, part. == twisted. Alys. 5723
Wrey, v. a. == accuse. Pol. S. 198, 199; part. ‘wreynt.’ Pol. S. 157.
AS. wrégan
Wrie, v. n. == move away. Wright’s L. P. p. 48. AS. wrigan, whence
our ‘wriggle’
Wrieth, == covereth. See Wreon
Wrikke, v. n. == wriggle. St Dunstan, 82; ‘wrikkend’ == walking,
going. Rel. Ant. ii. p. 216. AS. wrigan
76. Wring, v. a. (one’s hands). Body and Soul, 174; (clothes). HD. 1233
—— == keep tight hold of. Sermon, 20
—— == twist; part. ‘wrong.’ Alys. 6447
—— == press down, overcome; pret. ‘wrong.’ Marg. 47. AS. wringan
Wringer, sb. Sermon, 21
Writ, sb. HD. 136
—— == Scripture. Wright’s L. P. p. 101
—— == letter. Alys. 4502
Write, v. a. pret. ‘wrot.’ 164 B.; part. ‘iwrite.’ 1425 B.
Writeling, sb. == trills in a song? O. and N. 48, 912. From AS.
wriðan == to writhe or twist
Writhe, v. n. == bend easily. Body and Soul, 116. AS. wríðan
Wro, sb. == hole or corner. HD. 68. Su. Goth. wra. Dan. vraa
Wronehede. Probably a mistake for ‘wronghede’ == wickedness.
O. and N. 1398
Wrong, adj. == mistaken. Wright’s L. P. p. 31. ON. rángr. AS.
wringan
Wrong, sb. == injustice, oppression. Wright’s L. P. p. 68. 1616 B.
—— adv. == badly. O. and N. 196
Wrong, part. == twisted. See Wring
Wrongwis, adj. == wicked. Ritson’s AS. viii. 177; [wrancwise].
Moral Ode, 129
Wrot, sb. == snout. Rel. Ant. ii. 211. AS. wrót
Wroten, v. n. == to root. Earth, st. 3. AS. wrót
77. Wroth, adj. == angry. RG. 31; timid. Alys. 544. AS. wráð
—— == poor, base. Wright’s L. P. p. 38
—— sb. == evil, unkindness. RG. 31
Wrotherhele, sb. [wrothe hele] == injury, destruction. RG. 143,
164. Body and Soul, 225. See Gloss. Rem. to Laȝamon, iii. 444
Wrought. See Work, vb.
Wrying, sb. == treachery. Alys. 3514
Wune, sb. == custom. O. and N. 272. AS. wune
Wunne, adj. == accustomed? Wright’s L. P. p. 46
Wunne, sb. == joy. Wright’s L. P. p. 47. AS. wyn
—— == hope. See Won
Wyred, == wire, q. v.
Wyt, sb. == calamity, blame. Body and Soul, 62. AS. wíte
78. Y.
Y, == in. Pol. S. 151
Yard, sb. == rod. RG. 22; [ȝurd]. 2385 B.
—— == staff or sceptre. Ps. xliv. 7. AS. gyrd
Yard, sb. == courtyard. HD. 702. AS. geard
Yare, adj. == ready. RG. 396; [ȝarte]. O. and N. 1220. AS. gearo
—— v. a. == make ready. HD. 1350
Yare, adv. == of yore. 1512 B. AS. geara
Yate, v. a. == tell. Ritson’s AS. viii. 80. ON. géta
Yawn, v. n. [ȝonie]. O. and N. 292; [yene]. Body and Soul, 202.
Alys. 485. AS. ganian
Ybrad. See Braid
Ycholle, == I shall. RG. 405
Ycoled, part. == helmeted, armed. Alys. 2686. AS. col, a helmet
Ydle. See Isle
Ydought. See Dow
Yea. 36 B.; [ya]. Alys. 3571
Year, sb. RG. 373. AS. gear
Yearn, v. a. Wright’s L. P. p. 43; [eorne]. O. and N. 1202
—— v. n. Wright’s L. P. p. 63. AS. geornian
79. Yearning, sb. Wright’s L. P. p. 72
Yell, v. n. [ȝulle]. 498 β; 2 s. pres. ‘ȝollest.’ O. and N. 223; pret. ‘ȝal.’
502 β. AS. geallian
Yelling, sb. [ȝullinge]. 487 β. O. and N. 1641
Yellowman, sb. [ȝeolumon], Pol. S. 158
Yelp, v. n. == speak. Alys. 1065. AS. gilpan
—— == boast [ȝulpe], O. and N. 1650; part. ‘y-yolpe.’ Alys. 3368
Yelping [ȝulping], sb. == boasting. RG. 209, 210
Yeme, Yheme, Yheming. See ȝeme
Yene, sb. == yawn, q. v.
Yepe, adj. == ready. Alys. 1193. See ȝep
Yering, sb. == yearning, desire. Ritson’s AS. viii. 79
Yesterday. Ps. lxxxix. 4
Yet, adv. [ȝut]. RG. 372; [ȝot]. O. and N. 1695
Yfere, sb. == companions. Alys. 6906. AS. ge-fera
Yhaht. See Hatch
Yhatered, part. == clothed. Alys. 5922. See Hattren
Yhete, v. a. == cast, pour out. Ps. lxviii. 25; pret. ‘yhet.’ Ps. xli. 5;
pl. ‘yhotten.’ Ps. lxxviii. 3; part. ‘yotten.’ Ps. lxxiii. 21. AS. geotan. See
‘ȝete’
Yhoten, sb. == giant, Ps. xviii. 7. AS. eóten
Yield, v. a. == give up. Alys. 3176; pret. ‘yolde.’ RG. 387; part. ‘y-
yolde.’ RG. 449; ‘iȝulde.’ 612 B. AS. geldan
—— == repay. Alys. 132
80. —— v. n. == turn out. K. Horn, 495
Ylef, vb. == believe thou. RG. 265
Ylome, == frequently. See Ilome
Ylong, adv. == belonging to, proper to. Wright’s L. P. pp. 61, 74.
AS. gelang
Ymette, adj. == moderate? Wright’s L. P. p. 35. AS. gemet
Ymone, adv. == together, in concert. 380 β AS. gemana
Ympne. See Hymn
Ynele, == I ne will—I will not. RG. 314
Ynote, part. == noted, known. Alys. 59
Yoke, sb. RG. 453. AS. geoc
—— v. a. part. ‘y-yoked.’ Rel. Ant. ii. 211
Yolk, sb. Fr. Sci. 240. AS. geolca
Yond, adv. [ȝund] == yonder. 1 β. AS. geond
Yond, adj. == farther, as the ‘yond half,’ or farther side. Ritson’s AS.
viii. 200. 713 β
Yornandlike, adj. == desirable. Ps. xviii. 11
Young, adj. RG. 377; comp. ‘younger.’ RG. 423; sup. ‘youngest.’ RG.
381. AS. geong
Younghede, sb. [ȝonghede] == youth. Legend of St Cuthbert, in
Warton, H. E. P. vol. i. p. 15, n.
Younglike, adj. Ps. cxviii. 141
Youngling, sb. Alys. 2366
Your, adj. RG. 455; [ower]. RG. 500; [or]. Wright’s L. P. p. 32
81. Youth, sb. Body and Soul, 111; [ȝeuȝede]. Moral Ode, st. 178. AS.
geogoð
Youthhede, sb. Ps. xlii. 4
Yox, v. n. == sob. 1570 B. AS. geocsa
Yoxing, sb. == hiccuping. RG. 34
Ypotanos. See Hippopotamus
Yraȝte, vb. == procreated? O. and N. 106
Yse, sb. == iron. Alys. 5149. AS. ísen. Germ. eisen
Ysome, adv. == together. RG. 3, 83. AS. gesome
Ysteot, part. == fastened. Alys. 2768
Yswerred, adj. == having necks. Alys. 6264. AS. sweora
Yswowe, part. == in a swoon. Alys. 2262. See Swoon
Ythe, adv. == easily. K. Horn, 61. AS. eáðe
Ythen, part. == flourishing, prosperous. See The, vb.
Ytolde, part. == pitched (of a tent). Alys. 5901. See Teld
Yvortrou, adj. == mistrustful. RG. 342
Ywrye. See Wreon
82. Ȝ.
Ȝarewe, adj. == ready. O. and N. 378. AS. gearo
Ȝark, v. a. == make ready. RG. 391, 399. Alys. 1411. AS. gearcian
Ȝarte. See Yare
Ȝavre, == ever, or perhaps ‘of yore.’ O. and N. 1178
Ȝef. See If
Ȝeines. Rel. S. i. 16. Probably instead of ‘tharto ȝeines’ we should
read ‘thar toȝeines’ == there against, i.e. against death. AS. to-
geánes
Ȝeme, sb. == care. RG. 135. AS. gýman
—— v. a. == care for, take care of. HD. 131
Ȝeming, sb. == care. Ps. cxl. 3
Ȝende, sb. == end. RG. 169
Ȝene ? O. and N. 843
Ȝeode, vb. == went. See Go
Ȝep, adj. == active. Wright’s L. P. p. 39; bold. O. and N. 465. AS.
gæp
Ȝephede, sb. == boldness. O. and N. 683
Ȝerne, adv. == earnestly. RG. 487. AS. georne
Ȝete, v. a. == cast. Body and Soul, 189. See yhete
Ȝeuȝede, sb. == youth, q. v.
83. Ȝeve, == give, q. v.
Ȝeynchar, sb. == repentance. Wright’s L. P. p. 46. See App. to
Mapes’s Poems, p. 343. AS. cerran with ‘gen’
Ȝeȝe, v. n. == jog along, go. Wright’s L. P. p. 111
—— v. a. == jog. Pol. S. 158
Ȝif. See If
Ȝiverness, sb. == avarice. Rel. S. vii. 11. AS. gífer
Ȝoe, == she. See under He
Ȝoe, == joy, q. v.
Ȝokkyn, sb. == joking? Wright’s L. P. p. 50
Ȝomere, adj. == sorrowful. O. and N. 415. AS. geomor
Ȝonie, == yawn, q. v.
Ȝoȝelinge, sb. == chattering, gabbling. O. and N. 40. Probably the
same as the later ‘gaggle,’ which is used of a confused noise of
people talking, in the Poem on the Deposition of Richard II. p. 18,
and of geese, in Churchyard’s Pleasant Conceit penned in Verse
(1593), cited in the pref. to Nash’s Pierce Penniless. (Shaksp. Soc.’s
ed.), p. xviii.
Ȝraihand. See Thraying
Ȝuling. See Yelling
Ȝulle. See Yell
Ȝulpe. See Yelp
Ȝulping. See Yelping
85. ADDENDA.
Baru, add AS. bearh
Bert, v. n. == crepitum ventris edere. Rel. Ant. ii. p. 211
Bidde, v. n. == need, ought. HD. 1733. Another form of ‘bud.’ Dan.
bör. Compare Chaucer’s ‘bode.’ Rom. Rose, 790
Birde, sb. For HD. 2760, read Wright’s L. P. pp. 25, 30
Birde, vb. pret. == it behoved. HD. 2760. ON. byrjar. Dan. bör
Brol ? Rel. Ant. ii. 192
By, v. a. == to defame. Manuel des Pecches, 1355. ON. bía,
maculare
Ferblet. Possibly ‘suffused with blood,’ ‘sanguine.’ Cf. ‘forbled,’ in the
Anturs of Arthur at Tarne Wathelan, st. 51
Graueth. Probably for ‘graveth,’ or ‘geraveth,’ from AS. reáf, clothing
JOHN CHILDS AND SON, PRINTERS.
86. Welcome to our website – the perfect destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. We believe that every book holds a new world,
offering opportunities for learning, discovery, and personal growth.
That’s why we are dedicated to bringing you a diverse collection of
books, ranging from classic literature and specialized publications to
self-development guides and children's books.
More than just a book-buying platform, we strive to be a bridge
connecting you with timeless cultural and intellectual values. With an
elegant, user-friendly interface and a smart search system, you can
quickly find the books that best suit your interests. Additionally,
our special promotions and home delivery services help you save time
and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
Join us on a journey of knowledge exploration, passion nurturing, and
personal growth every day!
ebookbell.com